Skip to main content
Log in

1985: A defining year in the history of modern Austrian economics

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Mises and Hayek in the 1920s and 1940s thought of their work as within the orthodoxy of economic science. But after WWII it became increasingly obvious that the contributions of Mises and Hayek were out of step with the way the economics profession was evolving. But starting in 1974, due to the organizational efforts of Murray Rothbard and Israel Kirzner, and bolstered by the awarding of the Nobel Prize in Economic Science to FA Hayek, a resurgence of interest in Austrian economics by young scholars was initiated. Starting in 1984, but significantly in 1985, the work of the new generation of Austrian economics started to have an impact in the mainstream outlets in terms of journals and university presses. We argue that this is a defining year in the modern history of the Austrian school and that it reflected both the quality of work being done by the new generation as well as a methodological crisis within the mainstream of economic scholarship. Don Lavoie’s work in comparative economics, as well as his work in methodology, reflected this shift within the economic conversation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Vaughn (1994) for historical accounts of the South Royalton conference.

  2. McCloskey has continued to challenge the scientism within economics (see, for example, McCloskey 1994, 2008).

  3. See, for example, The Ultimate Foundation of Economic Science, originally published in 1962 and rescucitated in 1978 after South Royalton.

  4. The following is based on notes taken by Prychitko on September 9, 1985 in Lavoie’s Austrian Theory of the Market Process II course at George Mason University.

  5. To be sure, that evolution is not linear and often past ideas and insights are lost in an attempt to twist them into a narrative that claims that all that was worthwhile in earlier eras has already been successfully incorporated into the present. For more on this matter, see Boettke et al. (2010) contra-Whig defense of the history of thought.

  6. See Storr (2010) for a sympathetic challenge to this enterprise, which suggests that Lavoie need not have gone beyond Schutz to expound on his methodological points. Several years earlier Prychitko also challenged both Lachmann’s and Lavoie’s hermeneutical project. Prychitko (1994) evaluated Lachmann’s economics of the plan as being too embedded in the older hermeneutics of Dilthey, as opposed to Gadamer, which led him to focus almost exclusively on the mental intentions of individuals and didn’t clearly account for unintended consequences. Prychitko suggested that this approach colored Lachmann’s “equilibrium never” position, and that Gadamer’s more radical hermeneutics might better undergird the spontaneous order properties of markets. Later, Prychitko challenged Lavoie’s call for a vague “economics of meaning,” an interpretive framework that Lavoie developed in his introduction to his 1994 collection of Ludwig Lachmann’s essays. Prychitko felt Lavoie’s concern for hermeneutics lost sight of Lachmann’s primary theoretical concerns: a theory of capital and expectations. For more, see Prychitko (1997a, b) and Lavoie (1997).

References

  • Boettke, P. J. (1990a). The political economy of Soviet Socialism: The formative years, 1918–1928. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J. (1990b). Interpretive reasoning and the study of social life. Methodus: Bulletin of the International Network of Economic Method, 2(2), 35–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J. (1993). Why Perestroika failed: The politics and economics of socialist transformation. New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J. (2001). Calculation and coordination: Essays on socialism and transitional political economy. New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P.J., Coyne, C., and Leeson, P.T. (2010). “Contra-Whig history of economic ideas and the problem of the endogenous past.” Working Paper.

  • Caldwell, B. ([1982] 1994). Beyond positivism. New York: Routledge.

  • Dolan, E. G. (Ed.). (1976). The foundations of modern Austrian economics. Kansas City: Sheed and Ward.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ebeling, R. (1985). “Hermeneutics and the interpretive element in the analysis of the market process.” Center for Market Process Working Paper. George Mason University.

  • Grinder, W.E. (1977). “In pursuit of the subjective paradigm,” in L.M. Lachmann (1977), 3–24.

  • Hausman, D. M. (1984). The philosophy of economics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1948). Individualism and economic order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1971). The legacy of Max Weber. Berkely, CA: Univerity of California Glendessary Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1977). In W. E. Grinder (Ed.), Capital, expectations, and the market process: Essays on the theory of the market economy. Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews and McMeel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D. (1985a). Rivalry and central planning. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D. (1985b). National economic planning: What is left? Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D. (1986). “Euclideanism versus Hermenutics: A reinterpretation of Misesian Apriorism.”. In Israel M. Kirzner (Ed.), Subjectivism, intelligibility, and economic understanding: Essays in honor of Ludwig M. Lachman on his eightieth birthday (pp. 192–210). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D. (Ed.). (1990). Economics and hermeneutics. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D. (Ed.). (1994). Expectations and the meaning of institutions: Essays in economics by Ludwig Lachmann. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D. (1997). On regrouping the intellectual capital structure of Lachmann’s economics. Advances in Austrian Economics, 4, 219–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D. (2011). The interpretive dimension of economics—Science, hermeneutics, and praxeology. Review of Austrian Economics. doi:10.1007/s11138-010-0139-8.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D.N. (1983). “The rhetoric of economics,” Journal of Economic Literature 31 (June), pp. 431–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. N. (1985). The rhetoric of economics. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D.N. (1994). Knowledge and persuasion in economics. Cambridge University Press.

  • McCloskey, D. N. (2008). The cult of statistical significance: How the standard error cost us jobs, justice, and lives. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. (1949). Human action. Yale University Press.

  • Mises, L. (1978). The ultimate foundation of economic science. Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews and McMeel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. A., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Driscoll, G. P. (1977). Economics as a coordination problem. Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews and McMeel.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Driscoll, G. P., & Rizzo, M. J. (1985). The economics of time and ignorance. New York: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prychitko, D. L. (1991). Marxism and workers’ self-management. New York: Greenwood Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prychitko, D. L. (1994). Ludwig Lachmann and the interpretive turn in economics: A critical inquiry into the hermeneutics of the plan. Advances in Austrian Economics, 1, 303–309.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prychitko, D. L. (Ed.). (1995). Individuals, institutions, interpretations: Hermeneutics applied to economics. Brookfield, VT: Avebury.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prychitko, D. L. (1997a). “Lachmann’s plan, and its lesson: Comment on Lavoie”. Advances in Austrian Economics, 4, 209–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prychitko, D. L. (1997b). The dangers that court hermeneutics: Rejoinder to Lavoie. Advances in Austrian Economics, 4, 227–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. N. (1973). For a new liberty. New York: Collier Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storr, V. (2010). Schutz on meaning and culture. Review of Austrian Economics, 23(2), 147–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaughn, K. I. (1994). Austrian economics in America: The migration of a tradition. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • White, L. (1984). Free banking in Britain. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter J. Boettke.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Boettke, P.J., Prychitko, D. 1985: A defining year in the history of modern Austrian economics. Rev Austrian Econ 24, 129–139 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-011-0142-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-011-0142-8

Keywords

JEL Codes

Navigation