Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Tripartite decomposition of labor productivity growth, FDI and human development: evidence from transition economies

  • Published:
Economic Change and Restructuring Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study investigates the relative contribution of technological change, technological catch-up and capital deepening as drivers of labor productivity growth in 14 transition economies during the period 2000–2012. In addition, the study extends the usual decomposition of labor productivity growth by encompassing the impact of foreign direct investment (FDI) on labor productivity growth in transition economies. To illustrate the relative contribution of FDI as a driver of labor productivity growth, we present a simple theoretical model that augments Kohli [Labour productivity vs. total factor productivity. IFC Bulletin 20 (April), Irving Fisher Committee on Central Bank Statistics, International Statistical Institute, 2005] and Grosskopf et al. (Aggregation, efficiency, and measurement, Springer, New York, pp 97–116, 2007) decomposition of the labor productivity. The insights derived in this model provide an underpinning to the empirical analysis in this study. Using Blundell–Bond dynamic panel General Method of Moments estimators, the main finding of dynamic panel data regressions shows that technological catch-up, technological change, and human development level, trade and demographic of population ageing are the main factors that affect labor productivity growth in transition countries. Furthermore, the findings of dynamic panel data regressions show insignificant positive impact of FDI on productivity growth in transition economies. One explanation is that the 14 transition economies that are included in this study do not reach a minimum human development threshold level.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: UNDP (2014) *Elmawazini et al. (2013)

Notes

  1. According to UNCTAD (2014) transition economies are 17 countries: four South East Europe (Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Serbia, Montenegro and The former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia), eleven Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) countries (Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, Russia, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Ukraine, and Uzbekistan) and Georgia.

  2. See also Spiegel (1994) for a survey.

  3. It should be noted that Badunenko et al. (2008) investigate the technological catch-up, technological change and capital accumulation. However, they did not investigate other important determinants (e.g. FDI and HDI).

  4. For example, building on Malmquist (1953), Kumar and Russell (2002) illustrates that labor productivity growth depends on capital deepening, efficiency change, and technical change.

  5. If f is assumed to be Hicks-neutral in the sense described by Aczél and Gehrig (1989), then their characterization makes the explicit dependence of f on t rather redundant.

  6. Education index is more comprehensive than mean years of schooling. Specifically, education index has two variables. It is calculated based on mean years of schooling and expected years of schooling. Barro and Lee (2013) Educational Attainment Data does not suit our study because it provides education attainment data in 5-year intervals (not annual data).

References

  • Aczél J, Gehrig W (1989) Determination of all generalized Hicks-neutral production functions. Math Soc Sci 17:33–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aitken B, Harrison A (1999) Do domestic firms benefit from foreign investment? Evidence from Venezuela. Am Econ Rev 89:605–618

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almfrajia MA, Almsafirc MK (2014) Foreign direct investment and economic growth literature review from 1994 to 2012. Soc Behav Sci 129:206–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. J Econom 68:29–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Badunenko O, Henderson DJ, Zelenyuk V (2008) Technological change and transition: relative contributions to worldwide growth during the 1990s. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 70:461–492. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008.00508.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi BH, Griffin JM (1988) A generalized error component model with heteroscedastic disturbances. Int Econ Rev 29:745–753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Lee JW (2013) A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. J Dev Econ 104:184–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J, Spiegel M (2005) Human capital and technology diffusion. In: Philippe A, Steven ND (eds) Handbook of economic growth, chap 13, vol 1, Part A. Elsevier, pp 935–966

  • Berlemann M, Wesselhöft JE (2012) Total factor productivity in german regions. CESifo Forum 13:58–65

    Google Scholar 

  • Blomstrom M (1986) Foreign investment and productive efficiency: the case of Mexico. J Ind Econ 15:97–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell RW, Bond SR (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econom 87:115–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond S, Hoeffler A, Temple J (2001) GMM estimation of empirical growth models. CEPR discussion paper no. 3048

  • Borensztein E, Gregorio J, Lee J (1998) How does foreign direct investment affect economic growth. J Int Econ 45:115–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caselli F, Esquivel G, Lefort F (1996) Reopening the convergence debate: a new look at cross-country growth empirics. J Econ Growth 1:363–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves D, Christensen L, Diewert WE (1982) The economic theory of index numbers and the measurement of input, output, and productivity. Econometrica 50:1393–1414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Centre for the Study of Living Standards (CSLS) (2003) Productivity growth and poverty reduction in developing countries, Ottawa

  • de Mello LR (1997) Foreign direct investment in developing countries and growth: a selective survey. J Dev Stud 34:1–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Morrison CJ (1986) Adjusting output and productivity indexes for changes in the terms of trade. Econ J 96:659–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov S, Hoekman B (2000) Foreign investment and productivity growth in Czech enterprises. World Bank Econ Rev 14:49–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf SN, Johnson PA, Temple JRW (2005) Growth econometrics. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 1, 1st edn. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 555–677

    Google Scholar 

  • Elmawazini K (2008) Measuring the technology diffusion from multinational enterprises. Atl Econ J 36:373–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elmawazini K (2012) Foreign affiliates, export success of local firms and host country innovation capability. J High Technol Manag Res 23:103–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elmawazini K (2014) FDI spillovers, efficiency change and host country labor productivity: evidence from GCC countries. Atl Econ J 42:399–411. doi:10.1007/s11293-014-9428-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elmawazini K (2015) Foreign affiliates, technological catch-up, and productivity growth: Evidence from MENA oil and non-oil-producing countries. J High Technol Manage Res 26(2):117–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elmawazini K, Nawnkwo S (2012) Foreign direct investment: technology gap effects on international business capabilities of Sub-Sahara Africa. Thunderbird Int Bus Rev 54(4):457–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elmawazini K, Manga P, Saadi S (2008) Multinational enterprises, technology diffusion, and host country absorptive. Glob Econ Rev 37:379–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elmawazini K, Atallah G, Nwankwo S, Dissou Y (2013) US foreign affiliates, technology diffusion and host country human development: human development index versus human capital. Ind Innov 20:69–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farla K, Denis de Crombrugghe D, Verspagen B (2016) Institutions, foreign direct investment, and domestic investment: crowding out or crowding in? World Development 881-9. Online publication. Acess date 1 Dec 2016

  • Findlay R (1978) Relative backwardness, direct foreign investment and transfer of technology. Quart J Econ 92:1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fowowe B, Shuaibu MI (2014) Is foreign direct investment good for the poor? New evidence from African countries. Econ Change Restruct 47:321–339. doi:10.1007/s10644-014-9152-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gevorkyan AV, Canuto O (2016) Financial deepening and post-crisis development in emerging markets. Palgrave Macmillan US. ISBN: 9781137522467

  • Girma S, Görg H, Pisu M (2008) Exporting linkages and productivity spillovers from foreign direct investment. Can J Econ 41:320–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giroud A, Jindra B, Marek P (2012) Heterogeneous FDI in transition economics—a novel approach to assess the developmental impact of backward linkages. World Dev 40:2206–2220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görg H, Greenaway D (2004) Much ado about nothing? Do domestic firms really benefit from foreign directinvestment? World Bank Res Obs 19:171–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grosskopf S, Kathy JH, Taylor L (2007) Sources of manufacturing productivity growth: U.S. States 1990–1999. In: Fare R, Grosskopf S, Primont D (eds) Aggregation, efficiency, and measurement. Springer, New York, pp 97–116

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen LP (1982) Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica 50:1029–1054

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Havranek T, Irsova Z (2012) Survey article: publication bias in the literature on foreign direct investment spillovers. J Dev Stud 48:1375–1396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holtz-Eakin D, Newey W, Rosen HS (1988) Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica 56:137–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iradian G (2009) What explains the rapid growth in transition economies? IMF Econ Rev 56:811–851. doi:10.1057/imfsp.2009.1

    Google Scholar 

  • Iwasaki I, Suganuma K (2015) Foreign direct investment and regional economic development in Russia: an econometric assessment. Econ Change Restruct 48:209–255. doi:10.1007/s10644-015-9161-y

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiang Y (2012) An empirical study of openness and convergence in labor productivity in the Chinese provinces. Econ Change Restruct 45:317–336. doi:10.1007/s10644-011-9120-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kheng V, Sun S, Anwar S (2016) Foreign direct investment and human capital in developing countries: a panel data approach. Econ Change Restruct 49:1–25. doi:10.1007/s10644-016-9191-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohli UR (2005) Labour productivity vs. total factor productivity. IFC Bulletin 20 (April), Irving Fisher Committee on Central Bank Statistics, International Statistical Institute

  • Kokko A (1994) Technology, market characteristics, and spillovers. J Dev Econ 43:279–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kosová R (2010) Do foreign firms crowd out domestic firms? Evidence from the Czech Republic. Rev Econ Stat 92:861–881. doi:10.1162/REST_a_00035

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar S, Russell RR (2002) Technological change, technological catch-up and capital deepening: relative contributions to growth and convergence. Am Econ Rev 92:527–549

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Heshmati A, Hjalmarsson L (1999) Parametric approaches to productivity measurement: a comparison among alternative models. Scand J Econ 101:405–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li X, Liu X (2005) Foreign direct investment and economic growth: an increasingly endogenous relationship. World Dev 33:393–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey RE (2002) Home and host country effects of FDI. NBER working paper no. 9293

  • Malmquist S (1953) Index numbers and indifference curves. Trabajos de Estatistica 4(1):209–242

  • Nelson RR, Phelps ES (1966) Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. Am Econ Rev 56:69–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Newman C, Rand J, Talbot T, Tarp F (2015) Technology transfers, foreign investment and productivity spillovers. Eur Econ Rev 76:168–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2002) Foreign direct investment for development: maximising benefits, minimising costs. ISBN: 9789264199279

  • Roodman D (2009) A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 71:135–158. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008.00542.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sadik AT, Bolbol AA (2001) Capital flows, FDI, and technology spillovers: evidence from Arab countries. World Dev 29(12):2111–2125

  • Shiu A, Heshmati A (2006) Technical change and total factor productivity growth for chinese provinces: a panel data analysis. Ratio working papers 98, The Ratio Institute

  • Spiegel M (1994) Determinants of long-run labor productivity growth: a selective survey with some new empirical results, vol 94, issue 17 of working papers in applied economic theory

  • Stehrer R, Woerz J (2009) Attract FDI!” A universal golden rule? Empirical evidence for OECD and selected non-OECD countries. Eur J Dev Res 21:95–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Syverson C (2011) What determines productivity? J Econ Lit 49:326–365. doi:10.1257/jel.49.2.326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD (2014) World investment report: investing in the SDGs: an action plan, New York: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development

  • UNDP (2014) Human development trends by indicator. http://hdr.undp.org/en/data

  • Veugelers R, Schweiger H (2016) Innovation policies in transition countries: one size fits all? Econ Change Restruct 49:241–267. doi:10.1007/s10644-015-9167-5

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Windmeijer F (2005) A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. J Econom 126:25–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (2016) Introductory econometrics: a modern approach, 6th edn. ISBN-13: 9781305270107

  • World Bank (2014) World development indicators 2014, Washington: The World Bank. http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators

  • Xu B (2000) Multinational enterprises, technology diffusion, and host country productivity growth. J Dev Econ 62:477–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank anonymous reviewers and the editor for their helpful suggestions and constructive comments that contributed to enhancing the final version of the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Khaled Elmawazini.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Table 5.

Table 5 Definitions and sources

Appendix 2: The decomposition of the labor productivity index

For further support for the inclusion of FDI and human capital stock, recall that the rate of technology diffusion or TFP can be modeled using the Benhabib and Spiegel (2005) extension of the Nelson–Phelps model [Eq. (2.1) of Benhabib and Speigel], expressed by the differential equation

$$\frac{{d\ln \left( {A\left( t \right)} \right)}}{dt} = g\left( {H\left( t \right)} \right) + c\left( {H\left( t \right)} \right)\left( {\frac{{A_{f} \left( t \right)}}{A\left( t \right)} - 1} \right),$$
(12)

where H denotes human capital stock and the subscript f refers to the frontier or the state-of-the-art technology. The growth rate given by this equation may represent, in part or in total, the term \(\hat{f}_{t} + \hat{A}\) of (7). The right-hand side of this equation represents the innovation and the catching up terms. The work of Findlay (1978) employed the Veblen and Gerschenkron hypothesis, which was later formalized and utilized by Nelson and Phelps (1966) to model the technical efficiency indices that appear in the aggregate production functions for the frontier and backwards economies. Recall that the inclusion of capital stock index in Findlay’s model indicates that the growth rate of A(t) in (12) also depends on the capital stock index of Findlay’s. This provides further support for the inclusion of FDI in (1).

Based on productivity models, it is possible to define related indices. Now we build on Kohli’s idea of decomposing labor productivity. Kohli (2005) defines the average labor productivity index, using our notation, as

$$N_{t,t - 1} = \frac{{A\left( {F_{s,t} ,t} \right)f\left( {k_{t} ,t} \right)}}{{A\left( {F_{s,t - 1} ,t - 1} \right)f\left( {k_{t - 1} ,t - 1} \right)}}$$
(13)

Starting with a production function and using the Diewert and Morrison (1986) suggestion to employ a geometric mean of the Laspeyres and Paasache like indices, Kohli gave a decomposition of the labor productivity index N t,t1 . To account for labor productivity over time, Kohli isolates the effect of changes in endowments over time and the impact of technological change to obtain a decomposition of \(N_{t,t - 1}\). Employing (2), we obtain analogously in our case the following decomposition of the labor productivity index

$$N_{t,t - 1} = f_{V,t,t - 1} \times f_{T,t,t - 1} \times TF_{V,t,t - 1} \times TF_{T,t,t - 1} ,$$
(14)

where each of these factors is given as a geometric mean of indices at their levels at period t and period t − 1, and are defined by:

$$f_{V,t,t - 1} = \sqrt {\frac{{f\left( {k_{t} ,t - 1} \right)}}{{f\left( {k_{t - 1} ,t - 1} \right)}}.\frac{{f\left( {k_{t} ,t} \right)}}{{f\left( {k_{t - 1} ,t} \right)}}}$$
$$f_{T,t,t - 1} = \sqrt {\frac{{f\left( {k_{t - 1} ,t} \right)}}{{f\left( {k_{t - 1} ,t - 1} \right)}}.\frac{{f\left( {k_{t} ,t} \right)}}{{f\left( {k_{t} ,t - 1} \right)}}}$$
$$TF_{V,t,t - 1} = \sqrt {\frac{{A_{T} \left( {F_{s} \left( t \right),t - 1} \right)}}{{A_{T} \left( {F_{s} \left( {t - 1} \right),t - 1} \right)}}.\frac{{A_{T} \left( {F_{s} \left( t \right),t} \right)}}{{A_{T} \left( {F_{s} \left( {t - 1} \right),t} \right)}}}$$
$$TF_{T,t,t - 1} = \sqrt {\frac{{A_{T} \left( {F_{s} \left( {t - 1} \right),t} \right)}}{{A_{T} \left( {F_{s} \left( {t - 1} \right),t - 1} \right)}}.\frac{{A_{T} \left( {F_{s} \left( t \right),t} \right)}}{{A_{T} \left( {F_{s} \left( t \right),t - 1} \right)}}}$$

Of course, upon writing A T in the separable form assumed in (6), it is clear that a further decomposition can be obtained which extends that given by Kohli (2005) to include an efficiency factor and a factor due to FDI in addition to those of capital deepening and technological change.

Appendix 3

Another extension which supports further our econometric model (equation) is to consider the technology function given in its intensive form, in particular, we consider one that has an autoregressive component,

$$y_{t,n} = A\left( {F_{S,t}, t} \right)y_{t - 1}^{\mu } g\left( {k_{t}, t - n} \right),$$

where g is assumed to be linearly homogeneous in the first variable. The subscript n takes the values −1, 0 or 1, and is included to clearly account for the shift in technology. It is possible to depict this geometrically with a 4-cell lattice showing the variation of the parameter t,

$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {\left( {{\text{t,\, t}} - 1} \right)} \hfill & {\left( {\text{t,\, t}} \right)} \hfill \\ {\left( {{\text{t}} - 1,\,{\text{t}} - 1} \right)} \hfill & {\left( {{\text{t}} - 1,{\text{t}}} \right)} \hfill \\ \end{array}$$

Let

$$A_{V,t,t - 1}^{L} = \frac{{y_{t,1} }}{{y_{t - 1,0} }} = \frac{{y_{t - 1,1}^{\mu } g\left( {k_{t,} t - 1} \right)}}{{y_{t - 2,0}^{\mu } g\left( {k_{t - 1,} t - 1} \right)}}$$
$$A_{V,t,t - 1}^{P} = \frac{{y_{t,0} }}{{y_{t - 1, - 1} }} = \frac{{y_{t - 1,0}^{\mu } g\left( {k_{t,} t} \right)}}{{y_{t - 2, - 1}^{\mu } g\left( {k_{t - 1,} t} \right)}}$$
$$A_{T,t,t - 1}^{L} = \frac{{y_{t - 1, - 1} }}{{y_{t - 1,0} }} = \frac{{y_{t - 2,1}^{\mu } g\left( {k_{t - 1,} t} \right)}}{{y_{t - 2,0}^{\mu } g\left( {k_{t - 1,} t - 1} \right)}}$$
$$A_{T,t,t - 1}^{P} = \frac{{y_{t,0} }}{{y_{t,1} }} = \frac{{y_{t - 1,0}^{\mu } g\left( {k_{t,} t} \right)}}{{y_{t - 1,1}^{\mu } g\left( {k_{t,} t - 1} \right)}}$$

Taking the geometric means, we get

$${\text{A}}_{{{\text{V}},{\text{t}},{\text{t}} - 1}} = \left( {{\text{A}}^{\text{L}}_{{{\text{V,t,t}} - 1}} {\text{A}}^{\text{P}}_{{{\text{V,t,t}} - 1}} } \right)^{1/2} ,\quad {\text{A}}_{{{\text{T,t,t}} - 1}} = \left( {{\text{A}}^{\text{L}}_{{{\text{T,t,t}} - 1}} {\text{A}}^{\text{P}}_{{{\text{T,t,t}} - 1}} } \right)^{1/2}$$

Finally, it is easy to see that

$$A_{t,t - 1} = \frac{{y_{t,0} }}{{y_{t - 1,0} }} = A_{V,t,t - 1} \cdot A_{T,t,t - 1} .$$

For TFP, it is clear that

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{T,t,t - 1} & = \sqrt {\frac{{y_{t - 1, - 1} }}{{y_{t - 1,0} }}\frac{{y_{t,0} }}{{y_{t,1} }}} \\ & = A_{T,t,t - 1} \\ \end{aligned}$$

And so Kohli’s conclusion that TFP is equal to the technological change when explaining the average productivity of labor extends to this case as well. Now, it is easy to see that the multiplicative functional A T (F s,t , t) can simply be accounted for. Let

$$b_{L,t,0} = A_{T} \left( {F_{s,t} , t} \right)y_{t,0}$$
$$b_{L,t,1} = A_{T} \left( {F_{s,t} , t - 1} \right)y_{t,1}$$
$$b_{L,t - 1,0} = A_{T} \left( {F_{s,t - 1} , t - 1} \right)y_{t - 1,0}$$
$$b_{L,t - 1,t - 1} = A_{T} \left( {F_{s,t - 1} , t} \right)y_{t - 1, - 1}$$

Following along the same lines as above, we obtain an expression labor productivity index B t,t−1

$$B_{t,t - 1} = \frac{{A_{T} \left( { F_{s,t,} t} \right)}}{{A_{T } \left( { F_{s,t - 1} , t - 1 } \right)}}A_{t,t - 1} .$$

In other words, we obtain a tripartite decomposition of the index B t,t−1, which is also a simple extension of Kohli’s labor productivity index, modified by a term accounting for FDI.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Elmawazini, K., Saleeby, E.G., Ibn el Farouk, A. et al. Tripartite decomposition of labor productivity growth, FDI and human development: evidence from transition economies. Econ Change Restruct 51, 153–171 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-016-9197-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-016-9197-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation