Skip to main content
Log in

On the Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The effects of inflation are considered for a small open economy with overlapping generations and a cash-in-advance constraint on consumption. In an endowment economy with one good, the model recovers the adjustment mechanism underlying the monetary approach to the balance of payments, which incorporated the real balance effect in the savings function. Nevertheless, if the model has two goods that require different degrees of cash, the factor intensities of the goods also play a crucial role in determining the response of savings. In that case, the predictions of the monetary approach may be overturned; a result that is supported numerically.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Weil (1991) considers the effects of an increase in the rate of growth of money in a closed economy with money-in-utility of Sidrauski. Money-in-utility does not correspond to the assumption underlying the real balance effect. Mansoorian (2012) discusses the closed economy implications of the real balance effect in a model with overlapping generations and CIA on consumption.

  2. Cooley and Hansen (1991) work out the welfare implications of such asymmetric CIA constraints in a closed economy model. Mansoorian and Michelis (2010) work out some open economy implications of asymmetric CIA constraints in an infinite horizon (rather than an overlapping generations) model when both goods are traded, but one is durable.

  3. Engel and Kletzer (1990) and Mansoorian (1992) also emphasize the effects of changes in the value of titles to capital on savings in overlapping generations models with no money or non-traded goods.

  4. Notice, Eq. 4 has the standard interpretation that, with logarithmic utility, total expenditures at time t (c t (s)(1 + r + ε)) as a percentage of total lifetime expenditures (a t (s) + h t (s)) is equal to the weight attached to instantaneous utility at time t (θ + π).

  5. This assumption is convenient for our purposes, because by making the inflation rate exogenous, it abstracts completely from the off-steady state effects, arising from endogenous inflation, as emphasized by Fischer (1979). This paper is not concerned with whether inflation targeting is a superior policy. Cuche-Cueti et al. (2010) provide a comprehensive study of the advantages and disadvantages of inflation targeting versus a purely floating exchange rate system.

  6. To obtain Eq. 7, start by aggregating Eq. 4 over cohorts to obtain \(C_{t}=\frac {\theta +\pi }{1+r+\varepsilon }\left [ A_{t}+H_{t}\right ]\), which implies \(\dot {C}_{t}=\frac {\theta +\pi }{1+r+\varepsilon }\left [\dot {A}_{t}+\dot {H}_{t}\right ]\). Next, work out Ȧ t and t . First, consider the H t and t equations. Note \(H_{t}=\int _{-\infty }^{t}e^{\pi (s-t)}h_{v}(s)ds\), where \(h_{t}(s)=\int _{t}^{\infty }e^{(r+\pi )(t-v)}\left [ y+\tau _{v}(s)\right ] dv\), and hence t = (r + π)H t − (Y + Γ t ). Second, to obtain the equation for Ȧ t aggregate Eq. 3 over cohorts to obtain Ȧ t = r A t + Y + Γ t C t − (r + ε t )M t . Finally, substitute for t and Ȧ t into the expression for Ċ t using the results we have derived in this footnote, and use Eq. 5, together with the fact that A t = B t + M t , and hence Ȧ t = t + t , to obtain Eq. 7.

  7. Notice, for saddlepath stability when r > θ the Ċ = 0 locus must be steeper than that = 0 locus. Moreover, in the alternative case in which r > θ the Ċ = 0 will have a negative slope, and the intersection of the two curves will signify a negative steady state value for B, and, of course, a positive steady state value for C.

  8. In the alternative case that r < θ the increase in the inflation rate would lead to an increase in consumption and a current account deficit. Most would argue that r > θ is the more reasonable assumption in an overlapping generations model; and it is the assumption made in most of the growth literature.

  9. Non-traded goods consists mainly of services, while traded goods include all other goods. Services are traditionally more heavily financed with cash. Mansoorian and Michelis (2010) provide more details in this regard.

  10. This is a standard assumption made in the literature; see e.g., Engel and Kletzer (1990), and Matsuyama (1987, 1988).

  11. To derive this equation start from the no-arbitrage condition \(\dot {q}_{t}+r_{t}^{K}=rq_{t}\), multiply both sides by e r(tv) and then integrate by parts.

  12. To obtain Eq. 15, use the same methods as in Footnote 6 to obtain \(\dot {Z}_{t}=\frac {\theta +\pi }{1+\delta \left [ r+\varepsilon \right ] }\left [\dot {A}_{t}+\dot {H}_{t}\right ]\) and t = (r + π) H t − (w t + Γt). Now, however, to obtain the equation for Ȧ v aggregate Eq. 11 over cohorts to obtain \(\dot{A}_{t}=rA_{t} + w_{t}+ \Gamma_{t} - [1 + \delta (r + \varepsilon)] Z_{t}\). Finally, to obtain Eq. 15, substitute for \(\dot { H}_{t}\) and Ȧ t from the expressions we have derived in this footnote into the Ż t equation, use Eq. 5, and also note that \(\dot {q}_{t}=rq_{t}-r_{t}^{K}\).

  13. See, for example, Woodland (1982) for the properties of the GDP function, which will be used in several instances below.

  14. Notice, with logarithmic instantaneous utility specified in Eq. 8 the demand for the non-traded good at time t is given by Z t / p~ t

  15. Notice, this “distortion” effect involves the derivative of with respect to ε, which from the CIA constraint (16) involves the derivative of \(\frac {p_{t}}{\tilde {p}_{t}}\) with respect to ε. Now, as argued above, \(\frac {p_{t}}{\tilde {p}_{t}}\) is a measure of the distortion created by the fact that inflation implies an asymmetric tax on the traded and non-traded goods.

  16. Notice, as at any instant a fraction π of the population dies, while at the same time a fraction π is born, the population size stays constant over time. If we normalize the population size to unity, and use the assumption that each individual supplies one unit of labour at any instant throughout his lifetime, then total labour supply at any instant will be unity. This is the assumption used in the resource constraint \(L_{t}^{T}+L_{t}^{N}=1.\)

References

  • Altissimo F, Benigno P, Palenzuela DR (2011) Inflation differentials in a currency area: facts, explanations and policy. Open Econ Rev 22(2):189–133

    Google Scholar 

  • Balsam A, Eckstein Z (2013) Real business cycles in a small open economy with non-traded goods. http://sapir.tau.ac.il/papers/sapir-wp/9-00.pdf

  • Blanchard O (1986) Debts, deficits and finite horizons. J Polit Econ 93:223–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Cerra V, Tekin S, Turnovsky S (2009) Foreign transfers and real exchange rate adjustments in a financially constrained dependent economy. Open Econ Rev 20(2):147–181

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooley T, Hansen GD (1991) The welfare cost of moderate inflation. J Money Credit Bank 23:483–513

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooley T, Prescott E (1995) Economic growth and business cycles. In: Cooley T (ed)Frontiers of business cycle research. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 37–64

  • Corden WM, Neary JP (1982) Booming sectors and de-industrialisation in a small open eonomy. Econ J 92:825–848

    Google Scholar 

  • Cuche-Cueti N, Dellas H, Natal J-M (2010) Price stability and the case for flexible exchange rates. Open Econ Rev 21(1):3–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Eastwood RK, Venables AJ (1982) The macroeconomic implications of a resource discovery in an open economy. Econ J 92:285–299

    Google Scholar 

  • Engel C, Kletzer K (1990) Tariffs and saving in a model with new generations. J Int Econ 28:71–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer S (1979) Capital accumulation on the transition path in a monetary optimizing model. Econometrica 47:1433–1439

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel J, Mussa M (1985) Asset markets, exchange rates, and the balance of payments. In: Jones RW, Kenen PB (eds)Handbook of international economics, vol 2. Noth Holland, Amesterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansoorian A (1992) Income effect, wealth effect and the terms of trade with finite horizons. Can J Econ 25:474–484

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansoorian A (1996) On the macroeconomic policy implications of habit persistence. J Money Credit Bank 28:119–129

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansoorian A (2012) Money, capital and the Pigou effect. Econ Lett 117:354–356

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansoorian A, Michelis L (2010) Monetary policy in a small open economy with durable goods and differing cash-in-advance constraints. Econ Lett 107(2):246–248

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama K (1987) Current account dynamics in a finite horizon model. J Int Econ 23:299–313

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama K (1988) Terms of trade, factor intensities and the current account in a life-cycle model. Rev Econ Stud 55:247–262

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M (1981a) Capital mobility and devaluation in an optimizing model with rational expectations. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 71:217–221

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M (1981b) Macroeconomic policy, exchange rate dynamics and optimal accumulation. J Polit Econ 89:1142–1161

    Google Scholar 

  • Ryder HE, Heal GM (1973) Optimal growth with intertemporally dependent preferences. Rev Econ Stud 40:1–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen P, Turnovsky SJ (1989a) Deterioration of the terms of trade and capital accumulation: a re-examination of the Laursen-Metzler Effect. J Int Econ 26:227–250

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen P, Turnovsky SJ (1989b) Tariffs, capital accumulation and the current account in a small open economy. Int Econ Rev 30:811–831

    Google Scholar 

  • Shi S, Epstein LG (1993) Habits and time preference. Int Econ Rev 34:61–84

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidrauski M (1967) Inflation and economic growth. J Polit Econ 75:796–810

    Google Scholar 

  • Schubert S, Turnovsky S (2011) The impact of energy prices on growth and welfare in a developing open economy. Open Econ Rev 22(3):365–386

    Google Scholar 

  • Stolper W, Samuelson P (1941) Protection and real wages. Rev Econ Stud 9:58–73

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnovsky SJ (1997) International macroeconomic dynamics. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnovsky SJ (2000) Methods of macroeconomic dynamics, 2nd edn.MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa H (1968) Time preference, the consumption function, and optimal asset holdings. In: Wolfe JN (ed)Value, capital and growth: papers in honour of Sir John Hicks. Aldine Publishing Company, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Weil P (1991) Is money net wealth?Int Econ Rev 32:37–53

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodland A (1982) International trade and resource allocation, advanced textbooks in economics, vol 19. North-Holland Publishing Company, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank a referee and the editor for their very thoughtful comments and suggestions, which resulted in substantial improvements in this paper. I have also received very helpful comments from Leo Michelis. All the remaining errors are mine alone.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Arman Mansoorian.

Appendix

Appendix

In this Appendix we derive the saddlepath corresponding to the system of differential Eqs. 14, 15 and 17. Differentiating these equations totally, using (16), (18) and (19), we obtain

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \left[ \begin{aligned}{c} \dot{B}_{t} \\ \dot{Z}_{t} \\ \dot{q}_{t} \end{aligned} \right] =\left[ \begin{aligned} \alpha_{11} & \alpha_{12} & 0 \\ \alpha_{21} & \alpha_{22} & \alpha_{23} \\ 0 & \alpha_{32} & \alpha_{33} \end{aligned} \right] \left[ \begin{aligned}{c} B_{t}-\bar{B} \\ Z_{t}-\bar{Z} \\ q_{t}-\bar{q} \end{aligned} \right] \,, \end{array} $$
(31)

where bars denote steady state values, and the expressions for the coefficients α ij are as follows: α 11, α 11 = Ψ Z g p − 1, \(\alpha _{21}=-\frac {\pi (\theta +\pi )}{1+\left ( r+\varepsilon \right ) \delta }\), \(\alpha _{22}=r-\theta -\frac {\alpha \pi (\theta +\pi )}{1+r+\varepsilon }-\frac {\delta (1-\alpha )\pi (\theta +\pi )}{1+\left ( r+\varepsilon \right ) \delta }\), \(\alpha _{23}=-\frac {\pi (\theta +\pi )K}{1+\left ( r+\varepsilon \right ) \delta }\), α 32 = −Φ Z , and α 33 = r.

As B is the only predetermined variable in this system, for saddlepath stability the coefficient matrix should have one negative and two positive eigenvalues. A necessary condition for this is that the determinant Δ of the coefficient matrix for this system be negative. Let ξ denote the negative eigenvalue. Then the saddlepath of the system is given by the following equations:

$$ B_{t}-\bar{B}=\left(B_{0}-\bar{B}\right)\,e^{\xi \,t}, $$
(32)
$$ Z_{t}-\bar{Z}=-\;\frac{(\alpha_{11}-\xi )}{\alpha_{12}}\,\left( B_{0}-\bar{ B}\right) \,e^{\xi \,t}, $$
(33)
$$ q_{t}-\bar{q}=\;\frac{\alpha_{32}}{\alpha_{12}}\,\left( B_{0}-\bar{B} \right) \,e^{\xi \,t}. $$
(34)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mansoorian, A. On the Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments. Open Econ Rev 25, 721–737 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-013-9293-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-013-9293-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation