Skip to main content
Log in

An Anonymous Buyer of Intangible Property

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In a market for ideas, an intermediary often masks buyers’ information that is not to be exposed to the public. This article shows that such obscuration plays an important role in removing excess inertia because it prevents the emergence of a bandwagon effect among buyers. This model applies to outsourcing-type R&D competition. Although innovation is spurred, welfare implications are ambiguous because the competition among buyers becomes harsher than it is in the absence of the intermediary.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. SPILL: The wreck of the Exxon Valdez ( http://www.evostc.state.ak.us/facts/details.cfm)

  2. InnoCentive Solver Develops Solution to Help Clean Up Remaining Oil From the 1989 Exxon Valdez Disaster (http://www.innocentive.com/innocentive-solver-develops-solution-help-clean-remaining-oil-1989-exxon-valdez-disaster)

  3. A market for ideas (Economist, September 19th 2009, pp.69–70)

  4. Basic research cannot be generally patented. In addition, many countries limit patents of medical inventions.

  5. Arora and Fosfuri (2003) investigate licenses in detail.

  6. See Farrell and Saloner (1985). Our case is analogous.

  7. Patent grant delay may deter cooperation and licensing (Gans et al. 2008).

  8. Suppose that the firms who know the result of both calls compete after the second call phase. We define competition such that \(\pi _{i}(q_{i}) = (p_{i} - c_{i}) q_{i}\) (Cournot competition) and \(p_{i} = 1 - q_{i} - q_{j}\) (substitute goods). Assume that a firm can reduce its marginal cost from \(c = 1/5\) to zero by incurring an invention cost \(f = 1/20\). In the equilibrium, \(\pi _{i} = 1/9 - f\) if both innovate, \((1-c)^{2}/9\) if neither innovates, \((1+c)^{2}/9 - f\) if i innovates alone and \((1-2c)^{2}/9\) if \(j \neq i\) innovates alone. Then, the inequality \(1/9 - f < (1-c)^{2}/9\) holds, which holds if \(D<1\). Also, \(\{(1+c)^{2}/9-f\}+(1-2c)^{2}/9<(1-c)^{2}/9+(1/9 - f)\) is the counterpart of \(M+0<1+D\).

References

  • Anton JJ, Yao DA (2002) The sale of ideas: strategic disclosure, property rights, and contracting. Rev Econ Stud 69(3):513–531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora A, Fosfuri A (2003) Licensing the market for technology. J Econ Behav Organ 52(2):277–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1962) Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: Nelson RR (ed) The rate and direction of inventive activity. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 609–625

    Google Scholar 

  • Chesbrough H (2006) Open business models: how to thrive in the new innovation landscape. Harvard Business School Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Farrell J, Saloner G (1985) Standardization, compatibility, and innovation. RAND J Econ 16(1):70–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans JS, Stern S (2010) Is there a market for ideas? Ind Corp Chang 19(3):805–837

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans JS, Hsu DH, Stern S (2008) The impact of uncertain intellectual property rights on the market for ideas: evidence for patent grant delays. Manag Sci 54(5):982–997

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garella PG, Peitz M (2000) Intermediation can replace certification. J Econ Manag Strateg 9(1):1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagiu A, Jullien B (2011) Why do intermediaries divert search? RAND J Econ 42(2):337–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellman T, Perotti E (2011) The circulation of ideas in firms and markets. Manag Sci 57(10):1813–1826

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennes J, Schiff A (2008) Quality infomediation in search markets. Int J Ind Organ 26(5):1191–1202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri A (1999) Information revelation and certification intermediaries. RAND J Econ 30(2):214–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masters A (2007) Middlemen in search equilibrium. Int Econ Rev 48(1):343–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piatt JF, Ford RG (1996) How many seabirds were killed by the Exxon Valdez oil spill? In: American fisheries society symposium 18, pp 712–719

  • Topkis DM (1978) Minimizing a submodular function on a lattice. Oper Res 26(2):305–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yoichi Nishihara.

Appendix: Proofs

Appendix: Proofs

Lemma 1

Let us define \(\phi (a_{1},a_{2}):=U(a_{1},a_{1})+U(a_{2},a_{2})-U(a_{1},a_{2})-U(a_{2},a_{1})\), where \(a_{i} \in \{n,w,d\}\) and U is the payoff function of a firm. Then, \(\phi (n,w) = \lambda (1 + D - M)\), \(\phi (w,d) = (1 - \lambda ) (1-D+\theta _{i}+\rho )\) and \(\phi (n,d) = 1+D-M\) are non-negative, which prove supermodularity. In addition, the payoff function has decreasing differences in \((a_{i},\theta _{i})\). Hence, on the basis of Topkis (1978), a lower-type firm employs a higher-order strategy.

Proposition 1

When \(\theta _{i} = 1\), n dominates w and d for firm i because \(M-1 < D < 1\). Comparing n and w, we can see that \(\theta _{i} < D\) chooses w or d. Suppose, first, that some type chooses w or d. For a firm such that n and w are indifferent, \(\bar \theta = D\). In addition, \((1-\bar \theta )(M-\underline \theta )+ (\bar \theta -\underline \theta )(D-\underline \theta ) = (1-\underline \theta ) \cdot 1\) if w and d are indifferent. However, the solutions are \(\underline \theta < 0\) or \(\underline \theta > D = \bar \theta \), which is a contradiction. Next, suppose that w is not chosen. Then, the threshold between n and d occurs at \(\theta _{i} = \frac {M-1}{M-D} \in (0,D)\), but in the range between this threshold and D, a firm becomes better off by changing its strategy from n to w. Thus, d is excluded.

Lemma 2

Recall that an interior solution is assumed in Eqs. 1 and 2. These equations being transformed, we see that the thresholds must satisfy

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} (1-\bar\theta)(M-\bar\theta-1) + \left[\bar\theta + \underline\theta\left(\frac{1}{\lambda}-1\right)\right](D-\bar\theta) = \left[(1-\underline\theta) + \frac{\underline\theta}{\lambda}\right]\rho \end{array} $$
(3)
$$\begin{array}{rll} (1-\bar\theta) (M-\underline\theta-1) + (\bar\theta-\underline\theta)(D-\underline\theta-1) = (1-\underline\theta)\rho. \end{array} $$
(4)

By subtracting Eq. 4 from Eq. 3, we obtain

$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} \lambda\underline\theta + (1-\lambda)\bar\theta = D-\rho. \end{array} $$
(5)

The value function can be rewritten as

$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} V(\lambda,\rho) = \rho[\underline\theta-(1-\bar\theta)(1+D-M)] \end{array} $$

using Eqs. 4 and 5. For the agent to maximize its profit, \(\bar \theta \) and \(\underline \theta \) should be large. In addition to this, for any \(\rho \), \(\bar \theta \) and \(\underline \theta \) increase as \(\lambda \) increases in Eq. 5. Thus, \(\lambda = 1\) in equilibrium. For this proof, an intersection of Eqs. 4 (a quadratic curve that is downwardly convex) and 5 (a line) is checked in the \(\underline \theta -\bar \theta \) plane. The line always passes through the point \((D-\rho ,D-\rho )\) located under the rising quadratic curve. A larger. \(\lambda \) makes the slope of the line steeper (Fig. 1). The other intersection, \(\theta _{i} < 0\), should not be a solution.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Graphical Illustration for the Proof in Lemma 2

Now, w and d are indifferent for the firms, so we will consider that n and d meet at \(\bar \theta = \underline \theta \) determined as follows: \((1-\bar \theta ) M + \bar \theta D - \bar \theta - \rho = (1-\bar \theta ) \cdot 1 + \bar \theta \cdot 0\). By substitution of \(\bar \theta \), the optimization problem \(\max _{\rho } V|_{\lambda = 1} = \rho \bar \theta \) is transformed into \(\max _{\rho } \rho (M-1-\rho )\). The solution is \(\rho = \frac {M-1}{2}\).

Proposition 2

By Lemma 2, \(\lambda = 1\) and \(\rho = \frac {M-1}{2}\). At \(\underline \theta \),

$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} \underline\theta \cdot 1 + (1 - \underline\theta) \cdot 0 = \underline\theta M + (1 - \underline\theta) D, \end{array} $$

so the threshold \(\underline \theta = \frac {M-1}{2(M-D)}\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Nishihara, Y. An Anonymous Buyer of Intangible Property. J Ind Compet Trade 14, 511–518 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-013-0173-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-013-0173-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation