Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Part-time unemployment and optimal unemployment insurance

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A significant fraction of the labor force consists of employed workers who are part-time unemployed (underemployed) in the sense that they are unable to work as much as they prefer. This paper studies the design of optimal unemployment insurance in an economy with unemployment as well as part-time unemployment. Part-time work provides income insurance and serves as a stepping stone to full-time jobs. Unemployment benefits for part-timers reduce the outflow from part-time work to full-time employment. However, such benefits also increase the outflow from unemployment to part-time work, thereby reducing unemployment. We examine the optimal structure of benefits for unemployed and underemployed workers. The results indicate that there are welfare gains from part-time benefits. Moreover, there are welfare gains associated with time limits for unemployment benefits as well as for part-time benefits. The welfare gains from optimal insurance are larger when wages are fixed than when they are flexible.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The terms part-time unemployment and underemployment will henceforth be used interchangeably.

  2. See OECD (2010), Fig. 1.5, and the relevant source table.

  3. The problem of separating causal effects from selection effects is addressed (“timing of events approach”) in Kyyrä (2010) and Kyyrä et al. (2013) but not in the Swedish study. For more information on the empirical literature on part-time unemployment, see Kyyrä (2010).

  4. See Fredriksson and Holmlund (2006) and Tatsiramos and van Ours (2012) for surveys.

  5. Panel data from the Swedish labor force statistics reveal substantial mobility out of part-time unemployment. Over the period 2005–2009, some 20–25 % of the part-timers searching for full-time jobs have entered full-time work after one quarter.

  6. Other search and matching models that feature heterogeneous jobs and on-the-job search include Gautier (2002) and Dolado et al. (2009). Gautier considers simple and complex jobs, whereas Dolado et al. refer to the jobs as either skilled or unskilled.

  7. Benefits are taxable income in some countries, including Denmark, Finland, Sweden, and the US. The assumption here is not crucial; we could redo the analysis with nontaxed benefits and obtain essentially the same result. The key assumptions are proportional taxation on earnings and indexation of net benefits to after-tax wages.

  8. The value functions above imply that a job loss for a part-timer results in the same income as is available for a full-time employed worker if laid off. This is realistic for some countries to the extent that the part-timer has a history of full-time work.

  9. To obtain these present value differences, it is useful to deduct Eq. (9) from (8) and deduct (10) from (8) and (9).

  10. The case with full-time as well as part-time jobs is an example of a labor market where workers face jobs of different qualities. Although compensating wage differentials are conceivable in theory, evidence shows that such differentials are pervasively absent in practice (Bonhomme and Jolivet 2009).

  11. This condition is indeed fulfilled in all numerical simulations and robustness checks.

  12. The envelope condition \(\partial P/\partial s_{p}=0\) applies; the part-timers choose search effort optimally.

  13. Wages generally differ between full-timers and part-timers. Our results are virtually independent of the choice of wage concept in the definition of replacement rate.

  14. We focus on log utility which involves relatively low risk aversion. Higher risk aversion implies overall more generous optimal UI. However, the model ignores savings which arguably may overstate the case for part-time benefits if there is substantial risk aversion.

  15. Preliminary work on a model with worker heterogeneity and both voluntary and involuntary part-time work suggest that positive part-time benefits would be optimal even if the policy maker is unable to observe worker types (see Ek and Holmlund 2011). Another dimension of moral hazard that is not dealt with concerns the incentives that workers and/or firms may have to misreport hours of work.

References

  • Bonhomme, S., & Jolivet, G. (2009). The pervasive absence of compensating wage differentials. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 24, 763–795.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A., Francesconi, M., & Frank, J. (2002). Temporary jobs: Stepping stones or dead ends? Economic Journal, 112, F189–F213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brenke, K., Rinne, U. & Zimmermann, K. (2011). Short-time work: The German answer to the great recession. IZA Discussion Paper No. 5780.

  • Chetty, R. (2008). Moral hazard versus liquidity and optimal unemployment insurance. Journal of Political Economy, 116, 173–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolado, J., Jansen, M., & Jimeno, J. (2009). On-the-job search in a matching model with heterogeneous jobs and workers. Economic Journal, 119, 200–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ek, S. & Holmlund, B. (2011). Deltidsarbetslöshet och arbetslöshetsförsäkring i Sverige (Part-time unemployment and unemployment insurance in Sweden). In Välfärdsstaten i arbete (The welfare state at work), report to the Swedish long-term survey 2011. Stockholm: Fritzes.

  • Feldstein, M. (1978). The effect of unemployment insurance on temporary layoff unemployment. American Economic Review, 68, 834–846.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, P., & Holmlund, B. (2001). Optimal unemployment insurance in search equilibrium. Journal of Labor Economics, 19, 370–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, P., & Holmlund, B. (2006). Improving incentives in unemployment insurance: A review of recent research. Journal of Economic Surveys, 20, 357–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gautier, P. (2002). Unemployment and search externalities in a model with heterogeneous jobs and workers. Economica, 69, 21–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. (2005). Employment fluctuations with equilibrium wage stickiness. American Economic Review, 95, 50–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R., & Milgrom, P. (2008). The limited influence of unemployment on the wage bargain. American Economic Review, 98, 1653–1674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartman, L. (Ed.). (2008). Välfärd på deltid (Welfare on part-time). Stockholm: SNS Förlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holen, A., & Horowitz, S. (1974). Partial unemployment insurance benefits and the extent of partial unemployment. Journal of Human Resources, 9, 420–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hussmans, R. (2007). Measurement of employment, unemployment and underemployment—current international standards and issues in their application, International Labour Office. http://www.ilo.org/public/english/bureau/stat/download/articles/2007-1.

  • Kyyrä, T. (2010). Partial unemployment insurance benefits and the transition rate to regular work. European Economic Review, 54, 911–930.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyyrä, T., Parrotta, P., & Rosholm, M. (2013). The effect of receiving supplementary UI benefits on unemployment duration. Labour Economics, 21, 122–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Månsson, J., Ottosson, J., & Lundequist, K. (2008). Deltidsarbete och deltidsarbetslöshet (Part-time work and part-time unemployment). In L. Hartman (Ed.), Välfärd på deltid (Welfare on part-time). Stockholm: SNS Förlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCall, B. (1996). Unemployment insurance rules, joblessness, and part-time work. Econometrica, 64, 647–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munts, R. (1970). Partial benefit schedules in unemployment insurance: Their impact on work incentives. Journal of Human Resources, 5, 160–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Reilly, J., & Fagan, C. (Eds.). (1998). Part-time prospects: An international comparison. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • (2010). Employment outlook. Paris: OECD.

  • Pissarides, C. (2000). Equilibrium unemployment theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides, C. (2009). The unemployment volatility puzzle: Is wage stickiness the answer? Econometrica, 77, 1339–1369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shimer, R. (2005). The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies. American Economic Review, 95, 25–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shimer, R. (2006). On-the-job search and strategic bargaining. European Economic Review, 50, 811–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stratton, L. (1996). Are ‘involuntary’ part-time workers indeed involuntary? Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 49, 522–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tam, M. (1997). Part-time employment: A bridge or a trap?. Aldershot: Avebury.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tatsiramos, K., & van Ours, J. (2012). Labor market effects of unemployment insurance design. Journal of Economic Surveys. doi:10.1111/joes.12005.

  • Wahlberg, R. (2008). Part-time penalty in Sweden: Evidence from quantile regression. Working Paper in Economics 315, University of Gothenburg.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bertil Holmlund.

Appendices

Appendix 1: The numerical model

The calibration is done with an eye on the Swedish labor market. The matching function is Cobb Douglas, \(M=au^{\eta }v^{1-\eta }\), where \(\eta =0.7\) is assumed. Productivity is normalized to unity for both part-time and full-time employees: \(y=1\). The time period is taken to be a day. The rate of interest (equal to the rate of time preference) is set to zero. The annual separation rate is set to 15 % corresponding to daily rate of \(0.15/365=0.000411\).

UI coverage is relatively low according to the labor force surveys; around one third of the unemployed received unemployment benefits over the period 2005–2009. We account for this by choosing a benchmark replacement rate of 30 % for both unemployed and part-timers, i.e., \(\rho _{u}=\rho _{p}=0.3\).

Regarding work hours, we assume that the full-time employee works as much as she prefers. With log utility this implies \(h_{e}=1/(1+\delta )\) when \(T=1\) as is assumed. Working time among part-timers is given by \(h_{p}=0.48h_{e}\), which is in line with Swedish data: involuntary part-timers in the labor force surveys report that they wish to work twice as much as they actually do.

Regarding wages, empirical work has documented wage penalties for part-timers. A recent Swedish study by Wahlberg (2008) suggests a wage penalty of 20 %, arguably implausibly large. We aim for a full-time wage premium of less than 10 %. When baseline wages are determined by Nash bargaining (\(\beta =\eta \)) we obtain \(w_{e}=0.962\) and a wage premium for full-time workers of 3 %.

The matching parameter \(a\), preferences for leisure \(\delta ~\), and the vacancy cost \(\kappa \) are chosen so as to obtain reasonable outcomes regarding unemployment rates and durations. We set \(a=0.0091\), \(\delta =0.12\), and \(\kappa =3\) and obtain unemployment at 6 % and part-time unemployment at 4.4 %. Unemployment duration is 26 weeks, and the average vacancy lasts for 4 weeks.

The parameterized model produces outcomes as given by the first column in Table 3 in the main text.

Appendix 2: Time limits

With time limits of benefit receipt, the relevant utility functions are:

$$\begin{aligned} \upsilon _{u}^{I}&= \ln B^{I}+\ln \left( 1-t\right) +\delta \ln \left( T-s_{u}^{I}\right) , \\ \upsilon _{u}^{N}&= \ln B^{N}+\ln \left( 1-t\right) +\delta \ln \left( T-s_{u}^{N}\right) , \\ \upsilon _{p}^{I}&= \ln \left( w_{p}h_{p}+b^{I}\right) +\ln \left( 1-t\right) +\delta \ln \left( T-h_{p}-s_{p}^{I}\right) , \\ \upsilon _{p}^{N}&= \ln \left( w_{p}h_{p}+b^{N}\right) +\ln \left( 1-t\right) +\delta \ln \left( T-h_{p}-s_{p}^{N}\right) , \\ \upsilon _{E}&= \ln \left( w_{e}h_{e}\right) +\ln \left( 1-t\right) +\delta \ln \left( T-h_{e}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Optimal search efforts are obtained as:

$$\begin{aligned} s_{p}^{I}&:\frac{\delta }{T-h_{p}-s_{p}^{I}}=\alpha \left( \theta _{E}\right) \left( E-P^{I}\right) , \\ s_{p}^{N}&:\frac{\delta }{T-h_{p}-s_{p}^{N}}=\alpha \left( \theta _{E}\right) \left( E-P^{N}\right) , \\ s_{u}^{I}&:\frac{\delta }{T-s_{u}^{I}}=\alpha \left( \theta _{P}\right) \left( P^{I}-U^{I}\right) +\alpha \left( \theta _{E}\right) \left( E-U^{I}\right) , \\ s_{u}^{N}&:\frac{\delta }{T {\acute{}}-s_{u}^{N}}=\alpha \left( \theta _{P}\right) \left( P^{I}-U^{N}\right) +\alpha \left( \theta _{E}\right) \left( E-U^{N}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

The flow equilibrium conditions for unemployment and part-time work are given as:

$$\begin{aligned} u^{I}&: \phi (1-u^{I}-u^{N})=\left( \lambda +s_{u}^{I}\left[ \alpha \left( \theta _{P}\right) +\alpha \left( \theta _{E}\right) \right] \right) u^{I}, \\ u^{N}&: \lambda u^{I}=s_{u}^{N}\left[ \alpha \left( \theta _{P}\right) +\alpha \left( \theta _{E}\right) \right] u^{N}, \\ p^{I}&:s_{u}^{I}\alpha \left( \theta _{P}\right) u^{I}+s_{u}^{N}\alpha \left( \theta _{P}\right) u^{N}=\left[ \phi +\mu +s_{p}^{I}\alpha (\theta _{E})\right] p^{I}, \\ p^{N}&:\mu p^{I}=\left[ \phi +s_{p}^{N}\alpha (\theta _{E})\right] p^{N}, \end{aligned}$$

and employment is obtained from the labor force identity: \( 1=e+u^{I}+u^{N}+p^{I}+p^{N}\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ek, S., Holmlund, B. Part-time unemployment and optimal unemployment insurance. Int Tax Public Finance 22, 201–223 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-013-9301-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-013-9301-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation