Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

What is a service of general economic interest?

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The definition of the concept a “service of general economic interest” (SGEI) known from Article 106(2) treaty of the functioning of the European Union is clarified. When a service is determined to be an SGEI, Member States may enact measures and undertakings entrusted with the provision of the SGEI may engage in behaviour which would otherwise be contrary to the rules of the Treaties, notably the competition rules. Member States retain a wide discretion to define, provide and finance SGEIs; i.e. to use the entrustment of an SGEI as a tool to intervene in the market. This discretion is subject only to a test for manifest error of assessment by the Commission. To increase legal certainty, ensure effective intervention in markets and prevent their use in industrial policy, it is highly relevant to clarify what SGEIs are. The various definitions published by the Commission and in the literature are examined, and a new definition of an SGEI based on economic theory (networks and network effects) is formed. This definition is consistent with the case law of the Court of Justice of the European Union and the General Court. On the basis of the definition, implications for efficiency in dealing with SGEIs are made.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For readers not familiar with the topic, please refer to one of the comprehensive and detailed academic texts concerning the developments in case law and policy over time, e.g. Buendia Sierra (2000, 2007), Baquero Cruz (2005).

  2. The legal test under Article 106(2) TFEU will not be elaborated here, as focus is on the concept of an SGEI, and not on the legal implications of the service being an SGEI. For further information on the legal test under Article 106(2) TFEU; see references in note 1.

  3. Charter of Fundamental Rights of the European Union, OJ 2010 C 83/389, Article 36. Both Protocol no. 26 and the Charter are part of the Treaties, cf. Article 51 TEU and Article 6(2) TEU.

  4. For an analysis of the soft law regulation of SGEIs, see Neergaard (2011).

  5. Cf. Article 14 TFEU (ex Article 16 TEC): “… the Union and the Member States, each within their respective powers” “[emphasis added] and Article 1 of Protocol no. 26 on SGIs: The shared values of the Union in respect of services of general economic interest within the meaning of Article 14 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union include in particular: the essential role and the wide discretion of national, regional and local authorities in providing, commissioning and organising services of general economic interest as closely as possible to the needs of the users…” [emphasis added].

  6. The “first Altmark package” was adopted in 2005 and consisted of the Altmark Decision and the Framework for Public Service Compensation.

  7. The documents are available at: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/legislation/sgei.html.

  8. The list of case law in long, some recent examples on solidarity include C-218/00 Cisal (2002) ECR I-691; C-350/07 Kattner Stahlbau GmbH (2009) ECR I-1513 and C-437/09 AG2R (2011) ERC I-973 and on public authority, see C-49/07 MOTOE (2008) ECR I-4863 and C-138/11 Compass-Datenbank, judgment of 12 July 2012, nyr. On purchasing activities, see Cf. C-205/03P FENIN (2006) ECR I-6295 and C-113/07P SELEX (2009) ECR I-2207.

  9. The concept of an undertaking is e.g. central in the current reform of the State aid rules, cf. 2011 Communication.

  10. The review of definitions is delineated from definitions based on other norms than economic ones; e.g. Ross (2007, 2009).

  11. This could be influenced by the turn of interest towards Social Services of General Interest and Non-economic Services of General Interest, cf. 2006 Communication and the 2007 Communication, and most recently at Treaty level Protocol No. 26 on Services of General Interest.

  12. I.e. the more economic approach to assessments under Article 102 TFEU in the Communication on Article 82 EC and the more economic approach to State aid in the 2005 State Aid Action Plan. On the more economic approach under the rules on State aid, see also Friederiszick et al. (2008).

  13. This perception is criticised by Neegaard (2009), who mentions several weaknesses in the approach, notably the wording of Article 106(2) TFEU which mentions both imposing of an SGEI and assignment of “particular tasks”.

  14. E.g. joined cases C-34-38/01 Enirisorse (2003) ECR I-14243, para. 33 and C-399/08P Commission v Deutsche Post [2010] ECR I-7831, para. 41.

  15. C-280/00 Altmark (2003) ECR I-7747.

  16. Cf. Altmark Decision and 2011 Communication.

  17. Joined cases C-34-38/01 Enirisorse (2003) ECR I-14243, para. 33.

  18. T-289/03 BUPA (2008) ECR II-81, paras. 161–162.

  19. T-17/02 Fred Olsen (2005) ECR II-2031, para. 216; T-289/03, BUPA (2008) ECR II-81, para. 166; T-442/03 SIC (2008) ECR II-01161, para. 195; T-309/04, T-317/04, T-329/04 and T-336/04 TV2 Danmark (2008) ECR II-2935, para. 101.

  20. T-289/03 BUPA (2008) ECR II-81, para. 168.

  21. T-289/03 BUPA (2008) ECR II-81, para. 172.

  22. T-137/10 CBI v Commission, judgment of 7 November 2012, nyr.

  23. T-137/10 CBI v Commission, judgment of 7 November 2012, nyr., paras. 167 and 215.

  24. T-137/10 CBI v Commission, judgment of 7 November 2012, nyr., paras. 165-167.

  25. However, in several of the judgments of the General Court (T-17/02 Fred Olsen (2005) ECR II-2031; T-289/03, BUPA (2008) ECR II-81; T-442/03 SIC (2008) ECR II-01161; and, T-309/04, T-317/04, T-329/04 and T-336/04 TV2 Danmark (2008) ECR II-2935), reference is made in this connection to opinion of AG Léger on 10 July 2001 concerning C-309/99 Wouters [2002] ECR I-1577, para. 162: “In point of fact, it falls to the Member States to define the content of their services of general economic interest. In this respect they enjoy considerable leeway since the Court will intervene only in order to penalise any abuse, where the Member States damage the Community's interests.

  26. T-289/03 BUPA [2008] ECR II-81, para. 167.

  27. On the legal basis provided in Article 14 TFEU, see e.g. Krajewski (2008).

  28. The Communication provides important guidance on what the Commission considers manifest error to be, and thus increases legal certainty.”

  29. Which he terms “manifestly disproportionate”, cf. Sauter (2008), p. 186.

  30. Moreover, see Sauter (2013).

  31. Joined cases C-197 and 203/11, Eric Libert and Others, judgment of 8. May 2013, nyr., para. 97; along the same lines T-137/10 CBI v Commission, judgment of 7 November 2012, nyr., paras. 86–87.

  32. See references in fn. 40.

  33. T-289/03 BUPA (2008) ECR II-81, paras. 191-195.

  34. The Amsterdam Protocol was annexed to the Treaty in 1997, and has now been replaced by Protocol no 29 on the systems of public broadcasting in the Member States, annexed by the Lisbon Treaty to the TEU and TFEU.

  35. C-96/94 Spediporto (1995) ECR I-2883.

  36. What is now Protocol no 27 on the Internal Market and Competition and Article 4(3) TFEU, read in conjunction with Article 101 or 102 TFEU, see also Gerad (2010).

  37. See also C-7/82 GVL v Commission [1983] ECR 483, paras. 30-32; C-18/88 GB-Inno BM (1991) ECR I-5941, para. 22; and, T-266/97 Vlaamse Televisie Maatschappij (1999) ECR II-2329, para. 122.

  38. E.g. Recialt 18, Article 11(1) (a), Article 12 and Article 15 of Directive 96/67/EC on access to the ground handling market at Community airports, O.J. 1996 L 272/36; Article 1 of Directive 97/67/EC on common rules for the development of the internal market of Community postal services and the improvement of quality of service, O.J. 1998 L 15/4 as amended by Directive 2008/6/EC amending Directive 97/67/EC with regard to the full accomplishment of the internal market of Community postal services, O.J. 2008 L 52/3; Article 1 of Directive 2002/22/EC on universal service and users' rights relating to electronic communications networks and services, O.J. 2002 L 108/51 as amended by Directive 2009/136/EC amending Directive 2002/22/EC on universal service and users’ rights relating to electronic communications networks and services, Directive 2002/58/EC concerning the processing of personal data and the protection of privacy in the electronic communications sector and Regulation (EC) No 2006/2004 on cooperation between national authorities responsible for the enforcement of consumer protection laws, O.J. 2009 L 337/11; Regulation 1370/2007 on public passenger transport services by rail and by road and repealing Council Regulations Nos 1191/69 and 1107/70, O.J. 2007 L 315/1; Article 1 of Directive 2009/72/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 July 2009 concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and repealing Directive 2003/54/EC, O.J. 2009 L 211/55;.

  39. Opinion of Advocate General La Pergola on 4 March 1999 concerning C-124/97 Läärä (1999) ECR I-6067, para. 30.

  40. T-289/03 BUPA (2008) ECR II-81.

  41. C-203/96 Dusseldorph (1998) ECR I-4075 and C-209/98 Sydhavnens Sten og Grus (2000) ECR I-3743.

  42. A good or a service—here the term “good” will be used to encompass both as this is the standard terminology of welfare economics.

  43. However, public control with certain undertakings entrusted with an SGEI could be seen as dealing with information asymmetries. Such control could be achieved by golden shares but the Courts seem to deal with golden shares not through 106(2) TFEU but rather through free capital mobility. See the discussion in section IV on cases.

  44. The two cases mentioned in Section II.C on collection of hazardous and building waste have to do with remedying the environmental externality (collection and treatment of waste) rather than with limiting the size of the external effect at its root. However, the cases illustrate that environmental concerns may occasionally explain the existence of an SGEI.

  45. These circumstances are that a) there are increasing returns to scale in software production; b) there is free entry into software production; and c) consumers have a preference for software variety.

  46. For an example of this view, see Jordan (1972).

  47. For early contributions, see Stigler (1971) and Peltzman (1976).

  48. C-157/94 Commission v Netherlands (19970 ECR I-5699, para. 58).

  49. E.g. C-439/08, VEBIC, judgment of 7 December 2010, nyr, para. 38 or C-116/08, Christel Meerts (2010) ECR I-10063, para. 3.

  50. E.g. C-367/10P, EMC Development AB, judgment of 31 March 2011, nyr.

  51. E.g. C-205/99 Analir (2001) ECR I-1271 or joined cases C-282-283/04 Commission v Netherlands (2006) ECR I-9141.

  52. Hopefully, only one judgment was left out on this basis, namely T-137/10 Coordination bruxelloise d’institutions sociales et de santé (CBI) v European Commission, judgment of 7 November 2012, nyr.

  53. C-437/09, AG2R (2011) ECR I-973.

  54. AG Mengozzi made do with finding that a task of general economic interest had ostensibly been assigned to AG2R, cf. opinion of AG Mengozzi on 11 November 2010 concerning C-437/09 AG2R, para. 102.

  55. On proportionality of measures or conduct in the context of SGEIs, cf. Sauter (2008).

  56. C-67/96 Albany (1999) ECR I-5751; C-115-117/97 Stichting Bedrijfspensioenfonds (1999) ECR I-6025; C-219/97 Maatschappij Drijvende Bokken (1999) ECR I-6121; and, T-289/03 BUPA (2008) ECR I-81.

  57. See also 2011 Communication, paras 51–53.

  58. For a recent not very formalistic approach, see C-242/10 Enel Produzione, judgment of 21 December 2011, nyr., where the CJEU found that, even though the notification requirement in Article 3(9) of Directive 2003/54/EC concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and repealing Directive 96/92/EC—Statements made with regard to decommissioning and waste management activities, OJ 2003 L 176/37, was not fulfilled, this was not decisive for defining the national measures as a PSO, cf. para. 39 of the judgment.

  59. This case was appealed by RTE but the appeal was dismissed by CJEU in joined cases C-241/91 P and C-242/91 P. These joined cases do not appear in Table 1 since the search criterion “general economic interest” was not met. In other words the appeals do not throw additional light on SGEI compared with the original case T-69/89.

  60. Purchase of shares is categorized as direct investments, and hence, capital, cf. Directive 88/361/EEC for the implementation of Article 67 of the Treaty, OJ 1988 L 178/5.

  61. Cf. C-543/08 Commission v Portugal ECR 2010 I-11241, paras. 93–95.

  62. C-463/00 Commission v Spain, para. 70.

References

  • Almunia, J. (2011a). Public services for a better Europe, CEEP (The European Centre of Employers and Enterprises providing Public services). Budapest, 16 June 2011. SPEECH/11/444.

  • Almunia, J. (2011b) Reform of the State aid rules for services of general economic interest (SGEI) and decisions on WestLB, Bank of Ireland and France Telecom. Press conference, Brussels, 20 Decembre 2011. SPEECH/11/901.

  • Baquero Cruz, J. (2005). Beyond competition: Services of general interest and European community law. In Gráinne De Búrca (Ed.), EU law and the welfare state (pp. 169–212). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. P. (2010). Business and its environment (6th ed.). London: Pearson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Seabright, P. (1999). The effects and policy implications of state aids to industry: An economic analysis. Economic Policy, 14(28), 13–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buendia Sierra, J. L. (2000). Exclusive rights and State Monopolies under EC Law—Article 86 (Former Article 90) of the EC Treaty. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buendia Sierra, J. L. (2007). Article 86—exclusive rights and other anti-competitive state measures. In Jonathan Faull & Ali Nikpay (Eds.), The EC law of competition (pp. 595–655). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buendia Sierra, J. L. (2010). Finding the right balance: State aid and services of general economic interest. In Alistair Sutton (Ed.), EC state aid law—Le droit des aides d’Etat dans la CE—Liber Amicorum Francisco santaolalla Gadea (pp. 191–222). The Netherlands: Kluwer Law International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Church, J., & Gandal, N. (2008). Platform competition in telecommunications, Chap. 4. In S. K. Majumda, I. Vogelsang, & M. E. Cave (Eds.) Handbook of telecommunications economics, Vol. 2, Technology evolution and the internet, Bingley: Emerald.

  • Church, J., Gandal, N., & Krause, D. (2008). Indirect network effects and adoption externalities. Review of Network Economics, 7(3), 337–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1964). The regulated industries: Discussion. American Economic Review, 54(2), 192–197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Commission. (2001). Report to the Laeken European council on services of general interest (cited as: 2001 Report to the Laeken Council), COM, 598 final.

  • Commission. (2001). Communication on services of general interest (cited as: 2001 Communication), OJ 2001 C 17/4.

  • Commission. (2003). Green paper on services of general interest (cited as: 2003 Green Paper), COM, 270 final.

  • Commission. (2004). White paper on services of general interest (cited as: 2004 White Paper), COM, 374 Final.

  • Commission. (2005). State aid action plan: Less and better targeted state aid: A roadmap for state aid reform 2005–2009 (cited as: 2005 State Aid Action Plan), COM, 107 final.

  • Commission. (2005). Decision of 28 November 2005 on the application of Article 86(2) of the EC Treaty to State aid in the form of public service compensation granted to certain undertakings entrusted with the operation of services of general economic interest (cited as: Altmark Decision), OJ 2005 L 312/67.

  • Commission. (2005). Community framework for State aid in the form of public service compensation (cited as: Framework for Public Service Compensation), OJ 2005 C 297/4.

  • Commission. (2006). Implementing the community Lisbon programme: Social services of general interest in the European Union (cited as: 2006 Communication), COM, 177.

  • Commission. (2007). Services of general interest, including social services of general interest: A new European commitment (cited as: 2007 Communication), COM, 725 final.

  • Commission. (2009). Guidance on the Commission’s enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC treaty to abusive exclusionary conduct by dominant undertakings (cited as: Communication on Article 82 EC), OJ 2009 C 45/7.

  • Commission. (2011). Communication from the commission on the application of the European Union state aid rules to compensation granted for the provision of services of general economic interest (cited as: 2011 Communication), OJ 2012 C 8/4.

  • Cremer, H., Gasmi, F., Grimaud, A., & Laffont, J. J. (2001). Universal service: An economic perspective. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 72(1), 5–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies, G. (2009). Article 86 EC, the EC’s economic approach to competition law and the general interest. European Competition Journal, 5(2), 549–584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies, J., & Szyszczak, E. (2011). Universal service obligations: Fulfilling new generations of services of general interest. In E. Szyszczak, J. Davies, M. Andenæs, & T. Bekkedal (Eds.), Developments in services of general interest (pp. 155–177). The Hague: TMC Asser Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Economides, N., & Salop, S. C. (1992). Competition and integration among complements, and network market structure. Journal of Industrial Economics, 1(1), 105–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, J., & Klemperer, P. (2007). Coordination and lock-in: Competition with switching costs and network effects, Chap. 31. In M. Armstrong, & R. Porter (Eds.) Handbook of industrial organization (Vol. 3, pp. 1967–2072). North-Holland.

  • Farrell, J., & Saloner, G. (1985). Standardization, compatibility, and innovation. RAND Journal of Economics, 16(1), 70–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friederiszick, H. W., Röller, L.-H., & Verouden, V. (2008). European state aid control: An economic framework. In P. Buccirossi (Ed.), Handbook in antitrust economics, Chap. 17. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerad, D. (2010). EU competition policy after Lisbon: Time for a review of the ‘State Action Doctrine’? Journal of European Competition Law & Practice, 1(3), 202–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordan, W. A. (1972). Producer protection, prior market structure and the effects of government regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 15, 151–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M. L., & Shapiro, C. (1985). Network externalities, competition, and compatibility. American Economic Review, 75(3), 424–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krajewski, M. (2008). Providing legal clarity and securing policy space for public services through a legal framework for services of general economic interest: Squaring the circle? European Public Law, 14(3), 377–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kretschmer, T., & Grajek, M. (2008). Critical mass. ESMT Working Paper 08-004. European School of Management and Technology.

  • Kubota, K. (1999). Trade negotiations in the presence of network externalities. The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series: 2317.

  • Liebowitz, S. J., & Margolis, S. E. (1994). Network externality: An uncommon tragedy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(2), 133–150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J., & Margolis, S. E. (1995). Path dependence, lock-in and history. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 11(1), 205–226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magat, W. A., & Kip Viscusi, W. (1992). Informational approaches to regulation (p. 1992). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neergaard, U. (2008). Services of general (economic) interest and the services directive: What is left out, why and where to go? In U. Neergaard, R. Nielsen, & L. Roseberry (Eds.), The services directive: Consequences for the welfare state and the european social model (pp. 65–120). Copenhagen: DJØF Publishing).

    Google Scholar 

  • Neergaard, U. (2009). Services of general economic interest: The nature of the beast. In M. Krajewski, U. Neergaard, & J. van de Gronden (Eds.), The changing legal framework for services of general interest in Europe: Between competition and solidarity (pp. 17–50). The Hague: TMC Asser Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Neergaard, U. (2011). The Commission’s soft law in the area of services of general economic interest. In E. Szyszczak, J. Davies, M. Andenæs, & T. Bekkedal (Eds.), Developments in services of general interest (pp. 37–59). The Hague: TMC Asser Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19, 211–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pesaresi, N., Sinnaeve, A., Guigue-Koeppen, V., Wiemann, J., & Radulescu, M. (2012). The SGEI communication. Competition Policy Newsletter 1.

  • Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5, 355–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prosser, T. (2005). The limits of competition law. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2007). Promoting solidarity: From public services to a European model of competition? Common Market Law Review, 44(4), 1057–1080.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2009). A healthy approach to services of general economic interest? The BUPA judgment of the court of first instance. European Law Review, 34(1), 127–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sauter, W. (2008). Services of general economic interest and universal service in EU law. European Law Review, 33(2), 167–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sauter, W. (2013). Proportionality in EU law: A balancing act?. TILEC Discussion Paper, DP 2013-003, 25 January 2013. Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2208567.

  • Sauter, W., & Schepel, H. (2009). State and market in European Union law: The public and private spheres of the internal market before the EU courts. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1978). Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szyszczak, E. (2002). Golden shares and market governance. Legal Issues of Economic Integration, 29(3), 255–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szyszczak, E. (2007). The regulation of the state in competitive markets in the EU. Oxford: Hart Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van de Gronden, J. (2006). The internal market, the state and private initiative: A legal assessment of national mixed public-private arrangements in the light of European law. Legal Issues of Economic Integration, 33(2), 105–137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, K. W., Vernon, J. M., & Harrington, J. E., Jr. (2005). Economics of regulation and antitrust (4th ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winston, C. (2006). Government failure versus market failure: Microeconomic policy research and government performance, AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter Møllgaard.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ølykke, G.S., Møllgaard, P. What is a service of general economic interest?. Eur J Law Econ 41, 205–241 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-013-9426-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-013-9426-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation