Skip to main content
Log in

Learning as an emergent, creative process

A review essay on Joseph E. Stiglitz and Bruce C. Greenwald’s Creating a Learning Society

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In Creating a Learning Society, Joseph Stiglitz and Bruce Greenwald examine the role of knowledge in economic growth. They view economic growth as an impersonal and automatic phenomenon. The history of economic growth, however, suggests that it is a creative and personal process. We argue that the analytical framework deployed by Stiglitz and Greenwald is unsuited to study the creation of new products, new ways of doing things, and the discovery of new markets. While the questions Stigltiz and Greenwald ask are of fundamental importance, their analysis is neutered by the inability of their conceptual toolbox to grapple with creativity and novelty.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Pecuniary externalities occur when the actions of some agents change the prices faced by other agents. For example, when Firm A hires an additional worker, it increases the wage rate and reduces the profits of all other firms. Non-pecuniary externalities occur when the actions of some agents affect the utility or profits of other agents through a non-price channel. For example, when Firm A pollutes a river, it reduces the consumer welfare, without directly affecting the prices faced by consumers. When prices reflect opportunity costs, pecuniary externalities do not have negative welfare consequences. Non-pecuniary externalities always have negative welfare consequences. Stiglitz and Greenwald (1986) argue that in markets with asymmetric information pecuniary-externalities look a lot like non-pecuniary externalities. This is because with asymmetric information competitive prices do not reflect opportunity costs.

  2. In other words, a competitive equilibrium is in general not even constrained Pareto Efficient. Bernanke and Gertler (1990) provide an application of the Stiglitz-Greenwald Theorem. They study an economy in which lenders tell the quality of a borrower by observing their collateral. A subset of individuals does not make profitable investments because they do not have enough collateral, though they have good projects. An information-constrained government cannot use Lindhal Prices to allocate loans. However, a government can redistribute income, thereby reducing the number of individuals who are wealth-constrained, and increasing the number of loans. The redistribution of income does not require the government to have more information than market participants regarding which individuals have good projects.

  3. Many economists treat the desire of individuals to get ahead as if it is a recent phenomenon. It is not. The human desire to outcompete others can be observed throughout human history. Further, the broader psychology literature finds that envy occurs in all societies and economic arrangements, independent of the size or quantity of the object being envied (see Schoeck 1987: 77).

  4. And these non-price effects can extend into other areas and industries. For example, Ford employed wood scraps from building the Model-T to establish the Ford Charcoal Company which today is known as Kingsford’s Products Company (see Smith 2015).

  5. Nor is it sensible to make claims about the ‘inefficiency’ of monopoly by comparing its pricing behavior to that of a perfectly competitive market by assuming that both have the same cost curve. Costs of production are not technologically given; they are the consequence of human action. Cost curves reflect the relations between economic actors and are therefore endogenous to “market structure” (see Schumpeter 1942).

References

  • Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for ‘lemons’: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchain, A. A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. The Journal of Political Economy, 58(3), 211–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1951). An extension of the basic theorems of classical welfare economics. In J. Neyman (Ed.), Proceedings of the second Berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability (pp. 507–532). Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J., & Debreu, G. (1954). Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica, 22(3), 265–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axtell, R. (2005). The complexity of exchange. The Economic Journal, 115(504), F193–F210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1974). Are government bonds net wealth? Journal of Political Economy, 82(6), 1095–1117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, P. T. (2000). From subsistence to exchange. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: productive, unproductive and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 893–921.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (2002). The free-market innovation machine: Analyzing the growth miracle of capitalism. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1962). Irrational behavior and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 70(1), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Porath, Y. (1967). The production of human capital and the life cycle of earning. Journal of Political Economy, 75(4), 352–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B., & Gertler, M. (1990). Financial fragility and economic performance. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(1), 87–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J. (1994). The collapse of development planning. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1982). Order defined in the process of its emergence. Library of Economics and Liberty, available online: http://www.econlib.org/library/Essays/LtrLbrty/bryRF1.html

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Vanberg, V. J. (1991). The market as a creative process. Economics and Philosophy, 7(2), 167–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C. J. (2013). Doing bad by doing good: Why humanitarian action fails. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. (1959). Theory of value. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. The American Economic Review, 57(2), 347–359.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (2002). Toward a theory of property rights II. The Journal of Legal Studies, 31(S2), 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dupor, B., & Liu, W.-F. (2003). Jealousy and equilibrium overconsumption. The American Economic Review, 93(1), 423–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W. (2002). The elusive quest for growth. Massachusetts: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W. (2006). The white man’s burden. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, N. C. (1998). Emergentism, connectionism and language learning. Language Learning, 48(4), 631–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (2007). Falling behind: How rising inequality harms the middle class. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gode, D. K., & Sunder, S. (1993). Allocative efficiency of markets with zero-intelligence trades: markets are a partial substitute for individual rationality. Journal of Political Economy, 101(1), 119–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwald, B. C., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1986). Externalities in economies with imperfect information and incomplete markets. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101(2), 229–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, M. (2000). The human capital model. Handbook of Health Economics, 1, 347–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1976). Information and competitive price system. The American Economic Review, 66(2), 246–253.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. The American Economic Review, 70(3), 393–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1948). The meaning of competition. In: Individualism and economic order (pp. 92–106). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Hayek, F. A. (1952). The sensory order: An inquiry into the foundations of theoretical psychology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1998). Entrepreneurship and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 1(2), 45–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2003). The origins of entrepreneurial opportunities. The Review of Austrian Economics, 16(1), 25–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2007). Entrepreneurship and economic progress. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2009). Product differentiation and economic progress. The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 12(1), 17–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hughes, J. (1965). The vital few: The entrepreneur and American economic progress. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1992). The meaning of the market process. New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lal, D. K. (1983). The poverty of development economics. London: The Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D. (1986). The market as a procedure for discovery and conveyance of inarticulate knowledge. Comparative Economic Studies, 28(1), 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R. (2005). Happiness: Lessons from a new science. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewin, P. (1999). Capital in disequilibrium: The role of capital in a changing world. New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist, L., & Sargent, T. J. (2004). Recursive macroeconomic theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist, L., & Uhlig, H. (2000). Tax policy and aggregate demand management under catching up with the joneses. American Economic Review, 90(3), 356–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacLennan, B. (1993). Characteristics of connectionist knowledge representation. Information Sciences, 70(1–2), 119–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie, L. W. (1959). On the existence of general equilibrium for a competitive market. Econometrica, 27(1), 54–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. (1957). Theory and history. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Driscoll, G. P., & Rizzo, M. J. (2014). Austrian economics re-examined: The economics of time and ignorance. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potts, J. (2001). Knowledge and markets. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11(4), 413–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Read, L. E. (1958). I, Pencil. Irvington, NY: The Foundation for Economic Education.

  • Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002–1037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1994). New goods, old theory, and the welfare costs of trade restrictions. Journal of Development Economics, 43(1), 5–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, P. (2014). Emporiophobia (Fear of Markets): cooperation or competition? Southern Economic Journal, 80(4), 875–889.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schoeck, H. (1987). Envy: A theory of social behavior. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development: An inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business cycles. New York: McGraw-Hill. Reprinted in 2005 by Bartleby’s Books and Martino Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper & Brothers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1947a). Theoretical problems of economic growth. The Journal of Economic History, 7(1), 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1947b). The creative response in economic history. The Journal of Economic History, 7(2), 149–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (1962). An experimental study of competitive market behavior. The Journal of Political Economy, 70(2), 111–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, D. (2015). Like those charcoal briquettes you bought for your July 4th BBQ? Thank Henry Ford. Independent Journal, July 4. Available online: https://journal.ijreview.com/2015/07/245078-charcoal-light-4th-july-bbq-also-symbol-economic-freedom/

  • Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1), 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E., & Greenwald, B. C. (2014). Creating a learning society: A new approach to growth, development, and social progress. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stokey, N. L., & Lucas, R. E. (1989). Recursive methods in economic dynamics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swan, T. W. (1956). Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic Record, 32, 334–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, E. (1992). Prices and knowledge: A market-process perspective. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veetil, V. P. (2015). Out-of-equilibrium dynamics with heterogeneous capital goods. Mimeo.

  • Wagner, R. E. (2001). Competition as a rivalrous process: attilio da empoli and the years of high theory that might have been. Journal of Economic Studies, 28(4–5), 337–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2010). Mind, society and human action. New York: Routledge Taylor & Francis Group.

  • Williamson, C. R. (2009). Exploring the failure of foreign aid: the role of incentives and information. Review of Austrian Economics, 23(1), 17–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Dan Smith and Akshaya Vijayalakshmi for helpful discussion and suggestions for improvement.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christopher J. Coyne.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Coyne, C.J., Veetil, V.P. Learning as an emergent, creative process. Rev Austrian Econ 29, 415–428 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-015-0333-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-015-0333-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation