Skip to main content
Log in

Economists’ interest in collective decision after World War II: a history

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper tracks economists’ rising, yet elusive and unstable interest in collective decision mechanism after World War II. We replace their examination of voting procedures and social welfare functions in the 1940s and 1950s in the context of their growing involvement with policy-making. Confronted with natural scientists’ and McCathythes’ accusations of ideological bias, positive studies emphasizing that collective decisions mechanisms were unstable and inefficient, and normative impossibilities, economists largely relied on the idea the policy ends they worked with reflected a “social consensus.” As the latter crumbled in the 1960s, growing disagreement erupted on how to identify and aggregate those individual values which economists believed should guide applied work, in particular in cost-benefit analysis. The 1970s and 1980s brought new approaches to collective decision: Arrow’s impossibility was solved by expanding the informational basis, it was showed that true preferences could be revealed by making decision costly, and experimentalists and market designers enabled these mechanisms to be tested in the lab before being sold to those public bodies looking for decision procedures that emulated markets. In this new regime, the focus paradoxically shifted to coordination, revelation and efficiency, and those economists studying collective decision processes were marginalized.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The structure was borrowed from Dennis Mueller’s (1976) canonical survey, Pencavel explained. This anecdote is taken from Cherrier (2016).

  2. See Medema (2000) for a history of the early public choice movement.

  3. Mueller (1976, 2003) explains that collective decisions arise from market failures, and he frames all “the theory of the state, voting rules, voter behavior, party politics, the bureaucracy, and so on” in terms of collective decisions in a direct or representative democracy. Tideman (2006) defines collective decisions as the coordination of intended actions by members of a collectivity. He proposes a taxonomy of collective choice procedures and norms in which he distinguishes between those procedures designed to achieve assent to the decision (consensus, trade or extortion) and procedures requiring agreement to their use (authority, contest, voting).

  4. In his survey of the concepts of preferences, values, and choice, he explained that (1) economists have usually defined preferences in terms of valuations and (2) usually believe that agents choose the alternative that is at the top of their preference ranking. He concludes that choices, preferences ad valuations are difficult to disentangle in economic models.

  5. On the history of voting theory in particular, see McLean and Urken (1995) or Lagerspetz (2016).

  6. For an overview of the socialist calculation debate, see Levy and Peart (2008). See Amadae (2003) for an analysis of contributions by Abba Lerner, Maurice Dobb and Oskar Lange, and Boettke (2000) on Ludwig Von Mises and Friedrich Hayek’s arguments.

  7. Stigler himself conceded that in studying collective decision, economists were venturing into “applied ethics.”

  8. The dearth of knowledge in America concerning the “continental tradition” certainly motivated Musgrave and Peacock (1958) to publish a collection of texts from European theorists. James Buchanan contributed to the endeavor by selecting a few papers and translating some of Wicskell’s work.

  9. Bowen’s references to the political process largely were neglected by economists. A JSTOR search for papers published in economics journals from 1943 to 1950, and which refer to Bowen’s (1943) contribution, returns only one citation.

  10. Samuelson (1947, p. 250) also believed that “concretely, the new welfare economics is supposed to be able to throw light on such questions as to whether the Corn Laws should have been repealed” only to point out that it “gives no real hue to action.” Boulding (1952, p. 1) likewise insisted that “the contribution of welfare economics to the discussion of economic policy…is not too encouraging”, partly because it is not “a realistic guide to social policy.”

  11. Charles Tiebout (1956) quickly came up with a market solution to the problem of preference revelation, namely “voting with the feet”. Singleton (2015) explains how Tiebout developed the idea that citizens revealed their preferences by choosing among local communities proposing bundles of public goods and associated taxes.

  12. Marciano (2013) provides an archive-based survey of the exchanges between Buchanan and Samuelson on these topics.

  13. For instance, “we certainly wish to assume that the individuals in our society be free to choose, by varying their values, among the alternatives available,” he wrote (p. 338).

  14. Lindblom (1997, p. 246) remembers that the vast majority of political scientists in the 1940s and 1950s relied on a set of undisputed axioms, among which the notion “that stable governments require the consent of the governed; that some degree of agreement on values, at least among elites, is necessary for stability.”

  15. See Desmarais-Tremblay (2016) for a survey of Musgrave’s changing understanding of public goods.

  16. Most of them would move to the Virginia Polytechnic Institute in the late 1960s, where the Center for Study of Public Choice was then created. The Center moved in 1983 to George Mason University.

  17. As James March (1962, p. 671) also noted at the time, “most modern observers have viewed concepts of the ‘general will,’… as unsatisfactory concepts in the development of a theory of how political systems behave. ‘Public interest’ as a theoretical tool suffers from the standard problems of superordinate goals. It is almost impossible to make it simultaneously meaningful, stable, and valid.”

  18. Most of the details regarding the emergence of experimentation in economics, as well as mechanism design theory, are taken from Svorencik (2015), Lee (2016) and Plott (2014).

  19. See Jackson (2001, 2003) for a survey of the mechanism design and implementation literature, and Healy (2007) for a list of VGC’s shortcomings.

  20. Though Arrow always continued to claim that his theorem was relevant to Bergson-Samuelson’s work, he nevertheless used the terms “social choice function” and “constitutions” more and more to name his function. This longstanding controversy between Samuelson and Arrow, as well as its effects on welfare economics and social choice are thoroughly related in Igersheim (2016).

  21. Tucks (2007) argues that the void left by the lack of grand political philosophy syntheses was filled by economists’ purportedly ahistorical and universal concept of Pareto optimality to judge social arrangements.

  22. See, for instance, James Snyder's “collective choice” course at MIT: http://ocw.mit.edu/courses/political-science/17-812jcollective-choice-i-fall-2008/syllabus/ or curricula requirements at Columbia University’s Department of Philosophy (http://philosophy.columbia.edu/content/major-requirements). Collective decision courses have survived in those economics departments with a strong tradition in public or social choice. See, for instance, Bryan Caplan’s course outline at George Mason University (http://econfaculty.gmu.edu/bcaplan/e854/econ854.htm, Accessed 07/28/2016).

References

  • Amadae, S. M. (2003). Rationalizing capitalist democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T. H. (1995). The movement and the sixties. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1950). A difficulty in the concept of social welfare. The Journal of Political Economy, 58, 328–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1951). Social choice and individual values. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A., & Stiglitz, J. E. ([1980]1987). Lectures on public economics. New York: McGraw Hill.

  • Backhouse, R. (2010). Economics. In P. Fontaine & R. Backhouse (Eds.), The history of the social sciences since 1945. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf, S. (2009). Objective or multi-objective? Two historically competing visions for benefit cost analysis. Land Economics, 85(1), 3–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baujard, A. (2016). Welfare economics. In G. Faccarello & H. D. Kurz (Eds.), Handbook of the history of economic analysis (Vol. 3, pp. 611–623). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. M., DeGroot, M. H., & Marschak, J. (1964). Measuring utility by a single-response sequential method. Behavioral Science, 9(3), 226–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergson, A. (1938). A reformulation of certain aspects of welfare economics. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 52(2), 310–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berman, E. P. (2017). From economic to social regulation: How the deregulatory moment strengthened economists policy position. History of Political Economy, 49.

  • Bernstein, M. A. (2001). A perilous progress. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1948). On the rationale of group decision making. Journal of Political Economy, 56, 23–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1949). The theory of elections in single-member constituencies. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 15(2), 158–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J. (Ed.). (2000). Socialism and the market: The socialist calculation debate revisited. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Marciano, A. (2015). The past, present, and future of Virginia political economy. Public Choice, 163, 53–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boulding, K. (1952). Welfare economics. In F. Haley & H. S. Ellis (Eds.), A survey of contemporary economics. Homewood: Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boulding, K. (1970). Economics as a science. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowen, H. R. (1943). The interpretation of voting in the allocation of economic resources. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 58, 27–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breslau, D. (1997). Contract shop epistemology: Credibility and problem construction in applied social science. Social Studies of Sciences, 27(3), 363–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1949). The pure theory of government finance: A suggested approach. The Journal of Political Economy, 57, 496–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1951). Knut Wicksell on marginal cost pricing. Southern Economic Journal, 18(2), 173–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1954). Social choice, democracy and free markets. Journal of Political Economy, 62, 114–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1959). Positive economics, welfare economics, and political economy. Journal of Law and Economics, 2, 124–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The limits of liberty: Between anarchy and leviathan. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. ([1962]1967). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy, 2nd edn. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

  • Casella, A. (2012). Storable votes. Protecting the minority voice. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cherrier, B. (2017). Classifying economics: A history of the JEL codes. Journal of Economic Literature, 55(2).

  • Clarke, E. (1971). Multipart pricing of public goods. Public Choice, 11, 17–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claveau, F., Gingras, Y. (2016). Macrodynamics of economics: A bibliometric history. History of Political Economy, 48(4): 551–592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Council of Economic Advisers. (2008). Economic report of the president. Washington, DC: Council of Economic Advisers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. A., & Lindblom, C. E. (1953). Politics, economics and welfare. New York: Harper and Brothers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desmarais-Tremblay, M. (2017). Musgrave, Samuelson, and the crystalization of the standard rationale for public goods. History of Political Economy (forthcoming).

  • Diamond, P., & Mirrlees, J. (1971a). Optimal taxation and public. Production, part I: Production efficiency. American Economic Review, 61, 8–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A., & Mirrlees, J. A. (1971b). Optimal taxation and public production II: Tax rules. American Economic Review, 61, 261–278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckstein, O. (1961). A survey of the theory of public expenditure criteria. In National Bureau of Economic Research (Eds.), Public finances: Needs, sources, and utilization. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

  • Feddersen, T. J., & Pesendorfer, W. (1996). The Swing Voter’s Curse. The American Economic Review, 86(3), 408–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fleury, J.-B. (2010). Drawing new lines: Economists and other social scientists on society in the 1960s. History of Political Economy, 42(Suppl 1), 315–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1948). A monetary and fiscal framework for economic stability. The American Economic Review, 38(3), 245–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giraud, Y. (2014). Negotiating the ‘middle-of-the-road’ position: Paul Samuelson, MIT and the politics of textbook writing, 1945–1955. History of Political Economy, 46(5), 134–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groves, T. (1970). The allocation of resources under uncertainty: Doctoral dissertation, University of California Berkeley.

  • Guala, F. (2001). Building economic machines: The FCC auctions. Studies in History and Philosophy of Science, 32(3), 453–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, D. (2011). Preference, value, choice, and welfare. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Healy, P. (2007). Comment on “Thirteen reasons why the Vickrey-Clarke-Groves process is not practical” by Michael Rothkopf. Operations Research, 55(2), 191–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. The Economic Journal, 39(153), 41–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurwicz, L. (1972). On informationally decentralized systems. In R. Radner & C. B. McGuire (Eds.), Decision and Organization. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Igersheim, H. (2016). The death of welfare economics: History of a controversy. Working Paper.

  • Jackson, M. (2001). A Crash Course in Implementation Theory. Social Choice and Welfare 18: 655–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M. (2003). Mechanism Theory working paper. Retrieved February 7 2017. https://econ.ucsb.edu/~tedb/Courses/UCSBpf/mechtheo.pdf.

  • Jardini, D. (2013). Thinking through the Cold War: RAND, national security, and domestic policy. Meadowlands, PA: Jardini at Smashwords.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lagerspetz, E. (2016). Plurality, approval or Borda? A nineteeth century dispute on voting rules. Public Choice, 168(3), 265–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lalley, S. P., & Weyl, E. G. (2016). Quadratic voting, SSRN working paper dated 29 June 2016.

  • Lee, K. S. (2016). Mechanism designers in alliance: A portrayal of a scholarly network in support of experimental economics. History of Political Economy, 48(2), 191–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, D., & Peart, S. (2008). Socialist calculation debate. In S. Durlauf & L. Blume (Eds.), The New Palgrave dictionary of economics. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindblom, C. E. (1997). Political science in the 1940s and the 1950s. Daedalus, 126, 225–252.

    Google Scholar 

  • March, J. (1962). The business firm as a political coalition. The Journal of Politics, 24(4), 662–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marciano, A. (2013). Why market failures are not a problem: James Buchanan on market imperfections, voluntary cooperation, and externalities. History of Political Economy, 45(2), 223–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Margolis, J., & Guitton, H. (Eds.). (1969). Public economics: An analysis of public production and consumption and their relations to the private sectors. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskin, E. (2008). Mechanism design: How to implement social goals. American Economic Review, 98(3), 567–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLean, I., & Urken, A. (Eds.). (1995). Classics of social choice. Ann Arbor: Michigan University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Medema, S. G. (2000). Related disciplines: The professionalization of public choice. History of Political Economy, 32(Suppl 1), 289–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Medema, S. G. (2011). Public choice and the notion of creative communities. History of Political Economy, 43(1), 225–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (1976). Public choice: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 14(2), 395–433.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. (1939). The voluntary exchange theory of public economy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 53(2), 213–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. (1941). The planning approach in public economy: A reply. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 55(2), 319–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. (1948). Fiscal policy in prosperity and depression. The American Economic Review, 38(2), 383–394.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R. (1959). The theory of public finance. New York: McGraw and Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave, R., & Peacock, A. (1958). Classics in the theory of public finance. New York: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal, G. (1944). An American dilemma: The negro Problem and modern democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42(2), 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C. R. (2014). Public choice and the devleopment of laboratory modern experimental methods in economics and political science. Social Science Working Paper 1383.

  • Posner, E., & Weyl, E. G. (2014). Quadratic voting as efficient corporate governance. Working paper.

  • Ramsey, F. P. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. The Economic Journal, 38(152), 543–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, L. (1932). An Essay On the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E. (2002). The economist as engineer: Game theory, experimentation, and computation as tools for design economics. Econometrica, 70(4), 1341–1378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothenberg, J. (1967). Economic evaluation of urban renewal. Washington: The Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saez, E., & Stantcheva, S. (2016). Generalized social welfare weights for optimal tax theory. American Economic Review, 106(1), 24–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salles, M. (2005). The launching of Social Choice and Welfare and the creation of the “Society for Social Choice and Welfare”. Social Choice and Welfare, 25(2), 557–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuleson, P. (1947). Foundations of economic analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuleson, P. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditures. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1970). Collective choice and social welfare. London: Olivier & Boyd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singleton, J. (2015). Sorting Charles Tiebout. History of Political Economy, 47(Suppl 1), 199–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solberg, W. U., & Tomlinson, R. (1997). Academic McCarthyism and Keynesian economics: The Bowen controversy at the University of Illinois. History of Political Economy, 29(1), 55–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solovey, M. (Ed.). (2013). Shaky foundations: The politics-patronage-social science nexus in Cold War America. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1943). The new welfare economics. The American Economic Review, 33(2), 355–359.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svorencik, A. (2015). The experimental turn in economics. Phd Dissertation.

  • Svorencik, A. (2017). Allocating airport slots: The history of early applied experimental research. History of Political Economy (forthcoming).

  • Tideman, N. (2006). Collective decision and voting: The potential for public choice. Williston: Ashgate Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tideman, N., & Tullock, G. (1976). A new and superior process for making social choice. Journal of Political Economy, 84(6), 1145–1159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tuck, R. (2007). History In R. Goodin, P. Pettit, T. Pogge. (eds). A Companion to Contemporary Political Philosophy, (2nd edition, Vol I). Oxford: Backwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vickrey, W. (1961). Counterspeculation, auctions, and competitive sealed tenders. Journal of Finance, 16, 8–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Eric Posner, Glen Weyl, Roger Backhouse, Steven Medema, Vincent Merlin, Antoinette Baujard, Maxime Desmarais-Tremblay, Muriel Gilardone, Bernard Grofman, Herrade Igersheim, Alain Marciano, Dennis Mueller, Fabio Padovano, Maurice Salles and the participants at HISRECO (ENS-Cachan), at the “Bridging Public and Social Choice” conference (Center for Public Choice, University of Rennes I) and at the Quadratic Voting conference (Becker-Friedman Institute, University of Chicago). We acknowledge financial support from COST IC1205-Computational Social Choice and from INET.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Beatrice Cherrier.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cherrier, B., Fleury, JB. Economists’ interest in collective decision after World War II: a history. Public Choice 172, 23–44 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-017-0410-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-017-0410-7

Keywords

Navigation