Skip to main content
Log in

The interaction of international institutions from a social network perspective

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The literature increasingly acknowledges that international institutions do not exist in isolation, but regularly interact with each other. This interplay might induce influence, affecting institutions’ development and performance. The following research adds to this debate by systematically analyzing the quantitative evidence on how institutional interaction drives institutional design from a network perspective. Using dyadic cross-sectional data on international environmental agreements in 1952–2000, the authors find support for their theoretical argument that regimes’ similarity in design as captured by their degree of legalization strongly depends on institutions’ interaction. However, while “soft law” disseminates between regimes that are well connected through direct or indirect links, this does not apply to “hard law.” The authors explain this divergence with states’ concerns about binding-law commitments and sovereignty costs associated with the latter. This research may have important implications for studies of international institutions and of network analysis in general.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We use the terms “(international) institution,” “regime,” and “treaty” interchangeably. We also treat “performance” and “effectiveness” equally.

  2. Skjærseth et al. (2006) is the only exception in this regard. We elaborate below how we build on and intend to extend this study.

  3. Regime design can refer to more aspects than those under study here, such as the incorporation and design of dispute settlement mechanisms, the form of decision making, etc. However, our choice to understand design in terms of hard versus soft law is grounded in the fact that a major strand of the literature, to which we strive to contribute to, focuses on this particular aspect of regime design (Goldstein and Martin 2000; Skjærseth et al. 2006; Bernauer et al. 2013).

  4. For recent overviews, see Oberthür and Stokke (2011) or Oberthür and Gehring (2011).

  5. We also conducted a series of robustness checks, which we discuss in the online appendix or briefly refer to below.

  6. It is, of course, also possible that the kind of information on institutional design, which we focus on, spreads through different channels, such as government officials negotiating international agreements in different sectors, officials from international organizations, etc. However, this should not work against our proposed mechanism, since there is no reason to assume that contrary information should spread through these different channels.

  7. This is because hard-law treaties reduce the risk of incomplete contracting by lowering the transaction costs of the law’s application and by decreasing post-agreement costs such as management or enforcement (Rosendorff 2005). Furthermore, hard law may increase the reputational costs, a state will incur if it reneges on its commitments.

  8. The online appendix provides a list of all considered regimes. Originally, Bernauer et al. (2013) relied on CIESIN (2006) and Mitchell (2008), and then deleted treaties from the data that, in their assessment, deal with environmental issues only at the margin or not at all. They also eliminated treaties that are not open for ratification to all countries globally.

  9. The establishment of an institution refers to the first year this treaty is open for ratification. We also employed a more conservative setup by dropping those directed dyads in our data, in which the source institution has been established in the same year the target institution has been founded. The results based on this setup are identical to those reported below.

  10. The variables we use to measure legalization are coded dichotomously. Arguably, certain treaty design variables may exhibit more than a binary variation. Bernauer et al. (2013) originally allowed for more fine-grained categorizations for some of the variables. However, their coding process revealed the cure might be worse than the disease: since many of the treaties in the sample did not allow for a more fine-grained classification, Bernauer et al. (2013) ended up with only a few or no cases in several categories and, therefore, the coding became less reliable. Generally, this limitation mainly arises because the treaties are still rather heterogeneous, although they belong to the same policy area. In the end, Bernauer et al. (2013) decided that the empirical benefit from using more fine-grained scales is not worth the loss in data quality and reliability.

  11. Instead of relying on all countries that have ratified both regimes, one could use only those members that were part of the negotiating group to each treaty. While this could be sensible from a theoretical perspective, we would lose about 50 treaties in our sample, for which we are lacking the corresponding data, thereby making our empirical approach less generalizable.

  12. In order to calculate Maximum Flow of Information with this equation, the network must satisfy the condition \(r \le (n - 2)^{1/2} ,\) where n is the number of institutions and r is the ratio of the largest edge value in a network to the smallest edge value. This is given in our setup.

  13. The baseline category we leave out of the models pertains to those treaties that regulate mixed public goods, i.e., issues that have some regional or domestic component, but also a transnational character.

References

  • Abbott, K., Keohane, R., Moravcsik, A., Slaughter, A.-M., & Snidal, D. (2000). The concept of legalization. International Organization, 54(3), 401–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abbott, K., & Snidal, D. (2000). Hard and soft law in international governance. International Organization, 54(3), 421–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andresen, S., Rosendal, K., & Skjærseth, J. B. (2013). Why negotiate a legally binding mercury convention? International Environmental Agreements, 13(4), 425–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernauer, T., Kalbhenn, A., Koubi, V., & Spilker, G. (2013). Is there a “depth versus participation” dilemma in international cooperation? Review of International Organizations, 8(4), 477–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biermann, F., & Bauer, S. (2005). Managers of global governance: Assessing and explaining the influence of international bureaucracies. Working paper No. 15: The global governance project.

  • Biermann, F., & Gupta, A. (2011). Accountability and legitimacy in earth system governance: A research framework. Ecological Economics, 70(11), 1856–1864.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biermann, F., & Siebenhüner, B. (Eds.). (2009). Managers of global change: The influence of environmental bureaucracies. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boehmer, C., Gartzke, E., & Nordstrom, T. (2004). Do intergovernmental organizations promote peace? World Politics, 5(7), 1–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böhmelt, T., & Pilster, U. (2010). International environmental regimes—legalisation, flexibility and effectiveness. Australian Journal of Political Science, 45(2), 245–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borgatti, S., Mehra, A., Brass, D., & Labianca, G. (2009). Network analysis in the social sciences. Science, 323(5916), 892–895.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Brosig, M. (2011). Overlap and interplay between international organizations: Theories and approaches. South African Journal of International Affairs, 18(2), 147–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao, X. (2009). Networks of intergovernmental organizations and convergence in domestic economic policies. International Studies Quarterly, 53(4), 1095–1130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao, X., & Prakash, A. (2010). Trade competition and domestic pollution: A panel study, 1980–2003. International Organization, 64(3), 481–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlain, J. (1974). Provision of collective goods as a function of group size. American Political Science Review, 68(2), 707–716.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CIESIN. (2006). Environmental treaties and resource indicators (ENTRI). http://sedac.ciesin.columbia.edu/entri/, Accessed Oct 31, 2013.

  • Coleman, J. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conliffe, A. (2011). Combating ineffectiveness: Climate change bandwagoning and the UN convention to combat desertification. Global Environmental Politics, 11(3), 44–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dorussen, H., & Ward, H. (2008). Intergovernmental organizations and the Kantian peace—a network perspective. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52(2), 189–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, G., Rocke, D. M., & Barsoom, P. (1996). Is the good news about compliance good news for cooperation? International Organization, 52(3), 379–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fearon, J. D. (1998). Bargaining, enforcement, and international cooperation. International Organization, 52(2), 269–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ford, L. R., & Fulkerson, D. R. (1956). Maximal flow through a network. Canadian Journal of Mathematics, 8(5), 399–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, L., Borgatti, S., & White, D. R. (1991). Centrality in valued graphs: A measure of betweenness based on network flow. Social Networks, 13(2), 141–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehring, T., & Oberthür, S. (2009). The causal mechanism of interaction between international institutions. European Journal of International Relations, 15(1), 125–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, J., & Martin, L. (2000). Legalization, trade liberalization and domestic politics: A cautionary note. International Organization, 54(3), 603–632.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grilo, C. (2011). Institutional interplay in networks of marine protected areas with community-based management. Coastal Management, 39(4), 440–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haas, P. M. (1993). Epistemic communities and the dynamics of international environmental cooperation. In V. Rittberger (Ed.), Regime theory and international relations (pp. 168–201). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haas, P. M. (1997). Scientific communities and multiple paths to environmental management. In L. A. Brooks & S. D. VanDeVeer (Eds.), Saving the seas: Values, scientists, and international governance (pp. 193–228). College Park, MD: Maryland Sea Grant College.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hafner-Burton, E., Kahler, M., & Montgomery, A. (2009). Network analysis for international relations. International Organization, 63(3), 559–592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hafner-Burton, E., & Montgomery, A. (2006). Power positions—international organizations, social networks, and conflict. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(1), 3–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofmann, S. (2010). Why institutional overlap matters: CSDP in the European security architecture. Journal of Common Market Studies, 49(1), 101–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jinnah, S. (2010). Overlap management in the world trade organization: Secretariat influence on trade-environment politics. Global Environmental Politics, 10(2), 54–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jinnah, S. (2011). Climate change bandwagoning: The impacts of strategic linkages on regime design, maintenance, and death. Global Environmental Politics, 11(3), 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, T. (2013a). Institutional design and bureaucrats’ impact on political control. Journal of Politics, 75(1), 183–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, T. (2013b). Looking beyond states: Openings for international bureaucrats to enter the institutional design process. Review of International Organizations, 8(4), 499–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, G., Keohane, R., & Verba, S. (1994). Designing social inquiry: Scientific inference in qualitative research. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koremenos, B., Lipson, C., & Snidal, D. (2001). The rational design of international institutions. International Organization, 55(4), 761–799.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krackhardt, D. (1999). The ties that torture: Simmelian tie analysis in organizations. Research in the Sociology of Organizations, 16(1), 183–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leifeld, P., & Schneider, V. (2012). Information exchange in policy networks. American Journal of Political Science, 56(3), 731–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maoz, Z. (2010). Networks of nations: The evolution, structure, and impact of international networks, 1816–2001. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, P., Rittberger, V., & Zürn, M. (1993). Regime theory: State of the art and perspectives. In V. Rittberger (Ed.), Regime theory and international relations (pp. 391–430). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miles, E. L., Underdal, A., Andresen, S., Wettestad, J., Skjærseth, J. B., & Carlin, E. M. (Eds.). (2002). Environmental regime effectiveness. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, R. B. (2006). Problem structure, institutional design, and the relative effectiveness of international environmental agreements. Global Environmental Politics, 6(3), 72–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, R. B. (2008). International environmental agreements database project (200208), version 2007.1. http://iea.uoregon.edu/, Accessed Oct 31, 2013.

  • Oberthür, S. (2001). Linkages between the Montreal and Kyoto protocols: Enhancing synergies between protecting the ozone layer and the global climate. International Environmental Agreements, 1(3), 357–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oberthür, S. (2009). Interplay management: Enhancing environmental policy integration among international institutions. International Environmental Agreements, 9(3), 371–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oberthür, S., & Gehring, T. (Eds.). (2006). Institutional interaction in global environmental governance: Synergy and conflict among international and EU policies. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oberthür, S., & Gehring, T. (2011). Institutional interaction: Ten years of scholarly development. In S. Oberthür & O. S. Stokke (Eds.), Managing institutional complexity: Regime interplay and global environmental change (pp. 25–58). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Oberthür, S., & Stokke, O. S. (Eds.). (2011). Managing institutional complexity: Regime interplay and global environmental change. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action—public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ovodenko, A., & Keohane, R. (2012). Institutional diffusion in international environmental affairs. International Affairs, 88(3), 523–541.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, G., & Welsh Brown, J. (1996). Global environmental politics. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pretty, J., & Ward, H. (2001). Social capital and the environment. World Development, 29(2), 209–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosendorff, P. B. (2005). Stability and rigidity: Politics and design of the WTO’s dispute settlement procedure. American Political Science Review, 99(3), 389–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosendorff, P. B., & Milner, H. V. (2001). The optimal design of international trade institutions: Uncertainty and escape. International Organization, 55(4), 829–857.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruggie, R. (1986). Continuity and transformation in the world polity: Toward a neorealist synthesis. In R. Keohane (Ed.), Neorealism and its critics (pp. 131–157). New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selin, H., & VanDeVeer, S. D. (2003). Mapping institutional linkages in European air pollution politics. Global Environmental Politics, 3(3), 14–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer, G. (2001). The world trade organization under challenge: Democracy and the law and politics of the WTO’s treatment of trade and environment matters. Harvard Environment Law Review, 25(1), 1–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer, G., & Pollack, M. A. (2010). Hard vs. soft law: Alternatives, complements, and antagonists in international governance. Minnesota Law Review, 94(3), 706–799.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer, G., & Pollack, M. A. (2011). Hard versus soft law in international security. Boston College Law Review, 52(4), 1147–1241.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmel, G. (1950). Fundamental problems of sociology: Individual and society. In K. H. Wolff (Ed.), The sociology of Georg Simmel (pp. 3–79). New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skjærseth, J. B., Stokke, O. S., & Wettestad, J. (2006). Soft law, hard law, and effective implementation of international environmental norms. Global Environmental Politics, 6(3), 104–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slaughter, A.-M. (2004). Sovereignty and power in a networked world order. Stanford Journal of International Law, 40(283), 283–327.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slikker, M., & van den Nouweland, A. (2001). Social and economic networks in cooperative game theory. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Snidal, D. (1996). Political economy and international institutions. International Review of Law and Economics, 16(1), 121–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spilker, G., & Koubi, V. (2012). Why do countries participate in global environmental agreements?. ETH Zurich: Typescript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stokke, O. S. (2001). Governing high sea fisheries. The interplay of global and regional regimes. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ward, H. (2006). International linkages and environmental sustainability: The effectiveness of the regime network. Journal of Peace Research, 43(2), 149–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ward, M. D., Stovel, K., & Sacks, A. (2011). Network analysis and political science. Annual Review of Political Science, 14(1), 245–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wasserman, S., & Faust, K. (1997). Social network analysis: Methods and applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, O. R. (1999). The effectiveness of international environmental regimes: Causal connections and behavioral mechanisms. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, O. R. (2002). The institutional dimensions of environmental change: Fit, interplay, and scale. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Manfred Elsig, Tana Johnson, Xavier Fernández-i-Marín, the participants of the 6th Annual Conference on the Political Economy of International Organizations (PEIO), the participants of the Workshop on the Design and Effects of International Institutions at the ECPR Joint Sessions 2013, and the journal's anonymous reviewers as well as the editor for helpful comments and advice. The replication materials for the data analysis can be obtained from the authors on request.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tobias Böhmelt.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (DOCX 73 kb)

Supplementary material 2 (DOCX 38 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Böhmelt, T., Spilker, G. The interaction of international institutions from a social network perspective. Int Environ Agreements 16, 67–89 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10784-014-9248-3

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10784-014-9248-3

Keywords

Navigation