Skip to main content
Log in

How to get the snowball rolling and extend the franchise: voting on the Great Reform Act of 1832

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper suggests a new approach to analyzing the causes of franchise extension. Based on a new dataset, it provides a detailed econometric study of the Great Reform Act of 1832 in the United Kingdom. The analysis yields four main results. First, modernization theory receives limited support. Second, the reform enjoyed some measure of popular support. Third, the threat of revolution had an asymmetric impact on the voting behavior of the pro-reform Whigs and the anti-reform Tories. While the threat might have convinced reluctant reformers among the Whig politicians—and among their patrons—to support the bill, it seems to have hardened the resistance to reform among the Tories. Fourth, ideology played a critical role. Nevertheless, it also appears that self-interest and political expedience explained the votes of many Members of Parliament.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. “Rotten” boroughs were also known as “nomination” or “pocket” boroughs. They were constituencies that had been created in the Middle Ages and still returned MPs in the nineteenth century, even though they had by then lost the bulk of their population. The classic example of a “rotten” borough was Old Sarum, which only numbered 11 inhabitants in 1831.

  2. See among others Hettich and Winer (1988), Husted and Kenny (1997), Persson and Tabellini (2003), Aidt and Eterovic (2011), Aidt and Dallal (2008), and Aidt and Jensen (2009a, 2009b).

  3. Schonhardt-Bailey (1994, 1998, 2006) adopts a similar approach in her study of the repeal of the Corn Laws as well as in her study of industrial and agricultural interests in the German Parliament during the nineteenth-century. Galor and Moav (2006) also use a comparable methodology in their study of the voting patterns of the British MPs on the 1902 Balfour Act, which suggested a reform on the English education system. See also Greene (2008), who analyzes the survival strategies of dominant parties in authoritarian regimes when they face pressures to democratize by using sample surveys of leaders from the Revolutionary Institutional Party in Mexico in the 2000s. Finally, our study is closely related to Ziblatt (2008). He studies the failed 1912 attempt to reform the voting franchise governing elections in Imperial Germany and links the voting patterns on the reform to structural characteristics of the constituencies in which the legislators were elected. In particular, he shows that landholding inequality played a major role.

  4. The universities of Cambridge, Dublin and Oxford were self-governing bodies that returned MPs on a franchise that granted all graduates the right to vote. Cambridge and Oxford returned two MPs while the University of Dublin returned only one.

  5. These data are collected from Namier and Brooke (1964), Stookes Smith (1973), Thorne (1986), and various editions of Dod (various years).

  6. It must be noted that the categories are not mutually exclusive and many MPs are therefore recorded in more than one category, e.g., army officer and landowner. In our estimations, we use landowners as the control group.

  7. The influence of the patrons was also affected by the governance structure of a constituency. In the representative boroughs or in boroughs with officials appointed at the court leet of the lord (the court leet was a local court which could try and punish by jury crimes committed within its jurisdiction and its officials who served as local justices were appointed by the local patrons), the manor patrons could be very influential. In contrast, in boroughs with a municipal corporation, which consisted of a mayor, aldermen, burgesses and other officials, there was a body that, in principle, could curb the influence of local patrons.

  8. For some Welsh boroughs, we do not have definite information on the number of contested elections. We use these constituencies as the control group in the statistical analysis.

  9. The census and parliamentary districts do not overlap exactly. This should be kept in mind when studying the descriptive statistics. However, this does not limit the relevance of these data for our estimations for two reasons. First, it is reasonable to assume that the economic differences between the census and parliamentary districts are not important. Second, we use these data to assess the impact of the local economic circumstances in the elections, not to infer how individual voters voted. In any case, as we discuss below, most individuals did not have the right to vote under the rules of the Unreformed Parliament.

  10. The £10 cut-off was so high that a number of boroughs had very few voters. For example, Amersham with a population of 2612 would only have 25 £10 voters.

  11. The bill implied a total loss of 31 seats across England and Wales.

  12. To simplify the analysis, we assume in our estimations that Radicals and Whigs belong to the same political group (largely) in favor of reforms. In the following, we shall refer to them simply as the Whigs.

  13. In fact, on average, the constituencies in the sample did not experience any growth in the share of employment in the industrial sector between 1821 and 1831.

  14. Lizzeri and Persico (2004) also argue that the extension of the franchise was driven by a conflict of interest among the members of the elite, but they focus on conflicts along economic lines.

  15. Our data record only a limited number of characteristics of the MPs. One may be worried that some of these omitted factors are correlated with characteristics that we do observe. We cannot rule this out in general, but for some omitted factors it is unlikely to be a big issue. This is, for example, the case with respect to wealth, education, and religion. All of the MPs were relatively wealthy. Nearly all of them had attended Oxford or Cambridge at a time when one had to be Anglican to attend either one of these universities because of the Test and Corporation Act. Although that law was repealed in 1828 and the Catholic Relief Act was passed in 1829 so that Catholics and Dissenters could be elected in 1830 and 1831, all English MPs in our sample were Anglican. Thus, although these factors are omitted, they are unlikely to be correlated with any of the characteristics included simply because there is little or no variation across MPs.

  16. To the best of our knowledge, there is no reliable source on the precise number of electors in each constituency.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Why did the West extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4), 1167–1199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. A., & Yared, P. (2008). Income and democracy. American Economic Review, 98, 808–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. S., & Dallal, B. (2008). Female voting power: the contribution of women’s suffrage to the growth of social spending in Western Europe (1869–1960). Public Choice, 134(3–4), 391–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. S., & Franck, R. (2008). How to get the snowball rolling and extend the franchise: voting on the Great Reform Act of 1832 (Cambridge Working Papers in Economics 0832). Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge, UK.

  • Aidt, T. S., & Jensen, P. S. (2009a). Tax structure, size of government and the extension of the voting franchise in Western Europe, 1860–1938. International Tax and Public Finance, 16(3), 362–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. S., & Jensen, P. S. (2009b). The taxman tools up: an event history study of the introduction of the personal income tax, 1815–1941. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 160–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. S., Dutta, J., & Daunton, M. (2010). The retrenchment hypothesis and the extension of the franchise in England and Wales. Economic Journal, 120, 990–1020.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. S., & Eterovic, D. (2011). Political competition, participation and public finance in 20th century Latin America. European Journal of Political Economy, 27(1), 181–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ansell, B., & Samuels, D. (2010). Inequality and democratization: a contractarian approach. Comparative Political Studies, 43, 1543–1574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1999). Determinants of democracy. Journal of Political Economy, 107(6), S158–S183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon, F., & Verdier, T. (2000). Oligarchy, democracy, inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 62(2), 285–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock, M. (1973). The Great Reform Act. London: Hutchinson University Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cannon, J. A. (1973). Parliamentary reform, 1640–1832. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coll, S. (2008). The origins and evolution of democracy: an exercise in history from a constitutional economics approach. Constitutional Political Economy, 19(4), 313–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (2004). Economic development and democracy: does industrialization lead to universal suffrage? Homo Economicus, 21, 283–311.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (2007). From royal to parliamentary rule without revolution: the economics of constitutional exchange within divided governments. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 261–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (2011). Perfecting parliament. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dod (various years). Dod’s parliamentary companion. London: Dod.

  • Evans, E. J. (2000). Parliamentary reform, 1770–1918. London: Pearson Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2006). Das Human-Kapital: a theory of the demise of the class structure. Review of Economic Studies, 73(1), 85–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gundlach, E., & Paldam, M. (2009). A farewell to critical junctures. Sorting out the long-run causality of income and democracy. European Journal of Political Economy, 25, 340–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gradstein, M. (2007). Inequality, democracy and the protection of property rights. Economic Journal, 117, 252–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene, K. F. (2008). Dominant party strategy and democratization. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 16–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hettich, W., & Winer, S. (1988). Economic and political foundations of tax structure. American Economic Review, 78, 701–712.

    Google Scholar 

  • Himmelfarb, G. (1966). The politics of democracy: the English Reform Act of 1867. The Journal of British Studies, 6(1), 97–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horpedahl, J. (2011). Political exchange and the voting franchise: universal democracy as an emergent process. Constitutional Political Economy, 22(3), 203–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Husted, T. A., & Kenny, L. W. (1997). The effect of the expansion of the voting franchise on the size and scope of government. Journal of Political Economy, 105, 54–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janowitz, M. (1976). Military institutions and citizenship in western societies. Armed Forces and Society, 2, 185–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Justman, M., & Gradstein, M. (1999). The industrial revolution, political transition, and the subsequent decline in inequality in 19th-century Britain. Explorations in Economic History, 36, 109–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipset, S. M. (1960). Political man: the social basis of modern politics. New York: Doubleday.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2004). Why did the elites extend the suffrage? Democracy and the scope of government, with an application to Britain’s “Age of Reform”. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 707–765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llavador, H., & Oxoby, R. J. (2004). Partisan competition, growth, and the franchise. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(3), 1155–1192.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machin, I. (2001). The rise of democracy in Britain (pp. 1830–1918). London: Macmillan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moore, B. (1966). The social origins of dictatorship and democracy. Boston: Beacon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munshi, S. (2011). Enfranchisement from a political perspective. Constitutional Political Economy, 22(1), 21–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Namier, L. B., & Brooke, J. (1964). The House of Commons, 1754–1790. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Gorman, F. (1989). Voters, patrons and parties: the unreformed electoral system of Hanoverian England 1734–1832. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parliamentary Debates (various years). London: Hansard.

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Philbin, J. H. (1965). Parliamentary representation, 1832, England and Wales. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A. (2009). Conquered or granted? A history of suffrage extensions. British Journal of Political Science, 39, 291–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A., & Limongi, F. (1997). Modernization: Theories and facts. World Politics, 49(2), 155–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M. E., Cheibub, J. A., & Limongi, F. (2000). Democracy and development: political institutions and well-being in the world, 1950–1990. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. (2006). Economic development and democracy. Annual Review of Political Science, 9, 503–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schonhardt-Bailey, C. (1994). Linking constituency interests to legislative voting behavior: the role of district economic and electoral composition in the repeal of the Corn Laws. Parliamentary History, 13(1), 86–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schonhardt-Bailey, C. (1998). Parties and interests in the “marriage of iron and rye”. British Journal of Political Science, 28(2), 291–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schonhardt-Bailey, C. (2006). From the Corn Law to free trade: interests, ideas and institutions in historical perspective. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stookes Smith, H. (1973). The Parliaments of England. Chichester: Political Reference Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thorne, R. G. (1986). The House of Commons, 1790–1820. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. (1995). Popular contention in Great Britain, 1758–1834. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. (2004). Contention and democracy in Europe, 1650–2000. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971). The paradox of revolution. Public Choice, 11, 89–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma. The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: Center for the Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1987). Autocracy. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Whitfield, B. (2001). The Extension of the franchise, 1832–1931. Oxford: Heinemann Advanced History Series.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziblatt, D. (2006). How did Europe democratize? World Politics, 58, 311–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziblatt, D. (2008). Does landholding inequality block democracy? A test of the “bread and democracy” thesis and the case of Prussia. World Politics, 60, 610–641.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Omar Al-Ubaydli, Roger Congleton, Mark Gradstein, Hans Pitlik, James Robinson and David Samuels for helpful comments. Raphaël Franck gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Adar Foundation of the Economics Department at Bar Ilan University. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Raphaël Franck.

Electronic Supplementary Material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Online Appendices (PDF 178 kB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Aidt, T.S., Franck, R. How to get the snowball rolling and extend the franchise: voting on the Great Reform Act of 1832. Public Choice 155, 229–250 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9911-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9911-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation