Skip to main content
Log in

Some Simple Analytics of Vertically Linked Markets

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A firm may have an incentive to encourage competition and/or efficiency in an “aftermarket” that is vertically linked to a “foremarket” in which it participates. I describe a strong form of this potential incentive, and then explore how it is weakened in plausible circumstances. Some applications to net neutrality are described.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. I believe that one could legitimately use more than one concept of price here, provided that one is consistent; but the perceived system price most directly drives demand.

  2. Severin Borenstein has suggested a possible illustration: In airlines, the introduction of “premium economy” seating, or more generally the shifting around in relative amenities and terms that are offered by airlines to different groups of passengers, repeatedly changes the identity of “the marginal customer” (for any one airline, or, if it matters, for the industry).

References

  • Agarwal, S., Chomsisengphet, S., Mahoney, N., & Stroebel, J. (2015). Regulating consumer financial products: Evidence from credit cards. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(1), 111–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borenstein, S., MacKie-Mason, J., & Netz, J. (2000). Exercising market power in proprietary aftermarkets. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 9, 157–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cabral, L. (2014). Aftermarket power and foremarket competition. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 35, 60–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlton, D., & Waldman, M. (2010). Competition, monopoly, and aftermarkets. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 26, 54–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coppi, L. (2007). Aftermarket monopolization: The emerging consensus in economics. Antitrust Bulletin, 52, 53–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, J. (2012). Can privacy be just another good? The Journal on Telecommunications and High-Technology Law, 10, 251–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, J., & Weiser, P. (2003). Modularity, vertical integration, and open access policies. Harvard Journal of Law and Technology, 17, 85–134.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, D., & Smith, D. (2014). Privacy in online markets: A welfare analysis of demand rotations. Federal Trade Commission Bureau of Economics working paper no. 323.

  • Shapiro, C. (1995). Aftermarkets and consumer welfare: Making sense of Kodak. Antitrust Law Journal, 63, 483–511.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spence, M. (1975). Monopoly, quality and regulation. Bell Journal of Economics, 6, 417–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission. (2010). Horizontal merger guidelines.

  • Veiga, A., & Weyl, G. (2016). Product design in selection markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131, 1007–1056.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joseph Farrell.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Farrell, J. Some Simple Analytics of Vertically Linked Markets. Rev Ind Organ 50, 431–440 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-017-9571-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-017-9571-2

Keywords

Navigation