Skip to main content
Log in

Positive constitutional economics II—a survey of recent developments

  • Literature Survey
  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Analysis of the economic effects of constitutional rules has made substantial progress over the last decade. This survey provides an overview of this rapidly growing research area and also discusses a number of methodological issues and identifies underresearched areas. It argues that the next logical step of positive constitutional economics is to endogenize constitutional rules.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (2005). Constitutions, politics and economics: a review essay on Persson and Tabellini’s the economic effects of constitutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 43(4), 1025–1048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2000). Why did the west extend the franchise? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1167–1199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91(4), 938–963.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2005). A response to Albouy’s ‘A reexamination based on improved settler mortality data’ (Mimeo). MIT.

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2006). The colonial origins of comparative development: an investigation of the settler mortality data (Mimeo). Reply to the revised (May 2006) version of David Albouy’s.

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J., & Yared, P. (2007). Reevaluating the modernization hypothesis (Working Paper 07–23). MIT Department of Econ WPS.

  • Ackerman, B. (2000). The new separation of powers. Harvard Law Review, 113(3), 633–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, Ph., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Endogenous political institutions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 565–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, Ph., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2005). Choosing electoral rules: theory and evidence from US cities (Disc. Paper 2065). Harvard Institute of Economic Research.

  • Albouy, D. (2008). The colonial origins of comparative development: an investigation of the settler mortality data (Working Paper, W14130). NBER, June 2008.

  • Alesina, A., Persson, T., & Tabelloni, G. (2006). Reply to Blankart and Koester’s political economics versus public choice—two views of political economy in competition. Kyklos, 59(2), 201–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alt, J., & Lassen, D. (2003). The political economy of institutions and corruption in American States. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 5(3), 341–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G., Shugart, W. II, & Tollison, R. (1989). On the incentives of judges to enforce legislative wealth transfers. Journal of Law & Economics, 32, 215–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G., Martin, D., Shugart, W. II, & Tollison, R. (1990). Behind the veil: the political economy of constitutional change. In W. Crain & R. Tollison (Eds.), Predicting politics—essays in empirical public choice (pp. 89–100). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aristotle (1932). The politics. London: Heinemann (with an English trans.: Rackham, H.).

    Google Scholar 

  • Arndt, Ch., & Oman, Ch. (2006). Uses and abuses of governance indicators. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1951). Social choice and individual values. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asian Development Bank (2005). Country governance assessment: Philippines. www.adb.org/Documents/Reports/CGA.

  • Austen-Smith, D. (2000). Redistributing income under proportional representation. Journal of Political Economy, 108(6), 1235–1269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. (1997). Determinants of economic growth: a cross-country empirical study. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (2000). Rule of law, democracy, and economic performance. In 2000 index of economic freedom (pp. 31–49). Washington: Heritage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (1997). Parliament as a wealth-maximizing institution: the right to the residual and the right to vote. International Review of Law and Economics, 17, 455–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barzel, Y. (2000). Property rights and the evolution of the state. Economics of Governance, 1(1), 25–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, Th., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, Ph., & Walsh, P. (2000). New tools and new tests in comparative political economy: the database of political institutions. Washington: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Bassat, A., & Dahan, M. (2008). Social rights in the constitution and in practice. Journal of Comparative Economics, 36, 103–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K. (2004). Models of electoral system change. Electoral Studies, 23, 363–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benz, M., & Stutzer, A. (2004). Are voters better informed when they have a larger say in politics?—evidence for the European Union and Switzerland. Public Choice, 119, 31–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, H., de Haan, J., & Eijffinger, S. (2001). Central bank independence: an update of theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Surveys, 15, 3–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berggren, N. (2003). The benefits of economic freedom: a survey. The Independent Review, 8(2), 193–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berggren, N., & Jordahl, H. (2005). Does free trade really reduce growth? Public Choice, 122, 99–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (2007). The new political economy. Economic Journal, 117(524), F570–F587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Payne, A. (2003). Judicial accountability and economic policy outcomes: evidence from employment discrimination charges (Mimeo). June 2003.

  • Blankart, C. (2000). The process of government centralization: a constitutional view. Constitutional Political Economy, 11(1), 27–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blankart, Ch., & Koester, G. (2006). Political economics versus public choice—two views of political economy in competition. Kyklos, 59(2), 171–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blomberg, S., Hess, G., & Weerapana, A. (2004). The impact of voter initiatives on economic activity. European Journal of Political Economy, 20(1), 207–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume, L., & Voigt, S. (2007). The economic effects of human rights. Kyklos, 60(4), 509–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume, L., & Voigt, S. (2008a). Federalism and decentralization—a critical survey of frequently used indicators. Available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1263995.

  • Blume, L., & Voigt, S. (2008b). The economic effects of federalism and decentralization—a cross-country assessment. Available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1307169.

  • Blume, L., Müller, J., & Voigt, S. (2009a). The economic effects of direct democracy—a first global assessment. Public Choice, 140, 431–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume, L., Müller, J., Voigt, S., & Wolf, C. (2009b). The economic effects of constitutions: replicating----and extending—Persson and Tabellini. Public Choice, 139, 197–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C. (1999). Setting the rules of the game: the choice of electoral systems in advanced democracies. American Political Science Review, 93(3), 609–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordignon, M., & Tabellini, G. (2008). Moderating political extremism: single vs. dual ballot elections. Available at: http://www.igier.uni-bocconi.it/files/Guido_Tabellini/btapril08final2.pdf.

  • Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Legislative organization and government spending: cross-country evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 309–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2002). Bicameral legislatures and fiscal policy. Southern Economic Journal, 68(3), 646–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1980). The power to tax. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Hamlin, A. (1994). A revisionist view of the separation of powers. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 6(3), 345–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Hamlin, A. (1995). Constitutional political economy: the political philosophy of homo economicus? The Journal of Political Philosophy, 3(3), 280–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Hamlin, A. (2000). Democratic devices and desires. Cambridge: CUP.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Hamlin, A. (2001). Constitutional choice. In W. Shughart & L. Razzoli (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (pp. 117–139). Cheltenham Glos: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Kliemt, H. (1994). Finite lives and social institutions. Kyklos, 47(4), 551–571.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1975). The limits of liberty—between anarchy and leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1987). The constitution of economic policy. American Economic Review, 77, 243–250.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent—logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carey, J. (2009). Does it matter how a constitution is created? In Z. Barany & R. G. Moser (Eds.), Is democracy exportable? New York: Cambridge University Press (forthcoming).

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, F., & Lundström, S. (2002). Economic freedom and growth: decomposing the effects. Public Choice, 112, 335–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colomer, J. (2005). It’s parties that choose electoral systems (or, Duverger’s law upside down). Political Studies, 53, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. (2003). On the merits of bicameral legislatures: policy stability within partisan polities. Jahrbuch für Neue Politische Ökonomie, 22, 29–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. (2006). On the merits of bicameral legislatures: intragovernmental bargaining and policy stability. In R. Congleton (Ed.), Democratic constitutional design and public policy, analysis and evidence (pp. 163–188). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R., & Swedenborg, B. (2006). Introduction: rational choice, politics, and political institutions: toward a science of constitutional design. In R. Congleton & B. Swedenborg (Eds.), Democratic constitutional design and public policy, analysis and evidence (pp. 1–36). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W. M., & Tollison, R. (1979). Constitutional change in an interest-group perspective. Journal of Legal Studies, 8, 165–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cusack, T., Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2007). Economic interests and the origins of electoral systems. American Political Science Review, 101(3), 373–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutrone, M., & McCarty, N. (2006). Does bicameralism matter? In B. Weingast & D. Wittman (Eds.), Oxford handbook of political economy (pp. 180–195). Oxford: OUP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, R. (2008). Direct democracy good governance: does it matter? In Sh. Bowler & A. Glazer (Eds.), Direct democracy’s impact on American Political Institutions. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davoodi, H., & Zou, H. (1998). Fiscal decentralization and economic growth: a cross-country study. Journal of Urban Economics, 43, 244–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Haan, J. (2007). Political institutions and economic growth reconsidered. Public Choice, 131, 281–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Haan, J., & Sturm, J. E. (2000). On the relationship between economic freedom and economic growth. European Journal of Political Economy, 16, 215–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Vanssay, X., & Spindler, Z. (1994). Freedom and growth: do constitutions matter? Public Choice, 78, 359–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, J. (1997). Guns, germs and steel: the fate of human societies. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diermeier, D., & Myerson, R. (1999). Bicameralism and its consequences for the internal organization of legislatures. American Economic Review, 89(5), 1182–1196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The new comparative economics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 595–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doucouliagos, H., & Ulubasoglu, M. (2008). Democracy and economic growth: a meta-analysis. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 61–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duverger, M. (1954). Political parties: their organization and activity in the modern state. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duverger, M. (1980). A new political system model: semi-presidential government. European Journal of Political Research, 8(2), 165–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eggertsson, T. (1990). Economic behavior and institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Elazar, D. (1995). From statism to federalism: a paradigm shift. Publius, 25(2), 5–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elkins, Z., Ginsburg, T., & Melton, J. (2009). The endurance of national constitutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1991). Arguing and bargaining in two constituent assemblies, the storrs lectures. New Haven: Gale Law School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1993). Constitution-making in Eastern Europe: rebuilding the boat in the open sea. Public Administration, 71(1/2), 169–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enikolopov, H., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2007). Decentralization and political institutions. Journal of Public Economics, 91(11–12), 2261–2290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, D., & O’Halloran, Sh. (1999). Delegating powers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Farber, D. (2002). Rights as signals. Journal of Legal Studies, 31, 83–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90, 980–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (2001). The political economy of direct legislation: direct democracy and local decision-making. Economic Policy, 33, 329–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Savioz, M. (1997). Direct democracy matters for economic performance: an empirical investigation. Kyklos, 50(4), 507–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Voigt, S. (2003). Economic growth and judicial independence: cross-country evidence using a new set of indicators. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3), 497–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Voigt, S. (2006). Making judges independent—some proposals regarding the judiciary. In R. Congleton & B. Swedenborg (Eds.), Democratic constitutional design and public policy, analysis and evidence (pp. 251–288). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., Kirchgässner, G., & Schaltegger, Ch. (2003). Decentralized taxation and the size of government: evidence from swiss state and local governments (Working Paper 1087). CESifo, December 2003.

  • Feld, L. P., Zimmermann, H., & Döring, Th. (2004). Federalism, decentralization and economic growth (Discussion Paper series “Fiscal federalism and national growth”, No. 1). University of Marburg, Germany.

  • Feld, L. P., Schaltegger, Ch., & Schnellenbach, J. (2008). On government centralization and fiscal referendums. European Economic Review, 52, 611–645.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. (1997). The politics of imperfection: the amendment of constitutions. Law and Scoial Inquiry, 22, 501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Figueiredo, R., & Weingast, B. (2005). Self-enforcing federalism. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 21(1), 103–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1983). Dimensions of election procedures: analyses and comparisons. Theory and Decisions, 15, 371–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2000). Happiness, economy and institutions. The Economic Journal, 110, 918–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2006). Direct democracy: designing a living constitution. In R. Congleton (Ed.), Democratic constitutional design and public policy—analysis and evidence (pp. 39–80). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Funk, P., & Gathmann, Ch. (2005). Estimating the effect of direct democracy on policy outcomes: preferences matter. Available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=784446.

  • Furubotn, E., & Richter, R. (1997). Institutions and economic theory: an introduction to and assessment of the new institutional economics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerring, J., & Thacker, S. (2004). Political institutions and corruption: the role of unitarism and parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science, 34, 295–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerring, J., Thacker, S., & Moreno, C. (2006). Are federal systems better than unitary systems? (Mimeo). Boston University.

  • Ginsburg, T. (2002). Economic analysis and the design of constitutional courts. Theoretical Inquiries in Law, 3(1), 49–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2004). Do institutions cause growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3), 271–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golden, M., & Picci, L. (2005). Proposal for a new measure of corruption, illustrated with Italian data. Economics & Politics, 17(1), 37–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldwin, R., & Kaufman, A. (Eds.) (1988). Constitution-makers on constitution-making. Washington: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grofman, B., & Lijphart, A. (Eds.) (1986). Electoral laws and their political consequences. New York: Agathon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, Ph. (1989a). Fiscal decentralization and government size: an extension. Public Choice, 62, 63–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, Ph. (1989b). Federalism and the growth of government revisited. Public Choice, 79, 19–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, Ph. (1992). Fiscal decentralization and public sector size in Australia. Public Choice, 68(202), 240–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, Ph., & West, E. (1994). Federalism and the growth of government revisited. Public Choice, 79(1–2), 19–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gürerk, Ö., Irlenbusch, B., & Rockenbach, B. (2005). On the evolvement of institution choice in social dilemmas (Mimeo). University of Erfurt.

  • Güth, W., Levati, V., & Sausgruber, R. (2005). Tax morale and (de-)centralization: an experimental study. Public Choice, 125, 171–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gundlach, E., & Paldam, M. (2009). A farewell to critical junctures: sorting out long-run causality of income and democracy. European Journal of Political Economy, 25(3), 340–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., & Block, W. (1996). Economic freedom of the world: 1975–1995. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R., & Jones, Ch. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1), 83–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, A., Madison, J., & Jay, J. (1961). The federalist papers—with an introduction, table of contents, and index of ideas by C. Rossiter. New York: Mentor.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanssen, A. (2004). Is there a politically optimal level of judicial independence? American Economic Review, 94(3), 712–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1939). Economic conditions of inter-state federalism. In The new commonwealth quarterly (pp. 131–149).

  • Hayek, F. (1976). Law, legislation and liberty: Vol. 2. The mirage of social justice. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayo, B., & Hefeker, C. (2002). Do we really need central bank independence? A critical re-examination. European Journal of Political Economy, 18, 653–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayo, B., & Voigt, S. (2007). Explaining de facto judicial independence. International Review of Law and Economics, 27(3), 269–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller, W. (1997). Bicameralism and budget deficits: the effect of parliamentary structure on government spending. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 22(4), 485–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. (2000). The institutional environment for economic growth. Economics and Politics, 12(1), 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. (2001). Public choice and economic growth. In W. Shughart & L. Razzoli (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (pp. 628–644). Cheltenham Glos: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hume, D. (1987). Essays—moral, political, and literary. Indianapolis: Liberty Classics (ed. and with a foreword, notes, and glossary: Miller, E. F.).

    Google Scholar 

  • Inman, R., & Rubinfeld, D. (1997). Rethinking federalism. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(4), 43–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Islam, M., & Winer, S. (2004). Tinpots, totalitarians (and democrats): an empirical investigation of the effects of economic growth on civil liberties and political rights. Public Choice, 118, 289–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2006). Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: why some democracies redistribute more than others. American Political Science Review, 100, 165–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Justesen, M. (2008). The effect of economic freedom on growth revisited: new evidence on causality from a panel of countries 1970–1999. European Journal of Political Economy, 24, 642–660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2007). Worldwide governance indicators project: answering the critics (Working Paper No. 4149). World Bank Policy Research. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=965077.

  • Keefer, Ph., & Stasavage, D. (2003). The limits of delegation: veto players, central bank independence and the credibility of monetary policy. American Political Science Review, 97(3), 407–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner, G., & Frey, B. (1990). Volksabstimmung und direkte demokratie: ein beitrag zur verfassungsdiskussion. In H. D. Klingmann, & M. Kaase (Eds.), Wahlen und wähler—analysen aus anlaß der bundestagswahl (pp. 42–69). Opladen: Westdeutscher.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knack, St. (2006). Measuring corruption in Eastern Europe and Central Asia: a critique of the cross-country indicators (Working Paper 3968). World Bank Policy Research.

  • Knack, St., & Keefer, Ph. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics, 7(3), 207–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P., & Berggren, N. (2004). Economic consequences of constitutions: a theory and survey. Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 14(1), 3–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurtz, M., & Schrank, A. (2007a). Growth and governance: models, measures, and mechanisms. Journal of Politics, 69(2), 538–554.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurtz, M., & Schrank, A. (2007b). Conceptualizing and measuring institutions: a view from political science (Mimeo prepared for 2nd Workshop). Measuring Law & Institutions held in Paris, Dec. 14 and 15, 2007.

  • Landes, W., & Posner, R. (1975). The independent judiciary in an interest-group perspective. The Journal of Law and Economics, 18(3), 875–911.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lascher, E., & Wassmer, R. (2007). Reconsidering claims about the secondary benefits of direct democracy (Mimeo). Department of Public Policy and Administration, California State University at Sacramento.

  • Lederman, D., Loayza, N., & Soares, R. (2005). Accountability and corruption. Economics & Politics, 17(1), 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. (2009). The calculus of piratical consent: the myth of the myth of social contract. Public Choice, 139(3–4), 443–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levmore, S. (1992). Bicameralism: when are two decisions better than one? International Review of Law and Economics, 12, 145–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1984). Democracies. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1994). A study of twenty-seven democracies 1945–1990. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of democracy—government forms and performance in thirty-six countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipset, S. M. (1959). Some social requisites of democracy: economic development and political legitimacy. American Political Science Review, 53(1), 69–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2001). The provision of public goods under alternative electoral incentives. American Economic Review, 91(1), 225–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2004). Why did the elites extend the suffrage? Democracy and the scope of government, with an application to Britain’s ‘Age of reform’. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 705–763.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lutz, D. (1994). Toward a theory of constitutional amendment. American Political Science Review, 88(2), 355–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macey, J. (1986). Promoting public-regarding legislation through statutory interpretation: an interest-group model. Columbia Law Review, 86, 223–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. (1995). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative: evidence from the last 30 years. Journal of Political Economy, 102(2), 587–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. (2000). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative in the first half of the twentieth century. Journal of Law & Economics, 43, 619–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. (2004). For the many or the few. The initiative, public policy, and American democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. (2005). Direct democracy works. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(2), 185–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McArthur, J. W., & Sachs, J. (2001). Institutions and geography: comment on Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson (2000) (Working Paper, 8114). National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER).

  • McCormick, R., & Tollison, R. (1981). Politicians, legislation, and the economy—an inquiry into the interest-group theory of government. Boston: Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, M., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: the invisible hand. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 72–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A., & Richard, S. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., Perotti, R., & Ristagno, M. (2002). Electoral systems and public spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(2), 609–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G., & Hammond, T. (1989). Stability and efficiency in a separation-of-powers constitutional system. In B. Grofman, & D. Wittman (Eds.), The federalist papers and the new institutionalism (pp. 85–99). New York: Agathon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montesquieu, Ch. L. de (1748/1989). The spirit of the laws. Cambridge texts in the history of political thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1st edn. in 1748, reprinted in 1989.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (1996). Constitutional democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (2007). Book review: Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini, the economic effects of constitutions. Constitutional Political Economy, 18, 63–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, C. B., Gil, R., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004). Do democracies have different public policies than nondemocracies? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(1), 51–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambrdige University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. (1999). An essay on fiscal federalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 1120–1149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. (2005). Toward a second-generation theory of fiscal federalism. International Tax and Public Finance, 12, 349–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olken, B. (2007). Monitoring corruption: evidence from a field experiment in Indonesia. Journal of Political Economy, 115(2), 200–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, P. (1993). Some rules of constitutional design. In P. E. Frankel, F. Miller, & J. Paul (Eds.), Liberalism and the economic order (pp. 198–232). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Padovano, F., Sgarra, G., & Fiorino, N. (2003). Judicial branch, checks and balances and political accountability. Constitutional Political Economy. 14(1), 47–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panizza, U. (2001). Electoral rules, political systems, and institutional quality. Economics & Politics, 13(3), 311–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. (2005). Forms of democracy, policy and economic development (Mimeo). January 2005.

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics—explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2002). Do electoral cycles differ across political systems? (Mimeo). Universities of Stockholm and Bocconi.

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2004). Constitutions and economic policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(1), 75–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2006). Democracy and development. American Economic Review, 96(2), 319–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2007). The growth effect of democracy: is it heterogenous and how can it be estimated? (Working Paper, 2016). CESifo.

  • Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (1997). Separation of powers and political accountability. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 310–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Comparative politics and public finance. Journal of Political Economy, 108(6), 1121–1161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (2004). How do electoral rules shape party structures, government coalitions, and economic policies? (Working Paper, 1115). CESifo.

  • Pommerehne, W. (1983). Private vs. öffentliche Müllabfuhr: Nochmals betrachtet. Finanzarchiv, 41, 466–475.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pommerehne, W. (1990). The empirical relevance of comparative institutional analysis. European Economic Review, 34, 458–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plümper, Th., & Martin, Ch. (2003). Democracy, government spending, and economic growth: a political-economic explanation of the Barro-effect. Public Choice, 117, 27–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A., & Limongi, F. (1993). Political regimes and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(3), 51–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramseyer, M. (1994). The puzzling (in)dependence of courts: a comparative approach. Journal of Legal Studies, 23(2), 721–747.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasch, B. E., & Congleton, R. (2006). Constitutional Amendment Procedures. In R. Congleton (Ed.), Democratic constitutional design and public policy—analysis and evidence (pp. 319–342). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1983). Political theory and the art of heresthetics. In A. Finifter (Ed.), Political science: the state of the discipline (pp. 47–67). Washington: American Political Science Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1984). The heresthetics of constitution-making: the presidency in 1787, with comments on determinism and rational choice. American Political Science Review, 78, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J., & Torvik, R. (2008). Endogenous presidentialism (Working Paper 14603). NBER.

  • Rodden, J. (2002). The dilemma of fiscal federalism: grants and fiscal performance around the world. American Journal of Political Science, 46(3), 670–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J. (2003). Reviving leviathan: fiscal federalism and the growth of government. International Organization, 57, 695–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J., & Wibbels, E. (2002). Beyond the fiction of federalism—macroeconomic management in multitiered systems. World Politics, 54, 494–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2008). Second-best institutions (Mimeo). Downloadable at http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~drodrik/Second-best%20institutions%20paper.pdf.

  • Roll, R., & Talbott, J. (2001). Why many developing countries just aren’t (Mimeo). UCLA.

  • Sartori, G. (1994). Comparative constitutional engineering. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scully, G. (2001). Institutions, policy, and economic growth. In W. Shughart & L. Razzoli (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (pp. 611–627). Cheltenham Glos: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seabright, P. (1996). Accountability and decentralization in government: an incomplete contracts model. European Economic Review, 40, 61–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1999). Development as freedom. Oxford: OUP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, M. (2005). Comparative electoral systems research: the maturation of a field and new challenges ahead. In M. Gallagher & P. Mitchell (Eds.), The politics of electoral systems (pp. 25–55). Oxford: OUP.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, W., & Tollison, R. (1998). Interest groups and the courts. George Mason Law Review, 6, 953–969.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, D., & Tolbert, C. (2004). Educated by initiative. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spindler, Z., & de Vanssay, X. (2002). Constitutions and economic freedom: an international comparison. South African Journal of Economics, 70(6), 1135–1146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stegarescu, D. (2005). Public sector decentralization: measurement concepts and recent international trends. Fiscal Studies, 26(3), 301–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutter, D. (1995). Potholes along the transition from authoritarian rule. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 39(1), 110–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutter, D. (2006). The deterrent effects of the international criminal court. In S. Voigt, M. Albert & D. Schmidtchen (Eds.), International conflict resolution. Conferences on new political economy (Vol. 23).

  • Sutter, M., Haigner, S., & Kocher, M. (2008). Choosing the stick or the carrot?—endogenous institutional choice in social dilemma situations (Working Papers). Economics and Statistics 2008–2007, University of Innsbruck, May 2008.

  • Taagepera, R., & Shugart, M. (1993). Predicting the number of parties: a quantitative model of Duverger’s mechanical effect. American Political Science Review, 87(2), 455–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanzi, V. (2000). Some politically incorrect remarks on decentralization and public finance. In J.-J. Dethier (Ed.), Governance, decentralization and reform in China, India and Russia (pp. 47–63). Boston: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tavares, J., & Wacziarg, R. (2001). How democracy affects growth. European Economic Review, 45, 1341–1378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Testa, C. (2009). Bicameralism and corruption. European Economic Review, 54(2), 181–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thießen, U. (2003a). Fiscal decentralization and economic growth in high income OECD countries. Fiscal Studies, 24(3), 237–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thießen, U. (2003b). Fiscal federalism in Western European and selected other countries: centralization or decentralization? What is better for economic growth. DIW, Berlin.

  • Thomas, M. (2006). What do the worldwide governance indicators measure? (Mimeo). Johns Hopkins University.

  • Ticchi, D., & Vindigni, A. (2010). Endogenous constitutions. Economic Journal, 120(543), 1–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, Ch. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: a cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 399–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, D. (2007). What have we learned about the causes of corruption from ten years of cross-national empirical research? Annual Review of Political Science, 10, 211–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G., & Money, J. (1997). Bicameralism. Cambridge: CUP.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma: the economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: University Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1987). Autocracy. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaubel, R. (1996). Constitutional safeguards against centralization in federal states: an independent cross-section analysis. Constitutional Political Economy, 7(2), 79–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (1997). Positive constitutional economics—a survey. Public Choice, 90, 11–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (1999). Explaining constitutional change—a positive economics approach. Cheltenham Glos: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (2003). Constitutional political economy: international library of critical writings in economics. Cheltenham Glos: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (2004). The consequences of popular participation in constitutional choice—towards a comparative analysis. In Aaken, List & Luetge (Eds.), Deliberation and decision (pp. 199–229). Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (2008). Explaining institutional change: on the interplay between internal and external institutions.

  • Voigt, S., & Kiwit, D. (1998). The role and evolution of beliefs, habits, moral norms, and institutions. In H. Giersch (Ed.), Merits and limits of markets (pp. 83–108). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S., & Salzberger, E. (2002). Choosing not to choose: when politicians choose to delegate powers. Kyklos, 55(2), 247–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S., & Wagener, H.-J. (2002). Constitutions, markets and law—recent experiences in transition economies. Cheltenham Glos: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Widner, J. (2007). The effects of constitution writing procedures on choice of terms and patterns of violence: some data, some observations, and many reasons for modesty (Working Paper). Stanford Workshop in Comparative Politics.

  • Wildasin, D. (1997). Externalities and bailouts: hard and soft budget constraints in intergovernmental fiscal relations (Mimeo). Nashville, Tn.

  • Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: an economic theory of dictatorship. American Political Science Review, 84(3), 849–872.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stefan Voigt.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Voigt, S. Positive constitutional economics II—a survey of recent developments. Public Choice 146, 205–256 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9638-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-010-9638-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation