Skip to main content
Log in

Strategic ratification

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Previous models of ratifier effects have relied on restrictive assumptions regarding the dimensionality of the choice space and the preferences and rationality of actors. These assumptions can lead to an underestimation of the importance of ratifiers and a mischaracterization of their role. A model presented here responds to these concerns and finds that when ratifiers are strategic, ratification requirements consistently aid negotiators in settings where previous models find no effects. Furthermore, new relations between the types of ratifier and the strength of their influence are identified. Negotiators benefit from in-group homogeneity on dimensions along which negotiators agree and from internal dissension on dimensions along which negotiators disagree.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Banks, J., & Duggan, J. (2000). A bargaining model of collective choice. American Political Science Review, 94, 73–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butler, C.K. (2004). Modeling compromise at the international table. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 21, 159–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dai, X. (2002). Political regimes and international trade: The democratic difference revisited. American Political Science Review, 96, 159–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, P., Jacobson, H., & Putnam, R. (1993). Double-edged diplomacy: International bargaining and domestic politics. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1995). Game theory. Cambridge: MIT University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haller, H., & Holden, S. (1997). Ratification requirement and bargaining power. International Economic Review, 38, 825–851.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, T.H., & Prins, B. (1999, September). The impact of domestic institutions on international negotiations: A taxonomy of results from a complete-information spatial model. Paper presented at the 95th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta.

  • Hayes, D., & Smith, A. (1997). The shadow of the polls: Electoral effects on international agreements. International Interactions, 23, 79–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hug, S., & König, T. (2002). In view of ratification: Governmental preferences and domestic constraints at the Amsterdam Intergovernmental Conference. International Organization, 56, 447–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hug, S. (September, 2004). Models of multilateral negotiations and ratification. Paper presented at the 2004 meetings of the American Political Science Association, Chicago.

  • Iida, K. (1993). When and how do domestic constraints matter? Two level games with uncertainty. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 34, 403–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iida, K. (1996). Involuntary defection in two level games. Public Choice, 89, 283–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E.D., Milner, H.V., & Rosendorff, B.P. (2000). Free to trade: Democracies, autocracies and international trade. American Political Science Review, 94, 305–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E.D., Milner, H.V., & Rosendorff, B.P. (2002). Replication, realism and robustness: Analyzing political regimes and international trade. American Political Science Review, 96, 167–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milner, H.V. (1997). Interests, institutions, and information: Domestic politics and international relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milner, H.V., & Rosendorff, B.P. (1997). Democratic politics and international trade negotiations: Elections and divided government as constraints on trade liberalization. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41, 117–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mo, J. (1994). The logic of two level games with endogenous domestic coalitions. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 38, 402–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mo, J. (1995). Domestic institutions and international bargaining: The role of agent veto in two-level games. American Political Science Review, 89, 914–924.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, M.J., & Rubinstein, A. (1994). A course in game theory. Cambridge: MIT University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pahre, R. (1997). Endogenous domestic institutions in two-level games and parliamentary oversight of the European Union. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41, 147–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: The logic of two-level games. International Organization, 42, 427–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A. (1982). Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica, 50, 97–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T.C. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ståhl, I. (1972). Bargaining theory. Mimeo. Stockholm School of Economics, Stockholm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tarar, A. (2001). International bargaining with two-sided domestic constraints. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45, 320–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tarar, A. (2004). Bargaining power, the schelling conjecture, and fast-track trade negotiating authority. Mimeo. Department of Political Science, Texas A&M University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tarar, A. (2005). Constituencies and preferences in international bargaining. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49, 383–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Macartan Humphreys.

Additional information

JEL Codes: C78, D74, F13

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Humphreys, M. Strategic ratification. Public Choice 132, 191–208 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-007-9143-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-007-9143-3

Navigation