Skip to main content
Log in

Neutral money: Historical fact or analytical artifact?

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Long-run neutrality of money is an artifact of particular theoretical frameworks. We advance an alternative though not contradictory theoretical framework where monetary processes exert lasting real effects. Our framework holds without rejecting the classical equilibrium condition that nominal values are independent of economic realities because the two frameworks are non-commensurable. The real effects that we explore stem from the distribution of monetary injection among potential entrepreneurial experiments. The selected experiments influence the pattern of activity within society, which leads to changes in the standard given conditions of wants, knowledge, and expectations. These changes unravel into alternative paths of history.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On Cantilon’s work in general cf. Brewer (1992), von Hayek (1985 [1931]), Higgs (1891, 1892), Jevons (1881), Murphy (1987) and Spengler (1954a, b). For the discussion of his monetary thought see Bordo (1983). For the discussions that put Cantillon’s ideas on monetary process into historical context see von Hayek (1967 [1935], pp. 1 ff), Humphrey (1984, 1991) and Marget (1966a, b [1938–1942]).

References

  • Abrams, B. A., & Butkiewicz, J. L. (2012). The political business cycle: new evidence from the Nixon tapes. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44, 385–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies, 29, 155–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1974). Limited knowledge and economic analysis. American Economic Review, 64, 1–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertocco, G. (2007). The characteristics of a monetary economy: a Keynes–Schumpeter approach. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 31, 101–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordo, M. D. (1983). Some aspects of the monetary economics of Richard Cantillon. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 235–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brewer, A. (1992). Richard Cantillon: pioneer of economic theory. New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cantillon, Richard (2010 [1755]). An Essay on Economic Theory. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Clower, R. (1967). A reconsideration of the microfoundations of monetary theory. Western Economic Journal, 6, 1–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coddington, A. (1975). Review: creaking semaphore and beyond: a consideration of shackle’s ‘epistemics and economics. British Journal the Philosophy of Science, 26, 151–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan, R., & Rizzo, M. (1996). The genetic-causal tradition and modern economic theory. Kyklos, 49, 273–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Arista, J. (2009). The evolving international monetary system. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 33, 633–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe, P. (2010). Top-down versus bottom-up macroeconomics. CESifo Economic Studies, 56, 465–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldmann, H. (2006). Credit market regulation and labor market performance around the world. Kyklos, 59, 497–525.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster, A. D., & Rosenweig, M. R. (1995). Learning by doing and learning from others. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 1176–1209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G. (2008). Rationality for mortals. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grice-Hutchinson, M. (1978). Early economic thought in Spain, 1177–1740. London: Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haselmann, R., & Wachtel, P. (2010). Institutions and bank behavior: legal environment, legal perception, and the composition of bank lending. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42, 965–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, Friedrich August von (1985 [1931]). Richard Cantillon. Journal of Libertarian Studies 7: 217–47.

  • Higgs, H. (1891). Richard Cantillon. The Economic Journal, 1, 262–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Higgs, H. (1892). Cantillon’s place in economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 6, 436–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes, J. R. T. (1977). The governmental habit. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey, Thomas M. (1984). On nonneutral relative price effects in monetarist thought: some Austrian misconceptions. Federal ReserveBank of Richmond Economic Review 13–19.

  • Humphrey, Thomas M. (1991). Nonneutrality of money in classical monetary thought. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 3–15.

  • Jevons, W. S. (1881). Richard Cantillon and the nationality of political economy. Contemporary Review, 39, 61–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katzner, D. (1998). Time, ignorance, and uncertainty in economic models. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1978). Macro-economic thinking and the market economy. Menlo Park: Institute for Humane Studies. 1973.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1986). The market as an economic process. New York: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lastrapes, W. D. (2006). Inflation and the distribution of relative prices: the role of productivity and money supply shocks. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 38, 2159–2198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, T. (1997). Economics and reality. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, T. (2003). Reorienting economics. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, P. (Ed.). (2004). Transforming economics. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1996). Nobel lecture: monetary neutrality. Journal of Political Economy, 104, 661–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marget, A. W. (1966a [1938–1942]). The Theory of Prices: A Re-Examination of the Central Problems of Monetary Theory, Volume I. New York:Augustus M. Kelley.

  • Marget, A. W. (1966b [1938–1942]). The Theory of Prices: A Re-Examination of the Central Problems of Monetary Theory, Volume II. New York:Augustus M. Kelley.

  • Meltzer, A. H. (2011). Politics and the fed. Journal of Monetary Economics, 58, 39–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgenstern, O. (1972). Thirteen critical points in contemporary economic theory: an interpretation. Journal of Economic Literature, 10, 1163–1189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, A. E. (1987). Richard Cantillon: entrepreneur and economist. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Driscoll, G. P., & Rizzo, M. J. (1985). The economics of time and ignorance. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porta, L., Raphael, F. L.-d.-S., & Schleifer, A. (2002). Government ownership of banks. Journal of Finance, 57, 265–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potts, J. (2000). The new evolutionary microeconomics: complexity, competence, and adaptive behaviour. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). Theory of economic development, 2nd edn. New York: Oxford University Press.

  • Shackle, G. L. S. (1972). Epistemics and economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shackle, G. L. S. (1974). Keynesian Kaleidics. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snowdon, B., & Vane, H. R. (1998). Transforming macroeconomics: an interview with Robert E. Lucas Jr. Journal of Economic Methodology, 5, 115–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spengler, J. J. (1954a). Richard Cantillon: first of the moderns I. Journal of Political Economy, 62, 281–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spengler, J. J. (1954b). Richard Cantillon: first of the moderns II. Journal of Political Economy, 62, 406–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Hayek, F. A. (1967). Prices and production. New York: Augustus M. Kelly. 1935.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2010). Mind, society, and human action: time and knowledge in a theory of social economy. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2012a). A macro economy as an ecology of plans. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 82, 433–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2012b). Viennese Kaleidics. Review of Austrian Economics, 25, 283–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, L. H. (1999). The theory of monetary institutions. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard E. Wagner.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bilo, S., Wagner, R.E. Neutral money: Historical fact or analytical artifact?. Rev Austrian Econ 28, 139–150 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-014-0271-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-014-0271-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation