Skip to main content
Log in

Spillover Effects of Foreclosures on Neighborhood Property Values

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Previous studies have shown that foreclosure often results in vandalism, disinvestment and other negative spillover effects in the neighborhood. This paper extends these views into a formal theoretical model through pricing based on comparables. We project that the spillover effect of a foreclosure on neighborhood property values depends on two factors: the discount of foreclosure sale and the weight placed on the foreclosed property as a comparable in the valuation. The former is related to housing cycle and the latter varies by time of foreclosure and its distance from the subject property. Empirical results based on a 2006 sample show that this effect is significant within a radius of 0.9 km (roughly 10 blocks) and within 5 years from its liquidation. The most severe impact is an 8.7% discount on neighborhood property values, which gradually drops to anywhere between −1.2 to −1.7% for foreclosures liquidated within the past 5 years. These spillover effects vary slightly when the sample selection bias is taken into account. Based on an alternative sample of purchase transactions in 2003, the estimated spillover effects in booming years are reduced by half, confirming on the important role played by housing cycles.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Immergluck and Smith (2005) and Nassar (2007) both found that spatial concentration of subprime lending has led to concentrations of foreclosures in minority and modest-income neighborhoods, which is the emphasis of affordable housing goal. Recent home price depreciation or moderation has largely dampened the standing of this population.

  2. See Appendix for the “derivation” of the hypothesis.

  3. Data source: National Association of Realtors.

References

  • Baxter, V., & Lauria, M. (2000). Residential Mortgage Foreclosure and Neighborhood Change. Housing Policy Debate, 11, 675–699.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cannon, S., Norman, G. M., & Gurupdesh S. P. (2006). Risk and Return in the U.S. Housing Market: A Cross-sectional Asset-Pricing Approach. Real Estate Economics, 34(4), 519–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collins, M. (2003). Chicago’s Homeownership Preservation Challenge: Foreclosures, Mimeo, Joint Center for Housing Studies, Harvard University.

  • Cutts, A. C., & Green R. K. (2004). Innovative Servicing Technology: Smart Enough to Keep People in Their Houses? Freddie Mac Working Paper No. 04–03. Washington, DC: Freddie Mac. World Wide Web page <http://www.freddiemac.com/news/pdf/fmwp_0403_servicing.pdf> (accessed April 20, 2007).

  • Deng, Y., Pavlov, A. D., & Yang, L. (2005). Spatial Heterogeneity in Mortgage Terminations by Refinance, Sale and Default. Real Estate Economics, 33(4), 739–764.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deng, Y., Quigley, J. M., & Van Order, R. (2000). Mortgage Terminations, Heterogeneity and the Exercise of Mortgage Options. Econometrica, 68(2), 275–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Focardi, C. (2002). Servicing Default Management: An Overview of the Process and Underlying Technology. TowerGroup Research Note, No. 033-13C (November 15, 2002).

  • Forgey, F., Rutherford, R., & VanBuskirk, M. (1994). Effect of Foreclosure Status on Residential Selling Price. Journal of Real Estate Research, 9, 313–318.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, I., Maggie, M., Al, P., & Daniel, U.-A. (2005). Mortgage Foreclosure Filings in Pennsylvania. Philadelphia: Reinvestment Fund. World Wide Web page <http://www.trfund.com/policy/PA_Foreclosures.htm> (accessed April 22, 2007).

  • Goodman, J. L. (1992). A Housing Market Matching Model of the Seasonality in Geographic Mobility. Journal of the Real Estate Research, 8(1), 117–137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, A. C., & Thibodeau, T. G. (1997). Dwelling-Age-Related Heteroskedasticity in Hedonic House Price Equations: An Extension. Journal of Housing Research, 8(2), 299–317.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halverson, R., & Palmquist, R. (1980). The Interpretation of Dummy Variables in Semilogarithmic Regressions. American Economic Review, 70, 474–475.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, W., & Wolverton, M. (1996). The Relationship between Foreclosure Status and Apartment Price. Journal of Real Estate Research, 12, 101–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. (1979). Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Immergluck, D., & Smith, G. (2005). Measuring the Effects of Subprime Lending on Neighborhood Foreclosures: Evidence from Chicago. Urban Affairs Review, 40, 362–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Immergluck, D., & Smith, G. (2006). The External Costs of Foreclosure: The Impact of Single-Family Mortgage Foreclosures on Property Values. Housing Policy Debate, 17, 57–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, K. J. (1966). A New Approach to Consumer Theory. Journal of Political Economy, 74, 132–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lacour-Little, M. (2000). The Evolving Role of Technology in Mortgage Finance. Journal of Housing Research, 11(2), 173–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, Z., & Liu, Y. (2007). Real Estate Return and Risk with Heterogeneous Investors. forthcoming in Real Estate Economics.

  • Lin, Z., & Vandell, K. (2007). Illiquidity and Pricing Biases in the Real Estate Market. Real Estate Economics, 35, 291–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCarthy, G., VanZandt, S., & Rohe, W. (2001). The Economic Benefits and Costs of Homeownership: A Critical Assessment of the Research. Working Paper 01–02. Washington, DC: Research Institute for Housing America.

  • Moreno, A. (1995). The Cost-Effectiveness of Mortgage Foreclosure Prevention. Minneapolis: Family Housing Fund.

  • National Association of Realtors, Research Division. (2004). Rising Foreclosure Rates in Indiana: An Explanatory Analysis of Contributing Factors. World Wide Web page <http://www.mibor.com/_pdfs/ForeclosureStudy2004.pdf > (accessed April 16, 2007).

  • National Training and Information Center. (1999). Preying on Neighborhoods: Subprime Mortgage Lenders and Chicagoland Foreclosures. Chicago.

  • Rosen, S. (1974). Hedonic Prices and IMPLICIT Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure Competition. Journal of Political Economy, 82(1), 34–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simons, R. A., Quercia, R. G., & Maric, I. (1998). The Value of Residential Construction and Neighborhood Disinvestment in Residential Sales Price. Journal of Real Estate Research, 15(1/2), 147–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vandell, K. D. (1991). Optimal Comparable Selection and Weighting in Real Property Valuation. ARERUEA Journal, 19(2), 213–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vandell, K. D. (1995). How Ruthless Is Mortgage Default? A Review and Synthesis of the Evidence. Journal of Housing Research, 6(2), 245–264.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zhenguo Lin.

Additional information

We wish to thank editor C.F. Sirmans, an anonymous referee at the Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, and Paul Obrecht at Fannie Mae for their insightful comments and suggestions. All errors remain our own. The views expressed in this article are our own and do not necessarily represent the views of Fannie Mae. This article won a best research paper from the American Real Estate Society Foundation in 2007.

Appendix

Appendix

“Derivation” of the Hypothesis

The adjusted sale price based on each comparable sale price (i) is determined as follows,

$$ \widehat{P}_{{i,subject}} = P_{i} + {\sum\limits_{j = 1}^m {a_{j} {\left( {\Delta ^{{Characteristics{\text{ }}j}}_{{subject,i}} } \right)} + } }f{\left( {\Delta ^{{location}}_{{subject,i}} } \right)} + g{\left( {\Delta ^{{time\_sale}}_{{subject,i}} } \right)} $$
(A.1)

Thus, the final value estimate of the subject property can be computed as

$$\widehat{P}_{{subject}} = {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^n {W_{i} \widehat{P}_{{i,subject}} } }$$
(A.2)

The optimization problem for choosing weights and the number of comparable properties can be expressed as

$$\begin{aligned} & {\mathop {\min }\limits_{{\left( {n,W_{1} ,W_{2} ,...,W_{n} } \right)}} }{\left\{ {Var{\left( {{\sum\limits_{i = 1}^n {W_{i} \widehat{P}_{{i,subject}} } } - P_{{subject}} } \right)}} \right\}} \\ & {\text{ Subject\, to: }}\,\,\,{\text{ }}n \leqslant N{\text{ and }}{\sum\limits_{i = 1}^n {w_{i} = 1} } \\ \end{aligned} $$
(A.3)

When \( \operatorname{cov} {\left( {\widehat{P}_{{i,subject}} - P_{{subject}} ,\widehat{P}_{{k,subject}} - P_{{subject}} } \right)} = 0 \) for i ≠ k, then Eq. A.3 can be further simplified as,

$${\mathop {\min }\limits_{{\left( {W_{1} ,W_{2} ,...,W_{n} ,{\sum\limits_{i = 1}^n {W_{i} } } = 1,n \leqslant N} \right)}} }{\left\{ {{\sum\limits_{i = 1}^n {W^{2}_{i} } }\left. {\sigma ^{2}_{i} } \right)} \right\}}$$
(A.4)

where

$$ \sigma ^{2}_{i} = Var{\left( {\widehat{P}_{{i,subject}} - P_{{subject}} } \right)} $$

Generally speaking, the variance in Eq. A.4, \( \sigma ^{2}_{i} \), should increase with time and distance. We can thus hypothesize:

$$ \frac{{\partial \sigma _{i} }} {{\partial \Delta ^{{time\_sale}}_{{subject,i}} }} > 0{\text{, }}\frac{{\partial \sigma _{i} }} {{\partial \Delta ^{{location}}_{{subject,i}} }} > 0 $$
(A.5)

Eq. A.4 and A.5 suggest that,

$$ \frac{{\partial W_{i} }} {{\partial \Delta ^{{time\_sale}}_{{subject,i}} }} < 0{\text{, }}\frac{{\partial W_{i} }} {{\partial \Delta ^{{location}}_{{subject,i}} }} < 0 $$
(A.6)

Thus, we can expect that

$$ \frac{{\partial W_{k} {\left( {d,t} \right)}}} {{\partial d}} < 0{\text{ and }}\frac{{\partial W_{k} {\left( {d,t} \right)}}} {{\partial t}} < 0 $$
(A.7)

From Eq. 6, we thus have

$$ \frac{{\partial \Delta }} {{\partial d}} = \overline{\theta } * P_{k} * \frac{{\partial W_{k} {\left( {d,t} \right)}}} {{\partial d}} < 0 $$
(A.8)

and,

$$ \frac{{\partial \Delta }} {{\partial t}} = \overline{\theta } * P_{k} * \frac{{\partial W_{k} {\left( {d,t} \right)}}} {{\partial t}} < 0 $$
(A.9)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lin, Z., Rosenblatt, E. & Yao, V.W. Spillover Effects of Foreclosures on Neighborhood Property Values. J Real Estate Finan Econ 38, 387–407 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-007-9093-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-007-9093-z

Keywords

Navigation