Skip to main content
Log in

Workers’ risk underestimation and occupational health and safety regulation

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The standard treatment of occupational risk in the labour market is conducted in terms of the theory of compensating wage differentials, the basic characteristic of which is that workers can fully estimate actual occupational risks. However, research in cognitive psychology, and recent advances in economic psychology, suggest that individuals consistently underestimate risks associated with accidents. In this paper, we discuss the case when the workers systematically underestimate job risks. After presenting the standard treatment of occupational risks, and of health and safety at work regulation, we then proceed to incorporate the idea of job risk underestimation. The paper discusses the types and impact of regulation on health and safety effort in a simple framework in which workers’ beliefs concerning accident risks also play a role. The paper shows that a particular type of regulatory intervention is necessary for the risk underestimating workers not to suffer a welfare loss.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The discussion below is tangential to the methodological debate on ‘economic rationality’ between the neoclassical versus behavioural economics and its repercussions for policy (e.g. Jolls et al. 1998; Posner 1998). However, the present study abstracts from this important debate taking the empirical and theoretical evidence provided by the psychological literature at face value (see Gilbert 2006 for an interesting review).

  2. For a critical review, including the empirical findings supporting the CWD approach, see Dorman and Hagstrom (1998). In an earlier work, Leigh (1995) follows a similar critical line.

  3. There is a large body of literature examining the public management of risk and the role of key players such as public officials, risk generating firms and Courts of Law (see for instance, Hiriart et al. 2010 and references therein).

  4. There is no detailed data concerning the effects of OSH regulation in European countries and thus empirical results are not very clear, see Philipsen 2009.

  5. The public theories of regulation have traditionally assumed that regulators have sufficient information and aim to promote the public interest (e.g. Noll 1983). In this paper there is no need to assume that regulators are perfectly informed but in line with the bulk of the literature, it is assumed that they have access to more accurate data than workers concerning job risks (for a detailed review of theories of regulation, see Hägg 1997; Hertog 2010).

  6. It should be noted that the issue of the empirical testing of injury absenteeism is quite complicated given that a number of other factors also play a role in determining absenteeism levels (see for instance Reilly et al. 1995; Barmby et al. 2002). Similarly, given that job risks differ across sectors and types of jobs, the issue of regulatory differentiation also arises.

  7. Type 1 regulator will provide higher effort than Type 2 if Pw > Pr. In general, this indicates that the behaviour of the regulator is important when there are differences in risk perceptions.

  8. The ex post revision of workers risk perception is a very important issue which we do not consider in this paper. For the basic theoretical set up, see Spence 1977.

References

  • Akerlof, G., & Dickens, W. (1982). The economic consequences of cognitive dissonance. American Economic Review, 72(3), 307–319.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barmby, T. A., Ercolani, M. G., & Treble, J. G. (2002). Sickness absence: An international comparison. The Economic Journal, 112, 315–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartel, A., & Thomas, L. (1985). Direct and indirect effects of OSHA regulation: A new look at OSHA’s impact. Journal of Law and Economics, 8(1), 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (1988). A simple model for merit good arguments. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 371–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya, J., Goldman, D., & Sood, N. (2009). Market evidence of misperceived mortality risk. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 27(1), 451–462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biddle, J. E., & Zarkin, G. A. (1988). Source worker preference and market compensation for job risk. Review of Economics and Statistics, 70(4), 660–667.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bockerman, P., & Illmakunnas, P. (2008). Interaction of working conditions, job satisfaction, and sickness absences: Evidence from a representative sample of employees. Social Science and Medicine, 67, 520–528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G. (2010). Labor economics (5th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breyer, S. (1993). Breaking the vicious circle: Toward effective risk regulation. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burton, J. (2009). Workers’ compensation. In K. Dau-Schmidt, S. Harris, & O. Lobel (Eds.), Labor and employment law and economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantor, R. (1987). Long term contracts, consumption smoothing and wage-profit dynamics. Journal of Macroeconomics, 9(1), 59–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chapin, J., & Coleman, G. (2009). Optimistic bias: What you think, what you know, or whom you know? North American Journal of Psychology, 11(1), 121–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denscobe, M. (1993). Personal health and the social psychology of risk taking. Health Education Research, 8(4), 505–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dorman, P. (1996). Markets and morality: Economics, dangerous work and the value of human life. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dorman, P., & Hagstrom, P. (1998). Wage compensation for dangerous work revisited. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 52(1), 116–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrenberg, R. G., & Smith, R. (1997). Modern labor economics: Theory and public policy. New York: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furnham, A. (1988). Lay theories. Oxford: Pergamon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, D. (2006). Stumbling on happiness. London: Harper Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilovich, T., Griffin, D., & Kahneman, D. (2002). Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Glickman, T., & Gough, M. (1990). Readings in risk. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, W., & Mendeloff, J. M. (2005). The declining effects of OSHA inspections in manufacturing: 1979–1998. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 58, 571–586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gray, W., & Scholz, J. (1993). Does regulatory enforcement work? A panel analysis of OSHA enforcement. Law and Society Review, 27, 177–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guinnane, T., Jopp, T., & Streb, J. (2012). The costs and benefits of size in a mutual insurance system: The German miners’ Knappschaften, 1854–1923. In B. Harris (Ed.), Welfare and old age in Europe and North America: The development of social insurance. London: Pickering and Chatto.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guinnane, T., & Streb, J. (2012). Incentives that saved lives: Government regulation of accident insurance associations in Germany 1884–1914. Ruhr Economic Papers, 364, 1–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hägg, P. G. T. (1997). Theories of the economics of regulation: A survey of the literature from a European perspective. European Journal of Law and Economics, 4, 337–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, P. (1981). Ex ante and ex post welfare optimality under uncertainty. Economica, 48, 235–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartog, J., Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A., & Jonker, N. (2002). Linking measured risk aversion to individual characteristics. Kyklos, 55, 3–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertog, J. D. (2010). Review of economic theories of regulation, T. C. Koopmans research institute discussion paper, No. 10–18, Utrecht School of Economics, pp. 1–59.

  • Hird, J. (1994). Superfund: The political economy of environmental risk. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hiriart, Y., Martimort, D., & Pouyet, J. (2010). The public management of risk: Separating ex ante and ex post monitors. Journal of Public Economics, 94, 1008–1019.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jolls, C., Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. A. (1998). A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Review, 50(5), 1471–1550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (1982). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decisions under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 313–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (Eds.). (2000). Choices, values and frames. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lanoie, P. (1992). The impact of occupational safety and health regulation on the risk of workplace accidents: Quebec, 1983–1987. Journal of Human Resources, 27(4), 643–660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leigh, J. P. (1995). Compensating wages, value of statistical life, and inter-industry differentials. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 28(1), 83–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, L., & Safer, M. (2002). Sources of bias in memory for emotions. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 11, 169–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lloyd, A. J. (2001). The extent of patients’ understanding of the risk of treatments. Quality and Safety in Health Care, 10, i14–i18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendeloff, J. M. (1979). Regulating safety: An economic and political analysis of occupational safety and health policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendeloff, J. M. (2005). Inside the black box: How do OSHA inspections lead to reductions in workplace injuries. Law and Policy, 27(2), 219–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michie, S., & Williams, S. (2003). Reducing work-related psychological ill health and sickness absence: A systematic literature review. Occupational and Environment Medicine, 60, 3–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moore, M., & Viscusi, K. (1990). Compensation mechanisms for job risks: Wages, workers’ compensation and product liability. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Noll, R. G. (1983). The political foundations of regulatory policy. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 139, 377–404.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ose, S. O. (2005). Working conditions, compensation and absenteeism. Journal of Health Economics, 24, 161–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Philipsen, N. J. (2009). Compensation for industrial accidents and incentives for prevention: A theoretical and empirical perspective. European Journal of Law and Economics, 28(2), 163–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollack, R. (1998). Imagined risks and cost-benefit analysis. American Economic Review, 88, 376–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1998). Rational choice, behavioral economics and the law. Stanford Law Review, 50, 1551–1575.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pouliakas, K., & Theodossiou, I. (forthcoming). The economics of health and safety at work: An interdisciplinary review of the theory and policy. Journal of Economic Surveys. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6419.2011.00699.x.

  • Purse, K. (2004). Work-related fatality risks and neoclassical compensating wage differentials. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28(4), 597–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reilly, B., Paci, P., & Holl, P. (1995). Unions, safety committees and workplace injuries. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 33(2), 275–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. (1991). Toil and toxics: Workplace struggles and political strategies for occupational health. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers, A. E., Addington-Hall, J. M., & Abery, A. J. (2000). Knowledge and communication difficulties for patients with chronic heart failure: Qualitative study. British Medical Journal, 321, 605–607.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, D. (2001). Advanced macroeconomics. Boston: McGraw-Hill Higher Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1986). The theory of equalizing differences. In O. Ashenfelter & R. Layard (Eds.), The handbook of labor economics. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruser, A., & Smith, R. (1991). Re-estimating OSHA effects. Journal of Human Resources, 26, 212–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salanie, F., & Treich, N. (2009). Regulation in happyville. The Economic Journal, 119, 665–679.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo, A. (1983). Ex post welfare and the theory of merit goods. Economica, 50, 19–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scholz, J., & Gray, W. (1990). OSHA enforcement and workplace injuries: A behavioral approach to risk assessment. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 3, 283–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, S. (2009). Occupational safety and health regulation. In K. Dau-Schmidt, S. Harris, & O. Lobel (Eds.), Labor and employment law and economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (1984). Liability from harm versus regulation of safety. Journal of Legal Studies, 13, 357–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepperd, J. A., Carroll, P., Grace, J., & Terry, M. (2002). Exploring the causes of comparative optimism. Psychologica Belgica, 42, 65–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P. (2000). The perception of risk. London: Earthscan Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P., Fischhoff, B., & Lichtenstein, S. (1982). Facts versus fears: Understanding perceived risk. In D. Kahneman, P. Slovic, & A. Tversky (Eds.), Judgement under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases (pp. 463–489). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Spence, M. (1977). Consumer misperceptions, product failure and producer liability. Review of Economic Studies, 44(3), 561–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, C. R. (2000). Cognition and cost-benefit analysis. In M. D. Adler & E. A. Posner (Eds.), Cost-benefit analysis, legal, economic and philosophical perspectives (pp. 223–267). Chigaco: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. H. (2003). Libertarian paternalism. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceeedings, 93, 175–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge—improving decisions about health, wealth and happiness. Chicago: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 18, 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Koehler, D. (1994). Support theory: A nonextensional representation of subjective probability. Psychological Review, 101(4), 547–567.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1980). Imperfect job risk information and optimal workmen’s compensation benefits. Journal of Public Economics, 14(3), 319–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1986). The impact of occupational safety and health regulation, 1973–1983. Rand Journal of Economics, 17(2), 567–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1993). The value of risks to life and health. Journal of Economic Literature, 31(4), 1912–1946.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1996). Economic foundations of the current regulatory reform efforts. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(3), 119–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1998). Rational risk policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (2006). Regulation of health, safety, and environmental risks. Harvard Law School Discussion Paper, No 544, pp. 1–89.

  • Weinstein, N. D. (1989). Optimistic biases about personal risks. Science, 246, 1232–1233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein, N. D., & Klein, W. M. (1996). Unrealistic optimism: Present and future. Journal of Social and Clinical Psychology, 15(1), 1–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The financial support of the European Commission under the Seventh Framework Programme, Theme HEALTH-2007-4.2-3 (Grant agreement no.: 200716) is gratefully acknowledged. The authors are also grateful to the anonymous referees of this journal for their very helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stavros A. Drakopoulos.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Drakopoulos, S.A., Theodossiou, I. Workers’ risk underestimation and occupational health and safety regulation. Eur J Law Econ 41, 641–656 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-012-9379-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-012-9379-3

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation