Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal redistributive pensions and the cost of self-control

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine how the introduction of self-control preferences influences the tradeoff between two fundamental components of a public pension system: the contribution rate and its degree of redistribution. The pension regime affects individuals’ welfare by altering how yielding to temptation (i.e., not saving, or saving less) is attractive. We show that proportional taxation increases the cost of self-control, and that this adverse effect is more acute when public pensions become more redistributive.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Krussel et al. (2010) studied a Ramsey tax problem with linear taxes in a single-agent model, and advocated late consumption and savings subsidies.

  2. See Frederick et al. (2002) for a historical survey of time-discounting.

  3. For simplicity, here we assume that individuals face no binding liquidity constraints and the absence of risks.

  4. Two of the standard assumptions of the standard decision-utility model are therefore generated by the geometric discount function: the fixed lifetime preferences condition and the no-mistake property (Bernheim and Rangel 2007).

  5. In particular, credit card and debt puzzles raised the issue that many households simultaneously hold high-interest credit card debts, while otherwise saving through devices that yield significantly lower returns (Laibson et al. 2003; Haliassos and Reiter 2005).

  6. In Ameriks et al. (2007), subjects were asked to allocate a prize over time. They were also questioned about their ideal plan, and about whether they expected to deviate from it. The authors used these data to construct an index called the “ideal-expected gap”, which was found to be correlated with present-biased behavior. So individuals act in full knowledge that they do not follow their ideal plan.

  7. Note that the pension plan’s budget is always balanced by definition, as is typical in linear-progressive tax models.

  8. It satisfies \(\varphi (0) = 0, \ \varphi '(0) = 0, \ \varphi '(L_{ijt})>0 ~\forall L_{ijt}>0\) and \(\varphi ''(L_{ijt})>0~\forall L_{ijt}>0\).

  9. The only requirement is that the problem must be globally concave, or that \(u''(c_{ijt}) + \lambda _{j} v''(c_{ijt}) < 0, \ \forall ij\).

  10. That \(\partial E(Y)/\partial \alpha > 0\) can be observed from the first-order conditions with respect to \(L_{ijt},\) although the comparative statics is highly intractable in our three-period model.

  11. This contrasts with paternalistic objectives found in models of quasi-hyperbolic discounting (as previously discussed) in which the government must choose how to interpret the preference reversal of individuals.

  12. Note that \(\alpha =1\) means that the sole role of the pension system is to force individuals to save. It can only happen when all individuals are identical in all respects, in which case pensions are perfect substitutes for savings. It does not happen here, since the distribution of wages is a motive for redistribution.

  13. In our simulations, all agents have positive savings when \(\pi =0\). As a consequence, the first-order conditions for labor depend solely on \((1-\alpha )\tau \) altogether. There is thus a degree of freedom in choosing the pair (\(\alpha ^{*}, \tau ^{*}\)). We report in this last line the value \((0, \tau ^{*}_{0})\) that satisfy the first-order condition. Any other pair satisfying \((1-\alpha )\tau = \tau ^{*}_{0}\) would work.

References

  • Ameriks, J., Caplin, A., Leahy, J., & Tyler, T. (2007). Measuring self-control problems. American Economic Review, 97(3), 966–972.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angeletos, G.-M., Laibson, D., Repetto, A., Tobacman, J., & Weinberg, S. (2001). The hyberbolic consumption model: Calibration, simulation, and empirical evaluation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(3), 47–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ariely, D., & Wertenbroch, K. (2002). Procrastination, deadlines and performance. Psychological Bulletin, 82, 463–496.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashraf, N., Karlan, D., & Yin, W. (2006). Tying odysseus to the mast: Evidence from a commitment savings product in the philippines. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), 635–672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumeister, R. F. (2002). Yielding to temptation: Self-control failure, impulsive purchasing, and consumer behavior. Journal of Consumer Research, 28, 670–676.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B. D., Skinner, J., & Weinberg, S. (2001). What accounts for the variation in retirement wealth among U.S. households? American Economic Review, 91, 832–857.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, D., & Rangel, A. (2007). Public economics: Welfare and policy analysis with non-standard decision-makers. In P. Diamon & H. Vartiaine (Eds.), Behavioral economics and its applications (pp. 7–77). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernhei, D., Ray, D., & Yeltekin, S. (2012). Poverty and self-control. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bucciol, A. (2011). A note on social security welfare with self-control problems. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 15, 579–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucciol, A. (2012). Measuring self-control problems: A structural estimation. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 668–675.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, H., de Donder, P., Maldonado, D., & Pestieau, P. (2008). Designing a linear pension scheme with forced savings and wage heterogeneity. International Tax and Public Finance, 15(5), 547–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, H., & Pestieau, P. (2011). Myopia, redistribution and pensions. European Economic Review, 55, 165–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, H., Habermann, C., & Kindermann, F. (2008). Social security with rational and hyperbolic consumers. Review of Economic Dynamics, 11(4), 884–903.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time-discounting and time-preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, XL, 351–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gul, F., & Pesendorfer, W. (2001). Temptation and self-control. Econometrica, 69(6), 1403–1435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gul, F., & Pesendorfer, W. (2004). Self-control and the theory of consumption. Econometrica, 72(1), 119–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haliassos, M. & Reiter, M. (2005). Credit card debt puzzles. Economics Working Papers 901, Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.

  • Huang, K., Liu, Z., & Zhu, Q. (2013). Temptation and self-control: Some evidence and applications. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imrohoroglu, A., Imrohoroglu, S., & Joines, D. H. (2003). Time-inconsistent preferences and social security. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(2), 745–784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby, K., & Herrenstein, R. (1995). Preference reversals due to myopic discounting of delayed reward. Psychological Science, 6, 83–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krussel, P., Kuruscu, B., & Simth, A, Jr. (2010). Temptation and taxation. Econometrica, 78, 2063–2084.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumru, C. S., & Thanopoulos, A. (2008). Social security and self-control preferences. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 32, 757–778.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumru, C. S., & Thanopoulos, A. (2011). Social security reform and self-control preferences. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 886–899.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 443–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D., Repetto, A., & Tobacman, J. (2003). A debt puzzle. In S. Phelps (Ed.), In knowledge, information, and expectations in modern economics (pp. 228–266). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, A., & Persson, M. (2003). The gains from pension reform. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 74–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. (1996). Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65, 272–292.

  • Mani, A., Mulainathan, S., Shafir, E., & Zhao, J. (2013). Poverty impedes cognitive function. Science, 341, 976–980.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mullainathan, S. & Banerjee, A. (2010). The shape of temptation: Implications for the economic lives of the poor. NBER Working Papers.

  • Phelps, E. S., & Pollak, R. (1968). On second-best national saving and game-equilibrium growth. Review of Economic Studies, 35, 185–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1937). A note on measurement of utility. Review of Economic Studies, 4, 155–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shah, A., Mulainatha, S., & Shafir, E. (2012). Some consequences of having too little. Science, 338, 682–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spears, D. (2011). Economic decision-making in poverty depletes behavioral control. B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 11, 72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strotz, R. H. (1955). Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utlity maximization. Review of Economic Studies, 23, 165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wertenbroch, K. (1998). Consumption self-control by rationing purchase quantities of virtue and vice. Marketing Science, 17, 317–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Charles Bellemarre, Robin Boadway, Helmuch Cremer, Sean Horan, Sumon Majumdar, Pierre-Carl Michaud, Marie-Louise Vierø, Tim Worall, Pierre-Yves Yanni, seminar participants at Université Laval and two anonymous referees for their suggestions and comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jean-Denis Garon.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bouchard St-Amant, PA., Garon, JD. Optimal redistributive pensions and the cost of self-control. Int Tax Public Finance 22, 723–740 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-014-9331-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-014-9331-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation