Skip to main content
Log in

Vincent Ostrom’s revolutionary science of association

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Vincent Ostrom challenged epistemic choices at the foundation of modern political science and proposed an alternative conceptualization of democracy based on a theory of federalism he derived from The Federalist and Tocqueville’s Democracy in America. This essay examines Vincent Ostrom’s critique of contemporary mainstream political theorizing, relates his original theoretical work to the empirical research Elinor Ostrom, other colleagues, and he conducted, advised, or sponsored at The Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis Indiana University, and concludes that “Ostrom’s democratic alternative” constitutes an alternative scientific paradigm as defined by Thomas Kuhn. The paper concludes with a comment on the continuing relevance of Ostrom’s critique in the post-9/11 era.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. He also found common cause with other critics of the mainstream. Vincent Ostrom was a founding delegate to the April 1963 “no name” conference in Charlottesville and served as Society President (1967–1969), a duty also fulfilled by Elinor Ostrom (1982–1984).

  2. To distinguish the authorship of Vincent or Elinor Ostrom, parenthetical citations include the first initial. References in the text employ first and last names, except where the context clearly implies the author’s identity.

  3. The Workshop was renamed The Vincent and Elinor Ostrom Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis in honor of its founding co-directors. The author holds a Ph.D. in political science from Indiana University and was a student of Elinor Ostrom’s from 1994 to 1996. The author was not a student of Vincent Ostrom’s but acquired further interest in his work consequent to teaching courses on American political institutions.

  4. Barbara Allen’s commentary and a selection of essays and correspondence relating to Vincent Ostrom's work with the Alaska statehood constitutional convention in Volume 1 of The Quest to Understand Human Affairs: Natural Resources Policy and Essays on Community and Collective Choice (2011) describe how he came to realize the continuing relevance of constitutional choice to contemporary problems in policy analysis. The essays in Volume 2 of The Quest to Understand Human Affairs: Essays on Collective, Constitutional and Epistemic Choice (2012) provide examples of the global reach of his efforts to understand the terms and conditions of political experiments wherever communities of people attempt to govern themselves.

  5. Vincent Ostrom uses the term “art and science of association” with direct acknowledgment of Tocqueville’s extended examination of what citizens in a self-governing society would have to know in order to constitute a self-governing society (1994, pp. 211f.). Ostrom (2008b, pp. 65f.) refers to “democratic administration” as the “rejected alternative” of mainstream scholarship that favors bureaucratic administration. I use “Ostrom’s democratic alternative” in Table 1 below to refer to the whole of his theory of democratic self-government in a limited constitutional republic. McGinnis (2011) delivers a succinct and well-organized summary of Workshop language.

  6. For examples, see Acheson (2003), Blomquist (1992), Gibson (1999), Gibson et al. (2000), and E. Ostrom (1990).

  7. The question appears in the title of Robert Dahl’s seminal study of city government (Dahl 1961).

  8. Isaac is a former Dahl student and serves (2009 to present (2015)) as the Editor In Chief of Perspectives on Politics, a publication of the American Political Science Association.

  9. Fishkin is another former Dahl student who presently (2015) directs the Center for Deliberative Democracy at Stanford University. The quote appears in Dahl’s obituary posted on The New York Times website February 7, 2014.

  10. For examples, see Campbell et al. (1980), Green and Gerber (2004), and Nie et al. (1976).

  11. The essay was originally published in Savas (1977) and subsequently reprinted in V. Ostrom (1994).

  12. The Ostroms acknowledge Aristotle for an early description of the problems of common use and Samuelson (1954), Buchanan (1970), and Olson (1965, 1969) for later contributions to describing public goods.

  13. Coase (1960, 1974) made a similar point about the state of the discipline in economics when he wrote of institutional arrangements for providing and producing public goods and “bads” (i.e., social costs).

  14. Buchanan (1975) explores the conceptual basis for politics arising from contractarian (i.e., economically rational) reasoning, showing that multiple pathways to cooperative social orders are conceptually feasible.

  15. Concerning the importance of values and beliefs to effective constitutional limits on the power of governments, Vincent Ostrom and Buchanan appear in complete agreement. According to Buchanan (1975, p. 51), “Whether it is possible to constrain the powers of government… can never be proven empirically. It is at this point, however, that individuals’ attitudes toward reality seem more important than reality itself.”

  16. The passage quoted is reproduced in V. Ostrom (2011 [1991], p. 280).

  17. Hacker and Pierson (2010) provide an engaging example of this mode of argument. Constitutional arrangements subject to criticism include the Electoral College, Senate apportionment, and gerrymandering by state legislatures (Dahl 2002). The body of related commentary is extensive.

  18. The quoted passage by Barbara Allen refers to policymakers in the middle decades of the 20th century who were motivated to consolidate municipal governments by a newfound awareness of the interconnections among environmental, education, and law enforcement problems.

References

  • Acheson, J. (2003). Capturing the commons: Devising institutions to manage the Maine lobster industry. Hanover : University Press of New England.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aligica, P. D., & Boettke, P. J. (2009). Challenging institutional analysis & development: The Bloomington school. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aligica, P. D., & Boettke, P. J. (2011). The two social philosophies of Ostroms’ institutionalism. Policy Studies Journal, 39(1), 29–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, B. (2005). Tocqueville, covenant, and the democratic revolution: Harmonizing earth with heaven. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blomquist, W. (1992). Dividing the waters: Governing groundwater in southern California. Oakland, CA: ICS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1970). Public goods and public bads. In J. P. Crecine (Ed.), Financing the metropolis. Beverly Hills: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The limits of liberty: Between anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A., Converse, P., Miller, W., & Stokes, D. (1980). The American voter. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1974). The lighthouse in economics. Journal of Law and Economics, 17, 357–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. A. (1961). Who governs? democracy and power in an American city. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. A. (2002). How democratic is the American constitution?. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • De ATocqueville (1899 [1835, 1840]) Democracy in America (H. Reeve, Trans.) Charlottesville: University of Virginia.

  • Gibson, C. (1999). Politicians and poachers: the political economy of wildlife policy in Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, C., McKean, M. A., & Ostrom, E. (Eds.). (2000). People and forests: communities, institutions, and governance. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Godfrey-Smith, P. (2003). Theory and reality: An introduction to the philosophy of science. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Goldsmith, S., & Eggers, W. D. (2004). Governing by network: The new shape of the public sector. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, D. P., & Gerber, A. S. (2004). Get out the vote: How to increase voter turnout. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwald, G., & MacAskill, E. (2013). NSA Prism program taps into user data of Apple Google and others. The Guardian, 7(6), 1–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gross, T. (2013). ‘The watchers’ have had their eyes on us for years. Fresh Air from WHYY. Culve: National Public Radio.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hacker, J., & Pierson, P. (2010). Winner-take-all politics: How Washington made the rich richer-and turned its back on the middle class. New York: Simon & Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huntington, S. P. (1991–1992). How countries democratize. Political Science Quarterly, 106, 579–616.

  • Isaac, J. (2014). Robert Dahl as mentor. Washington: Monkey Cage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn, T. (1996). The structure of scientific revolutions (3rd ed.). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lasswell, H. (1958 [1936]) Politics: Who gets what, when, how? New York: Meridian Books.

  • Lasswell, H., & Kaplan, A. (1950). Power and society: A framework for political inquiry. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luker, K. (2008). Salsa dancing into the social sciences: Research in the age of info-glut. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, D. (2014). Robert A. Dahl, Yale scholar defined politics and power, dies at 98. New York: The New York Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K., & Engels, F. (1848). The communist manifesto. Canberra: The Australian National University.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGinnis, M. D. (2011). An introduction to IAD and the language of the Ostrom Workshop: A simple guide to a complex framework. Policy Studies Journal, 39(1), 169–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGinnis, M. D., & Ostrom, E. (2011). Reflections on Vincent Ostrom, public administration, and polycentricity. Public Administration Review, 72(1), 15–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGinnis, M. D., & Ostrom, V. (2012 [1999]) Democratic transformations: From the struggle for democracy to self-governance? in Ostrom, V. In: B. Allen, E. Ostrom (Ed.), The quest to understand human affairs: Essays on collective, constitutional, and epistemic choice (Vol. 2, pp.501–532). Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

  • Morello, C. and Mellnick, T. (2012). Seven of nation’s 10 most affluent counties are in Washington region, The Washington Post, (September 19, updated September 20) Web.

  • Nie, N., Verba, S., & Petrocik, J. (1976). The changing American voter. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1969). The principle of fiscal equivalence: the division of responsibility among different levels of government. American Economic Review, 59, 479–487.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, D., & Gaebler, T. (1993). Reinventing government: How the entrepreneurial spirit is transforming the public sector. New York: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1971). Institutional arrangements and the measurement of policy consequences: Applications to evaluating police performance. Urban Affairs Quarterly, 6, 447–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1977). Some problems in doing political theory: A response to Golembiewski’s ‘critique of ‘democratic administration’ and its supporting ideation’. American Political Science Review, 71(4), 1508–1525.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1980). Artisanship and artifact. Public Administration Review, 40(4), 309–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V., & Ostrom, E. (1994[1977]) Public goods and public choices: The emergence of public economies and industry structures in Ostrom, V. (1994) The meaning of American federalism: Constituting a self-governing society (pp. 163–97). San Francisco: ICS Press.

  • Ostrom, V. (1994). The meaning of American federalism: Constituting a self-governing society. San Francisco: ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1997). The meaning of democracy and the vulnerability of democracies: A response to Tocqueville’s challenge. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (2008a). The political theory of a compound republic: Designing the American experiment (3rd ed.). Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (2008b). The intellectual crisis in American public administration (3rd ed.). Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. American Economic Review, 100(3), 641–672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (2011 [1971]) An alternative approach to the design of public organizational arrangements, in Ostrom, V. In: B. Allen, E. Ostrom (Eds.), The quest to understand human affairs: Natural resource policy and essays on community and collective choice (Vol. 1, pp. 177–216). Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

  • Ostrom, V. (2011 [1999]) The centrality of local institutions in the constitution of democracies, in Ostrom, V. In: B. Allen, E. Ostrom (Eds.), The quest to understand human affairs: Natural resource policy and essays on community and collective choice (Vol. 1). Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

  • Ostrom, V. (2012 [1986]) Culture, liberation movements, and human development, in Ostrom, V. In: B. Allen, E. Ostrom (Eds.), The quest to understand human affairs: Essays on collective, constitutional, and epistemic choice (Vol. 2, pp. 219–252). . Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

  • Ostrom, V. (2012 [1991]) Some ontological and epistemological puzzles in policy analysis, in Ostrom, V. In: B. Allen, E. Ostrom (Eds.), The quest to understand human affairs: Essays on collective, constitutional, and epistemic choice (Vol. 2, pp. 253–296). Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

  • Ostrom, V. (2012 [1993]) Interpreting social experiments: An agenda for critical reflections and inquiry about a research program in comparative institutional analysis and development, in Ostrom, V. In: B. Allen, E. Ostrom (Eds.), The quest to understand human affairs: Essays on collective, constitutional, and epistemic choice (Vol. 2, pp. 297–321). Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

  • Ostrom, V. (2012 [1994]) Great experiments and the welfare state: Basic paradigmatic challenges, in Ostrom, V. In: B. Allen, E. Ostrom (Eds.), The quest to understand human affairs: Essays on collective, constitutional, and epistemic choice (Vol. 2, pp. 323–353). Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

  • Ostrom, V.,& Allen, B. (2012 [1994]) Studying democracy in America: Learning to be self-governing, in Ostrom, V. In: B. Allen, E. Ostrom (Eds.), The quest to understand human affairs: Essays on collective, constitutional, and epistemic choice (Vol. 2, pp. 455–500). Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

  • Ostrom, V. (2012 [1999]) Some requisites for understanding viable constitutional designs, in Ostrom, V. In: B. Allen, E. Ostrom (Eds.), The quest to understand human affairs: Essays on collective, constitutional, and epistemic choice (Vol. 2, pp. 394–406). Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

  • Ostrom, E., Gardner, R., & Walker, J. M. (1994). Rules, games, and common pool resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E.,& Parks, R. B. (1973) Suburban police departments: Too many and too small?. In: L. H. Masotti, J. K. Hadden (Eds.), The urbanization of the suburbs, 4 Urban Affairs Annual Review (pp. 367–402). Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.

  • Ostrom, E., Parks, R. B., & Whitaker, G. P. (1977). Policing metropolitan America. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V., Tiebout, C., & Warren, R. (1961). The organization of government in metropolitan areas: A theoretical inquiry. American Political Science Review, 55, 831–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., Walker, J. M., & Gardner, R. (1992). Covenants with and without a sword: Self-governance is possible. American Political Science Review, 86, 404–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1982). Liberalism against populism. Prospect Heights, IL: Waveland Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1986). The art of political manipulation. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salisbury, R. H. (1992). Interests and institutions: Substance and structure in American politics. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 36, 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savas, E. S. (Ed.). (1977). Alternatives for delivering public services: Towards improved performance. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schattschneider, E. E. (1960). The semi-sovereign people. New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1942) Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York: Allen & Unwin, excerpt reproduced in The democracy sourcebook [electronic resource]. In: R. Dahl, I. Shapiro, J. A. Cheibub (Eds.), Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

  • Searle, J. (1969). Speech acts: An essay in the philosophy of language. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Searle, J. (1998). Mind, language, and society: Philosophy in the real world. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, Ian. (1996). Democracy’s place. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, Ian. (2011). The real world of democratic theory. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economic and Management Science, 2, 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The National Commission on Terrorist Attacks upon the United States. (2004). The 9/11 commission report: Final report of the National Commission on Terrorist Attacks upon the United States (authorized ed.). New York: W.W. Norton & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Congress. Senate. Committee on Homeland Security and Governmental Affairs. Hurricane Katrina: a nation still unprepared, special report of the Committee on Homeland Security and Governmental Affairs together with additional views. One Hundred Fifth Congress, second session, Special Report, 109–322, (2006). New York: U.S. Congress

  • Van Riper, T. (2014). America’s richest counties 2014. Forbes, 145, 374–384.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (2011 [1940]). Interventionism: An economic analysis; edited and with a foreword by Bettina Bien Greaves. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.

  • Walker, J. L. (1991). Mobilizing interest groups in America: Patrons, professions and social movements. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wikipedia.org. (2013). List of United States federal legislation, 2001–present. June 22.

  • Wilson, W. (1887). The study of administration. Political Science Quarterly, 2, 197–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, W. (1956). Congressional government: A study in American politics. New York: Meridian Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This essay was prepared initially for presentation to the Yale Center for the Study of Representative Institutions and subsequently revised for presentation as part of the Colloquium series at The Vincent and Elinor Ostrom Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis Indiana University. The author thanks Danilo Petranovich of the Yale Center for setting that first deadline, Barbara Allen, Trevor Brown, Tyler Carlisle, Nathan O’Neill, Margaret Polski, Matt Potoski, and James Walker for their comments on early drafts, Patty Lezotte for a rich supply of Workshop papers and books without which this essay would not exist, Kate Fotos for proofreading, and Edward Lopez for editorial guidance, for pointing the author to James Buchanan’s work on related topics, and for shepherding this valuable symposium to publication.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael A. Fotos III.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fotos, M.A. Vincent Ostrom’s revolutionary science of association. Public Choice 163, 67–83 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0235-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0235-1

Keywords

Navigation