Skip to main content
Log in

Harm to Competition Under the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In August, 2010, the Antitrust Division and the Federal Trade Commission issued new Guidelines for assessing horizontal mergers under the antitrust laws. These Guidelines were long awaited not merely because of the lengthy interval between them and previous Guidelines but also because enforcement policy had drifted far from the standards articulated in the previous Guidelines. The 2010 Guidelines are distinctive manly for two things. One is briefer and less detailed treatment of market delineation. The other is an expanded set of theories of harm that justify preventing mergers or reversing mergers that have already occurred. The 2010 Guidelines reflect a growing belief that in markets where product differentiation is minimal competition tends to be robust and the structural presumptions stated in previous Guidelines were too harsh. By contrast, where product differentiation is substantial the Guidelines’ approach tended to define markets too broadly, overlooking significantly anticompetitive possibilities. Under the 2010 Guidelines unilateral effects analysis relevant markets can be very small, often limited to three or four firms, and excluding some obvious substitutes. Markets in merger analysis are not defined for their own sake, however, but rather to ascertain whether a particular alteration in market structure covered by the merger provisions will be likely to facilitate a price increase. The 2010 Guidelines address four substantive merger concerns: exclusion, restraints on innovation, unilateral effects, and coordinated effects. The Guidelines have a separate section on mergers limiting “innovation and product variety,” treated mainly in the category of unilateral effects. The 2010 Guidelines are more flexible than previous Guidelines and also more catholic about the types of harms that mergers might cause and the techniques that can be used to assess them. Older Guidelines were excessively wed to methodologies that were at the forefront of applied merger analysis when they were drafted, but that tended to make the Guidelines obsolete as new methodologies became available. Not only do methodologies change, they are also specific to the situation. Further, they tend to be well developed in the literature and accessible to experts consulted by those defending a merger as well as to the government economists who employ them. To be sure, there is a tradeoff between flexibility and guidance. Often we can have more of one only by giving up some of the other, and that tradeoff is clearly present in the 2010 Guidelines.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Areeda P. E., Hovenkamp H. (2007) Antitrust law, 2, 2A, 2B. Aspen, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Areeda P. E., Hovenkamp H. (2008) Antitrust law, 3, 3A. Aspen, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Areeda P. E., Hovenkamp H. (2009) Antitrust law, 4, 4A. Aspen, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Areeda P. E., Hovenkamp H. (2010) Antitrust law. Supp. Aspen, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker D. I., Blumenthal W. (1983) The 1982 guidelines and pre-existing law. California Law Review 71: 337–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker J. B., Bresnahan T. F. (1985) The gains from merger or collusion in product—differentiated industries. Journal of Industrial Economics 33: 429

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker J. B. (2009) Market concentration in the antitrust analysis of horizontal mergers. In: Hylton K. (eds) Antirust law and economics. Edward Elgar, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, J. B. (2010). Market concentration in the antitrust analysis of horizontal mergers. available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1092248.

  • Bohannan, C., & Hovenkamp, H. (2011a). Concerted refusals to license intellectual property rights. 1 Harvard Business Law Review Bulletin 1, 21.

  • Bohannan C., Hovenkamp H. (2011b) Creation without restraint: Promoting liberty and rivalry in innovation. Oxford Univ. Press, forthcoming, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlton D. W. (2004) Using economics to improve antitrust policy. Columbia Business Law Review 2004: 297

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlton D. W. (2010) Revising the horizontal merger guidelines. Journal of Competition Law and Economics 6: 619

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cave J., & Salant, S. W. (1995). Cartel quotas under majority rule. American Economic Review, 85, 82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coate, M. B. (2008). Unilateral effects under the guidelines: Models, merits, and merger policy. available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1263474.

  • Cohen N. B., Sullivan C. A. (1983) The Herfindahl–Hirschman index and the new antitrust merger guidelines: Concentrating on concentration. Texas Law Review 62: 453–490

    Google Scholar 

  • Das Varma G. (2009) Will use of the upward pricing pressure test lead to an increase in the level of merger enforcement. Antitrust 24: 27

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell J., & Shapiro, C. (2008). Improving critical loss analysis. Antitrust Source, available at http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/critical2008.pdf.

  • Farrell J., & Shapiro, C. (2010). Antitrust evaluation of horizontal mergers: An economic alternative to market definition. The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 10, art. 9, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1313782.

  • Gans J. S. (2007) Concentration-based merger test and vertical market structure. Journal of Law and Economics 50: 662

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurrea S. D., Owen B. M. (2003) Coordinated interaction and Clayton §7 enforcement. George Mason Law Review 12: 93–94

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H. (1929) Stability in competition. Economic Journal 39: 41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hovenkamp, H. (2010a). The law of vertical integration and the business firm: 1880–1960. Iowa Law Review, 95, 914 & n. 237.

  • Hovenkamp H. (2010b) The Obama administration and section 2 of the Sherman act. Boston University Law Review 90: 1611

    Google Scholar 

  • Hovenkamp, H. (2010c). Notice and patent remedies. 88 Texas Law Review Online 221, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1596789.

  • Hovenkamp, H. (2011). Federal antitrust policy: The law of competition and its practice. (St. Paul: West Group 4th ed., 2011).

  • Kaplow L. (2010) Why (Ever) define markets?. Harvard Law Review 124: 437

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaysen C., Turner D. F. (1959) Antitrust policy: An economic and legal analysis. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Kovacic W. E., Marshall R. C., Marx L. M., Schulenberg S. (2009) Quantitative analysis of coordinated effects. Antitrust Law Journal 76: 397

    Google Scholar 

  • Kwoka J. E. (1979) The effect of market share distribution on industry performance. Review of Economics and Statistics 61: 101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwoka J. E. (1985) The Herfindahl index in theory and practice. Antitrust Bulletin 30: 915

    Google Scholar 

  • Lande R. H. (2001) Resurrecting incipiency: From Von’s grocery to consumer choice. Antitrust Law Journal 68: 884

    Google Scholar 

  • Leary T. B. (2002) The essential stability of merger policy in the United States. Antitrust Law Journal 70: 129

    Google Scholar 

  • Ordover, J. A. (2007). Coordinated effects in merger analysis: An introduction. Columbia Business Law Review, 414, 2007.

  • Ordover J. A. (2008) Coordinated effects. In: Collins W. D. (eds) Issues in competition law and policy (1359). American Bar Association, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter R. H. (2005) Detecting collusion. Review of Industrial Organization 26: 157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C. (1989) Theories of oligopoly behavior. In: Schmalensee R., Willig R. (eds) Handbook of industrial organization (Ch. 6). Elsevier, San Diego

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C. (2010). The 2010 horizontal merger guidelines: From Hedgehog to Fox in forty years. Antitrust Law Journal, 77, #1 (forthcoming).

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler G. J. (1964) A theory of oligopoly. Journal of Political Economy 72: 44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Werden G. J. (1997) Simulating unilateral competitive effects from differentiated products mergers. Antitrust 11: 27

    Google Scholar 

  • Werden G. J., Froeb L. M. (2008) Unilateral competitive effects of horizontal mergers. In: Buccirossi P. (eds) Handbook of antitrust economics (Ch. 3). MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Werden G. J. (2009) Next steps in the evolution of antitrust law: What to expect from the Roberts court. Journal of Competition Law and Economics 5: 61–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Herbert Hovenkamp.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Hovenkamp, H. Harm to Competition Under the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines. Rev Ind Organ 39, 3–18 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-011-9301-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-011-9301-0

Keywords

Navigation