Skip to main content
Log in

Land ownership, the subsistence constraint, and the demographic transition

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We develop a novel model of fertility choice predicting an increase and subsequent decrease in fertility levels without introducing a quality–quantity tradeoff, mortality changes, or urbanization. The model highlights the roles of a subsistence constraint and non-wage income deriving from the ownership of land. We show that the sign of the effect of the wage rate on fertility depends on whether non-wage income is greater or less than a minimum consumption level. Suggestive evidence supporting the model, on changes in fertility from 1851 to 1891 across French départements, is provided. Finally, we embed our static model in a model of endogenous growth, and provide a numerical illustration of the working of the model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Some of the more important contributions building on Becker (1960) are: Becker and Lewis (1973), Razin and Ben-Zion (1975), Becker and Barro (1988), Barro and Becker (1989), Becker et al. (1990), Ehrlich and Lui (1991), Galor and Weil (2000), Galor and Moav (2002), and Moav (2005). For excellent surveys of the theory and the evidence on the demographic transition, see Guinnane (2011) and Galor (2012).

  2. For an interesting growth model (not specifically related to the fertility transition) introducing a minimum consumption requirement, see Chatterjee and Ravikumar (1999).

  3. An important recent exception is Galor et al. (2009), which analyzes the effect of land inequality on public education and thus on growth.

  4. See O’Rourke and Williamson (2002), Figure 3, which shows the ratio of wages to land rents rising three-fold in France, from 1800 to 1900.

  5. Tamura (1994) analyzes an endogenous growth model in which, for low human capital countries, the effect of income is different from the effect of the wage, where the latter is the return to skilled human capital.

  6. See Tamura (2006) for a complementary general equilibrium model featuring endogenous timing of demographic transitions.

  7. Note that non-wage income resulting from land ownership is relevant only when the farmer either cultivates his own land or when he rents his land out, but not when he is a sharecropper. Where the farmer cultivates his own land, his “non-wage” income is the imputed return to the land which he owns, since he has the option of renting out his land and working at the market wage rate.

  8. We are indebted to Oded Galor for pointing this out.

  9. According to the indices of Coale (1967), overall fertility in England and Wales began declining only around 1871 (see Dyson and Murphy 1985, Table 1). Overall fertility using the Coale index in France, in contrast, began to decline at least as early as 1811 (Bonneuil 1997).

  10. This, of course, is a simplifying assumption. The results would be qualitatively the same as long as children are a relatively time-intensive commodity.

  11. It should be noted that altruistic parents (not a feature of our model) will tend to prefer partible inheritance to the extent that land is sufficiently productive to make \(v>c_{\min }\) , thus ensuring an adequate (non-wage) income to their heirs. This suggests that partible inheritance may be endogenous to the value of land. In our empirical work (Sect. 5) we account for this possibility in the regression displayed in Table 2, by using a dummy variable for partible inheritance related to inheritance customs a century earlier than the time period analyzed by the regression.

  12. Thus our model may provide an alternative explanation of the fact, noted by Galor et al. (2009), that countries where land ownership initially was relatively equally divided have experienced relatively rapid growth. Galor et al. point to the differing growth paths of the US and Canada, where land ownership was relatively equally distributed, and Latin America, where land ownership was highly concentrated. See also Deininger and Squire (1998) who document a negative cross-sectional correlation between initial land inequality and long-term growth.

  13. See Acemoglu (2003) for micro-foundations supporting the proposition that technological change will be labor augmenting in long-run growth. See also O’Rourke et al. (1996) and O’Rourke and Williamson (2005) for evidence that this was the case in nineteenth century Europe. O’Rourke et al. (1996, Table 4, Panel D) estimate that 52.2 % of the rise in the wage-rental ratio in France from 1875 to 1914 was due to land-saving technological change.

  14. If we were to make the simpler assumption that the elasticity of substitution is unity, the production function would be Cobb-Douglas, and the only way to model labor-augmenting technological change would be to increase the production elasticity of labor and simultaneously to decrease the production elasticity of land (to keep their sum constant at unity). This would impose a limit on technological change (production elasticity of labor = 1), which is clearly unattractive and unrealistic.

  15. The condition that the w rises relative to v is intended to minimize the confounding, positive income effect of increasing v, on fertility.

  16. Weir (1983) ran a regression of primarily pre-Revolutionary changes in fertility on (among other variables) 1866 inheritance custom data for a sample of 40 French villages. Due to the small sample size and the time gap between the 1866 inheritance data and pre-Revolutionary fertility changes, it is somewhat difficult to draw conclusions from this part of his important study.

  17. The data on the relative change in real wages are from Sicsic (1991, Chapter 1). We used Sicsic’s nominal agricultural wage data for 1852, and deflated his nominal wage data for 1892 by his index of ratio of 1893 non-rental (essentially food) agricultural prices to 1852 non-rental agricutural prices, weighted by the share of non-rental prices in the overall basket. For the rental part of the basket, we relied on his claim that rural housing rental prices did not change over the period. Thus the price deflator for 1892 is

    $$\begin{aligned} s\left( \frac{\pi _{non-rental,1893}}{\pi _{non-rental,1852}}\right) +(1-s). \end{aligned}$$

    where s is the share of non-rental goods in the overall basket and \(\pi _{t}\) denotes the price level.

    The data on fertility and mortality are from Bonneuil (1997). The fertility rates are overall fertility rates (the Coale \(I_{f}\) index).

  18. For simplicity and because of data limitations, we treat mortality as exogenous, despite the fact that, in reality, mortality is partly endogenous (parents can choose the level of care they take to prevent their infants from dying).

  19. Sicsic’s (1991) estimates of the cost of a basket of food items and of urban rents indicate that real rents increased from 1852 to 1890.

  20. The interaction term with work-own i is insignificant in both regressions, presumably reflecting small landholdings for agricultural workers (though we have no direct evidence on this point).

  21. The index assigns a value of 1 for the following (modern) French regions: Basse-Normandie, Bretagne, Champagne-Ardenne, Haute-Normandie, Ile-de-France, Pays del la Loire, and Poitou-Charentes. It assigns a value of 0.5 to the following two regions: Centre and Nord-Pas-de-Calais, which appear to have been “mixed” with respect to the prevalence of partible inheritance. The index for the remaining regions takes a value of zero.

  22. Differentiating (11) with respect to \(a_{t}\equiv A_{t}/N_{t},\)

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial v_{t}}{\partial a_{t}}=\left( \ell _{t}^{\rho }+a_{t}^{\rho }\right) ^{\frac{1}{\rho }}a_{t}^{\rho -1}\left[ \frac{\rho \ell _{t}^{\rho }+a_{t}^{\rho }}{\left( \ell _{t}^{\rho }+a_{t}^{\rho }\right) ^{2}}\right] . \end{aligned}$$

    Since \(\rho\) is assumed to be −1, the numerator in the square brackets is

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{a_{t}}-\frac{1}{\ell _{t}}=\frac{\ell _{t}-a_{t}}{a_{t}\ell _{t}}. \end{aligned}$$

    Thus the sign of \(\partial v_{t}/\partial a_{t}\) is the same as the sign of \(\ell _{t}-a_{t}.\)

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (2003). Labor-and capital-augmenting technical change. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(1), 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Becker, G. S. (1989). Fertility choice in a model of economic growth. Econometrica, 57(2), 481–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1960). An economic analysis of fertility. In Demographic and economic change in developed countries (pp. 209–240). New York: Columbia University Press.

  • Becker, G. S. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal, 75, 493–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., & Lewis, H. G. (1973). On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. Journal of Political Economy, 81(2, part 2), S279–S288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., & Barro, R. J. (1988). A reformulation of the economic theory of fertility. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103(1), 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., Murphy, K. M., & Tamura, R. (1990). Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5, part 2), S12–S37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binswanger, H. P. (1974). A cost function approach to the measurement of elasticities of factor demand and elasticities of substitution. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 56(2), 377–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonneuil, N. (1997). Transformation of the French Demographic Landscape, 1806–1906. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee, S., & Ravikumar, B. (1999). Minimum consumption requirements: Theoretical and quantitative implications for growth and distribution. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 3, 482–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coale, A.J. (1967). Factors associated with the development of low fertility: An historic summary. In Proceedings of the World Population Conference, 1965, (vol. 2). New York: United Nations.

  • Deininger, K., & Squire, L. (1998). New ways of looking at old issues: Inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 57, 259–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desan, S. (1997). War between brothers and sisters: Inheritance law and gender politics in revolutionary France. French Historical Studies, 20, 597–634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyson, T., & Murphy, M. (1985). The onset of fertility transition. Population and Development Review, 11(3), 399–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich, I., & Lui, F. (1991). Intergenerational trade, longevity, and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 99(5), 1029–1059.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Weil, D. (2000). Population, technology, and growth: From Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review, 90, 806–829.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2002). Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1133–1192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., Moav, O., & Vollrath, D. (2009). Inequality in landownership, the emergence of human-capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. Review of Economic Studies, 76, 143–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O. (2012). The demographic transition: Causes and consequences. Cliometrica, 6, 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guinnane, T. W. (2011). The historical fertility transition: A guide for economists. Journal of Economic Literature, 49, 589–614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guttman, J.M., & Tillman, A. (2014). Dispersion of land ownership, the subsistence constraint, and the demographic transition. Unpublished Bar-Ilan University.

  • Jones, C. I. (2001). Was an industrial revolution inevitable? Economic growth over the very long run. Advances in Macroeconomics, 1(2), 1–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lagerlöf, N. P. (2006). The Galor-Weil model revisited: A quantitative exercise. Review of Economic Dynamics, 9, 116–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moav, O. (2005). Cheap children and the persistence of poverty. Economic Journal, 115, 88–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Rourke, K.H., & Williamson, J.G. (2002). From Malthus to Ohlin: Trade, growth and distribution since 1500 (No. w8955). National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • O’Rourke, K.H., Taylor, A.M., & Williamson, J.G. (1996). Factor price convergence in the late nineteenth century. NBER Working Paper Series, 46.

  • O’Rourke, K. H., & Williamson, J. G. (2005). From Malthus to Ohlin: Trade, industrialisation and distribution since 1500. Journal of Economic Growth, 10(1), 5–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Razin, A., & Ben-Zion, U. (1975). An intergenerational model of population growth. American Economic Review, 65(5), 923–933.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sicsic, P. (1991). Labor markets and establishment size in nineteenth century France. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Harvard University.

  • Swinnen, J. F. M. (2002). Political reforms, rural crises, and land tenure in western Europe. Food Policy, 27(4), 371–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tamura, R. (1994). Fertility, human capital and the wealth of families. Economic Theory, 4(4), 593–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tamura, R. (2006). Human capital and economic development. Journal of Development Economics, 79(1), 26–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weir, D. R. (1983). Fertility transition in rural France, 1740–1829. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joel M. Guttman.

Additional information

We thank Raphael Franck, Jonathan Liebowitz, Tommy E. Murphy, and Pierre Sicsic for generously providing the data used in this study. We are also indebted to James Ang, Oded Galor, George Grantham, Eric Jones, Deirdre McCloskey, Jakob Madsen, David Mitch, Omer Moav, Sam Peltzman, David Weil, the Editor-in-Chief, and two anonymous referees, as well as participants in seminars at Bar-Ilan University, Monash University, and the University of Hong Kong, for helpful comments and discussions.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Guttman, J.M., Tillman, A. Land ownership, the subsistence constraint, and the demographic transition. Rev Econ Household 15, 1017–1036 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-015-9286-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-015-9286-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation