Skip to main content
Log in

Fairness constraints on profit-seeking: evidence from the German club concert industry

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Cultural Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Unlike Kahneman et al. (Am Econ Rev 76(4):728–741, 1986) iconic snow shovel, live music is a performance good that fans attach a particular value to. Hence, an artist’s pricing decision might differ from standard rent-seeking behavior. In this paper, I propose a model that incorporates fairness concerns into the pricing decision for concert tickets. The hypotheses derived from this model are tested on data from the German club concert industry. The results are consistent with the model: Although (1) price dispersion is the dominant pricing strategy in the club concert industry and artists prefer to perform on a Friday or Saturday night, (2) artists do not set higher prices on the weekend. These results are consistent with fairness constraints, but are difficult to explain within a standard profit maximization framework. As a third result, (3) the data reveal that ticket prices are positively correlated with a city’s number of inhabitants .

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As a consequence of the so-called “Napster crisis” or “MP3 crisis” (starting in the late 1990s caused by the digitization of recorded music), revenue from live performances became a major source of a musician’s income. See, for example, Connolly and Krueger (2006), Hull et al. (2011), Mortimer et al. (2012) or DiCola (2013). To put it pointedly: Recorded music serves to promote live music, as, e.g., the results of Nguyen et al. (2014) suggest.

  2. In addition, Rosen and Rosenfield (1997) provide an adequate analytical framework.

  3. Actually, the concert price is determined by a bargaining process between the artist, the artist’s management or booking agent and the local promoter. I will discuss this issue below.

  4. See Connolly and Krueger (2006) or Courty and Pagliero (2012) for a description of the players involved in this process.

  5. Or, as Marburger (1997) points out, it is rather the entry to the event that is sold.

  6. Eckard and Smith (2012) find empirical support for this assumption. In detail, they show that selling one more ticket does not have any statistically significant influence on total costs. Seliger (2012) gives an overview of the parameters that commonly determine the ticket price.

  7. This definition originates from Fehr and Schmidt (1999).

  8. Note that the capacity constraint S does not substantially affect results. The main difference is that \(\forall p\) such that \(D(p)\ge S\), \(\hbox {MR}=S\).

  9. See the Investor Relations site on http://www.eventim.de/.

  10. According to the Federal Statistical Office of Germany, the monthly average household net-adjusted disposable income per capita in Germany is 1710.09 EUR (taken from https://www.destatis.de).

  11. Regression analysis shows that the mean concert price tends to be higher if the artist performs longer sequences of events (at 10 % significance level). In contrast to Decrop and Derbaix (2014), foreign artists do not charge a higher price than their national colleagues within the sample.

  12. Note that the result is robust to a sample restriction to a subset of artists with at least five events.

  13. In two personal interviews, one with a professional booking manager from the German alternative music journal VISIONS and one with an agent from a well-established German booking agency, I was informed that event managers of a band’s club tour receive an uniform ticket price proposal. It is open to the local event manager to declare, for instance, higher costs, but in general they do not deviate. The booking managers explain this procedure with artists’ concerns about the fairness expectations of their fans.

  14. Technically, this means to include Düsseldorf, Stuttgart and Frankfurt.

  15. Note that this result is mainly driven by national artists as the effect is much weaker for foreign artists alone. As a possible explanation, tours of foreign artists include fewer concerts than national artists (see Sect. 3.1) but are more focused on metropolises (a share of 41.14 % vs. a share of 21.44 %). Hence, one would expect the deviation from the mean to be rather small.

References

  • Abbing, H. (2002). Why are artists poor? The exceptional economy of the arts. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1991). A note on restaurant pricing and other examples of social influences on price. Journal of Political Economy, 99(5), 1109–1116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, A. C., & Trivedi, P. K. (2010). Microeconometrics using stata (Revised ed., Vol. 5). Texas: Stata press College Station.

    Google Scholar 

  • Connolly, M., & Krueger, A. B. (2006). Rockonomics: The economics of popular music. Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, 1, 667–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Courty, P., & Pagliero, M. (2010). Price variation antagonism and firm pricing policies. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 75(2), 235–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Courty, P., & Pagliero, M. (2012). The impact of price discrimination on revenue: Evidence from the concert industry. Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(1), 359–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Courty, P., & Pagliero, M. (2014). The pricing of art and the art of pricing: Pricing styles in the concert industry. Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, 2, 299–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Serpa, A. C., & Faith, R. L. (1996). “Bru-uu-uce”: The simple economics of mob goods. Public Choice, 89(1–2), 77–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Decrop, A., & Derbaix, M. (2014). Artist-related determinants of music concert prices. Psychology & Marketing, 31(8), 660–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiCola, P. (2013). Money from music: Survey evidence on musicians’ revenue and lessons about copyright incentives. Arizona Law Review, 55, 301.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckard, E. W., & Smith, M. A. (2012). The revenue gains from multi-tier ticket pricing: Evidence from pop music concerts. Managerial and Decision Economics, 33(7–8), 463–473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichhorn, C., & Sahm, M. (2010). Why were fifa world cup tickets so cheap? monopoly pricing, demand quality and two-sided markets. Journal of Economic Psychology, 31(2), 212–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Englmaier, F., Gratz, L., & Reisinger, M. (2012). Price discrimination and fairness concerns. Discussion Paper

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Pommerehne, W. W. (1993). On the fairness of pricing—An empirical survey among the general population. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 20(3), 295–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hull, G. P., Hutchison, T. W., & Strasser, R. (2011). The music business and recording industry: Delivering music in the 21st century. London: Taylor & Francis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. (1986). Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market. The American Economic Review, 76(4), 728–741.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koenker, R., & Bassett, Jr. G. (1978). Regression quantiles. Econometrica, 46(1), 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenker, R., & Hallock, K. (2001). Quantile regression: An introduction. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(4), 43–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. B. (2005). The economics of real superstars: The market for rock concerts in the material world. Journal of Labor Economics, 23(1), 1–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levinson, J. (2013). Values of music. Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, 2, 101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marburger, D. R. (1997). Optimal ticket pricing for performance goods. Managerial and Decision Economics, 18(5), 375–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maxwell, S. (2002). Rule-based price fairness and its effect on willingness to purchase. Journal of Economic Psychology, 23(2), 191–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miravete, E. J. (2008). Price discrimination (theory). In S. N. Durlauf & L. E. Blume (Eds.), The New Palgrave dictionary of economics. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mortimer, J. H., Nosko, C., & Sorensen, A. (2012). Supply responses to digital distribution: Recorded music and live performances. Information Economics and Policy, 24(1), 3–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nguyen, G. D., Dejean, S., & Moreau, F. (2014). On the complementarity between online and offline music consumption: The case of free streaming. Journal of Cultural Economics, 38(4), 315–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okada, T. (2014). Third-degree price discrimination with fairness-concerned consumers. The Manchester School, 82(6), 701–715.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piron, R., & Fernandez, L. (1995). Are fairness constraints on profit-seeking important? Journal of Economic Psychology, 16(1), 73–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raux, C., Souche, S., & Croissant, Y. (2009). How fair is pricing perceived to be? An empirical study. Public Choice, 139(1–2), 227–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S., & Rosenfield, A. M. (1997). Ticket pricing. The Journal of Law and Economics, 40(2), 351–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rotemberg, J. J. (2011). Fair pricing. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(5), 952–981.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seliger, B. (2012). 40 euro fuers ticket, vier fuer die kuenstler. Berliner Zeitung, 03, 12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stole, L. A. (2007). Price discrimination and competition. Handbook of Industrial Organization, 3, 2221–2299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D. (1994). The production and consumption of the arts: A view of cultural economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 32(1), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vulkan, N., & Shem-Tov, Y. (2015). A note on fairness and personalised pricing. Economics Letters, 136, 179–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, C. C., Liu, Y. F., Chen, Y. J., & Wang, C. J. (2012). Consumer responses to price discrimination: Discriminating bases, inequality status, and information disclosure timing influences. Journal of Business Research, 65(1), 106–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Joachim Grosser, Hans-Jörg Schmerer and other faculty members for helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hendrik Sonnabend.

Additional information

This article received The President’s Prize. This prize was awarded to the best paper presented by a Ph.D. or postgraduate student at the 19th International Conference on Cultural Economics, Valladolid, Spain, June 2016.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sonnabend, H. Fairness constraints on profit-seeking: evidence from the German club concert industry. J Cult Econ 40, 529–545 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-016-9282-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-016-9282-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation