Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Influence of Collective Action on the Demand for Voluntary Climate Change Mitigation in Hypothetical and Real Situations

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this experiment, we investigate demand for voluntary climate change mitigation. Subjects decide between a cash prize and an allowance from the EU Emissions Trading Scheme for one ton of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) that will be deleted after the completion of the experiment. Decisions were implemented either as purely individual or as a collective action using majority voting. We vary the incentives of the decision situation in which we distinguish between real monetary incentives and a hypothetical decision situation with, and without, a cheap talk script. Collective decision making affects demand positively in the hypothetical decision situation only and we observe a significant hypothetical bias in the demand for voluntary climate change mitigation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In this paper, all WTP values are, if necessary, converted to €  values using the 2010 ECB average reference exchange rate for US$ (€1 \(=\) US$ 1.3257) or GBP (€1 \(=\) GBP 0.8578).

  2. This variant of the iterative bidding game with an ascending sequence may induce starting point bias (e.g. Kang et al. 2013). We tested the null hypothesis that the coefficients for the price group assigned to the respondent are jointly equal to zero. We cannot reject the null hypothesis for all treatments.

  3. For the following hypotheses we use the cheap talk variant of the hypothetical treatment, because for stated preferences applications this is generally considered as the more robust procedure to elicit WTP.

  4. A transaction confirmation is available under https://bsturm.htwk-leipzig.de/uehleke/fairpayclim/.

  5. Note that 173 participants (5.6 % of the sample) decided inconsistently, because they chose the certificate at a high price, but not at a low price. We did not exclude these participants, since we are interested in the overall behavioural effect. A separate analysis shows that excluding these participants has no effect on the results.

  6. Results can be requested from the corresponding author.

  7. In the following we refer to the lower bound Turnbull WTP when we write Turnbull WTP or WTP.

  8. The test statistic for the difference in average WTP constitutes \(t=\frac{\overline{WTP}_1 -\overline{WTP}_2 }{\sqrt{\hat{\sigma }_1^2 +\hat{\sigma }_2^2 }}\) (Haab and McConnell 2003, p. 76; Carson et al. 2004, p. 183).

  9. The WTP calculation with the fitted shares is given in “Appendix 7”.

  10. The parametric results confirm the univariate finding that there is no effect of cheap talk. We nevertheless repeated the parametric analyses without pooling which did not change results. Results can be requested from the corresponding author.

  11. Note that it is not possible to compare effect sizes across different logit models. A test for difference in hypothetical bias between Ind and Coll requires the respective interaction effect, which in a separate regression is not significant. Thus we cannot reject the hypothesis of equal hypothetical bias in Ind and Coll.

  12. We confirmed that the interaction effect is significant for all observations with the stata user written programme inteff (Norton et al. 2004).

  13. Results in “Appendices 9 and 10”.

  14. See for example https://www.europol.europa.eu/content/press/carbon-credit-fraud-causes-more-5-billion-euros-damage-european-taxpayer-1265.

References

  • Aadland D, Caplan AJ (2003) Willingness to pay for curbside recycling with detection and mitigation of hypothetical bias. AJAE 85(2):492–502

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aadland D, Caplan AJ (2006) Cheap talk reconsidered: new evidence from CVM. J Econ Behav Organ 60(4):562–578

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Achtnicht M (2012) German car buyers’ willingness to pay to reduce \(\text{ CO }_{2}\) emissions. Clim Change 113(3):679–697

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alpizar F, Carlsson F, Johansson-Stenman O (2008) Does context matter more for hypothetical than for actual contributions? Evidence from a natural field experiment. Exp Econ 11(3):299–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J (1990) Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm glow giving. Econ J 100(401):464–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard M, Dreber A, Strimling P et al (2013) The subgroup problem: when can binding voting on extractions from a common pool resource overcome the tragedy of the commons? J Econ Behav Organ 91:122–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blasch J, Farsi M (2012) Retail demand for voluntary carbon—a choice experiment among Swiss consumers. IED working paper no. 18. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2145267

  • Blumenschein K, Blomquist GC, Johannesson M et al (2008) Eliciting willingness to pay without bias: evidence from a field experiment. Econ J 118(525):114–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brouwer R, Brander L, Van Beukering P (2008) “A convenient truth”: air travel passengers willingness to pay to offset their \(\text{ CO }_{2 }\)emissions. Clim Change 90(3):299–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown TC, Ajzen I, Hrubes D (2003) Further tests of entreaties to avoid hypothetical bias in referendum contingent valuation. JEEM 46(2):353–361

    Google Scholar 

  • Carson RT, Hanemann WM (2005) Contingent valuation. In: Mäler KG, Vincent JR (eds) Handbook of environmental economics, Elsevier, pp 821–936

  • Carson RT, Conaway MB, Hanemann WM et al (2004) Valuing oil spill prevention: a case study of California’s Central Coast. In: Bateman IJ (ed) The economics of non-market goods and resources, vol 5. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Champ PA, Moore R, Bishop RC (2009) A comparison of approaches to mitigate hypothetical bias. ARER 38(2):166–180

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper P, Gregory LP, Bateman IJ (2004) The structure of motivation for contingent values: a case study of lake water quality improvement. Ecol Econ 50(1–2):69–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crumpler H, Grossman PJ (2008) An experimental test of warm glow giving. J Public Econ 92(5–6):1011–1021

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cummings RG, Harrison GW, Rutström EE (1995) Homegrown values and hypothetical surveys: is the dichotomous choice approach incentive-compatible? Am Econ Rev 85(1):260–266

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummings RG, Elliot S, Harrison GW et al (1997) Are hypothetical referenda incentive-compatible? J Polit Econ 105(3):609–621

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cummings RG, Taylor LO (1999) Unbiased value estimates for environmental goods: a cheap talk design for the contingent valuation method. Am Econ Rev 89(3):649–665

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diederich J, Goeschl T (2014a) Willingness to pay for voluntary climate action and its determinants: field-experimental evidence. ERE 57(3):405–429

    Google Scholar 

  • Diederich J, Goeschl T (2014b) Motivational drivers of the private provision of public goods: evidence from a large framed field experiment. Discussion paper series/University of Heidelberg, Department of Economics 0561, urn:nbn:de:bsz:16-heidok-167229

  • Fischbacher U, Gächter S, Fehr E (2001) Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Econ Lett 71(3):397–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haab TC, McConnell KE (2003) Valuing environmental and natural resources. The econometrics of non-market valuation. E, Elgar, Cheltenham, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Hauser OP, Rand DG, Peysakhovich A et al (2014) Cooperating with the future. Nature 511:220–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansson-Stenman O, Svedsäter H (2012) Self-image and valuation of moral goods: stated versus actual willingness to pay. J Econ Behav Organ 84(3):879–891

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Knetsch JL (1992) Valuing public goods: the purchase of moral satisfaction. JEEM 22(1):57–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Kang H, Haab TC, Interis MG (2013) Identifying inconsistent responses in dichotomous choice contingent valuation with follow-up questions. Resour Energy Econ 35(3):396–411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koch N, Fuss S, Grosjean G et al (2014) Causes of the EU ETS price drop: recession, CDM, renewable policies or a bit of everything? New evidence. Energ Policy 73:676–685

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kosfeld M, Okada A, Riedl A (2009) Institution formation in public goods games. Am Econ Rev 99(4):1335–1355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kroll S, Cherry TL, Shogren JF (2007) Voting, punishment, and public goods. Econ Inq 45(3):557–570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landry CE, List JA (2007) Using ex ante approaches to obtain credible signals for value in contingent markets: evidence from the field. Am J Agric Econ 89(2):420–429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liebe U, Preisendörfer P, Meierhoff J (2011) To pay or not to pay: competing theories to explain individuals’ willingness to pay for public environmental goods. Environ Behav 43(1):106–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List JA (2001) Do explicit warnings eliminate the hypothetical bias in elicitation procedures? Evidence from field auctions for sportscards. Am Econ Rev 91(5):1498–1507

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long JS, Freese J (2014) Regression models for categorical dependent variables in Stata, 3rd edn. Stata Press, College Station

    Google Scholar 

  • Löschel A, Sturm B, Vogt C (2013) The demand for climate change mitigation–an empirical assessment for Germany. Econ Lett 118:415–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Löschel A, Sturm B, Uehleke R (2014) Revealed preferences for climate change mitigation when the purely individual perspective is relaxed—evidence from a framed field experiment. ZEW discussion paper no. 13-006, Mannheim. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2217489

  • MacKerron GJ, Egerton C, Gaskell C et al (2009) Willingness to pay for carbon offset certification and co-benefits among (high-)flying young adults in UK. Energy Policy 37(4):1372–1381

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Margreiter M, Sutter M, Dittrich D (2005) Individual and collective choice and voting in common pool resource problem with heterogeneous actors. ERE 32(2):241–271

    Google Scholar 

  • Mjelde JW, Jin YH, Lee C et al (2012) Development of a bias ratio to examine factors influencing hypothetical bias. J Environ Manag 95(1):39–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morrison M, Brown TC (2009) Testing the effectiveness of certainty scales, cheap talk, and dissonance-minimization in reducing hypothetical bias in contingent valuation studies. ERE 44(3):307–326

    Google Scholar 

  • Moser R, Raffaelli R, Notaro S (2014) Testing hypothetical bias with a real choice experiment using respondents’ own money. Eur Rev Agric Econ 41(1):25–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mozumder P, Berrens RP (2011) Social context, financial stakes and hypothetical bias: an induced value referendum experiment. Appl Econ 43(29):4487–4499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy JJ, Allen PG, Stevens TH et al (2005) A meta-analysis of hypothetical bias in stated preference valuation. ERE 30(3):313–325

    Google Scholar 

  • Norton EC, Wang H, Ai C (2004) Computing interaction effects and standard errors in logit and probit models. Stata J 4(2):154–167

    Google Scholar 

  • Plott CR, Zeiler K (2011) The willingness to pay-willingness to accept gap, the endowment effect, subject misconceptions, and experimental procedures for eliciting valuations: reply. Am Econ Rev 101(2):1012–1028

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spash CL (2006) Non-economic motivation for contingent values: rights and attitudinal beliefs in the willingness to pay for environmental improvements. Land Econ 82(4):602–622

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugden R (1984) Reciprocity: the supply of public goods through voluntary contributions. Econ J 94(376):772–787

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steg L, van den Berg AE, De Groot JIM (2013) Environmental psychology. An introduction, Wiley-Blackwell, Chichester

    Google Scholar 

  • Steg L, Dreijerink L, Abrahamse W (2005) Factors influencing the acceptability of energy policies: a test of VBN theory. J Environ Psychol 25(4):415–425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern PC, Dietz T, Abel T et al (1999) A value-belief-norm theory of support for social movements: the case of environmentalism. Hum Ecol Rev 6(2):81–97

    Google Scholar 

  • Veronesi M, Alberini A, Cooper JC (2011) Implications of bid design and willingness-to-pay distribution for starting point bias in double-bounded dichotomous choice contingent valuation surveys. ERE 49(2):199–215

    Google Scholar 

  • Walker J, Gardner R, Herr A et al (2000) Collective choice in the commons: experimental results on proposed allocation rules and votes. Econ J 110(460):212–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Financial support by the German Federal Ministry of Education and Research (FairPayClim FKZ 01LA1108B) is gratefully acknowledged. We thank workshop participants at the ZEW Mannheim, Carlo Gallier and two anonymous referees for valuable comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Reinhard Uehleke.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Information Screen

1.1 Information on the European Emissions Trading System

The EU Emissions Trading System for carbon dioxide (\(\hbox {CO}_{2})\) came into force in 2005. Emission trading is the key instrument of climate policy in Europe, which is based on a simple principle: It is specified how much \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) the participating sectors (power generators and energy-intensive industries) are allowed to emit until 2020. This total amount is distributed as emission rights from the state (so-called “Certificates”) to the companies. For each unit of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emitted, the company must give such a certificate to the state. The certificates can be traded between companies.

For every ton of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) that is emitted by a facility, such as a coal power plant, the plant operator has to show appropriate authorization in the form of a certificate. This has an important consequence: If the total quantity of allowances is reduced, then the total emissions must be reduced simply because the plant operators have fewer allowances at their disposal. This means that if a certificate for a ton of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) is bought and deleted, the total \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions are reduced by exactly this one ton.

Emission trading has a central advantage. It ensures that avoidance of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions takes place where it is cheapest. Companies with inexpensive ways to avoid \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) will sell allowances. Companies where avoidance is rather expensive purchase certificates. This trade ensures that the emission target is achieved at minimal cost.

European electricity producers and the energy-intensive industry may emit a total of about 2 billion tons \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) in 2014. In comparison, the global \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions in 2013 were approximately 36 billion tons of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\).

To sum up: If you decrease the total amount of allowances in the EU ETS, European total emissions of \(\hbox {CO}_{2 }\)are reduced.

Appendix 2: Instruction Screen for the REAL_Ind Treatment

1.1 Instructions

  • 1. Payoff

  • You can now choose between a cash payment, and a certificate of one ton of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions from the EU Emissions Trading System. The probability that you win and your decisions will be realized is 20 %. Therefore, it is in your interest that you make every decision as if your decision would be realized.

  • Won certificates will be removed permanently from the trade for you by the research team of the Leipzig University of Applied Sciences. Due to the deletion of a certificate, European \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions will be reduced by one ton.

  • 2. Decision

  • You will have three possibilities to decide between a cash payment and the deletion of a certificate in the following form:

  • Please choose now between the cash payment or the emissions trading certificate about one ton of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) with subsequent deletion.

  • I would like the ...

  • () ... €€ Euro cash payment

  • () ... emissions trading certificate about one ton of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)

  • For the winners one the three decisions is randomly selected and depending on how you have chosen in this situation, you receive the cash payout or a certificate that will be deleted for you by the research team.

  • The winners will be notified by email. A summary of the study and the verification of the amount of deleted certificates will be published on the website of the Faculty of Business Administration of the Leipzig University of Applied Sciences.

Appendix 3: Instruction Screen for the REAL_Coll Treatment

1.1 Instructions

  • 1. Payoff

  • You can now choose as a group between a cash payment, and a certificate of one ton of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions from the EU Emissions Trading System. The probability that your group wins and the decision of your group will be realized is 20 %. Therefore, it is in your interest that you make every decision as if you would be realized.

  • Won certificates will be removed permanently from the trade for you by the research team of the Leipzig University of Applied Sciences. Due to the deletion of a certificate, European \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) emissions will be reduced by one ton.

  • 2. Voting

  • You can now vote on whether each member of your group receives a cash payment or whether all members receive a certificate for deletion. Your group is composed of 100 participants. If more than half of the participants vote for the cash payment, each participant will receive the cash payment and if more than half of the participants vote for the deletion of a certificate, each participant will receive a certificate for deletion.

  • You will have three possibilities to decide between a cash payment and the deletion of a certificate in the following form:

  • Please vote now for the cash payment or for the emissions trading certificate about one ton of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) with subsequent deletion.

  • I vote for ...

  • () ... €€ Euro cash payment

  • () ... The emissions trading certificate through a ton of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)

  • For the winning group one of the three decisions is randomly chosen and depending on how the group has decided in this situation, you receive the cash payout or a certificate that will be deleted for you by the research team.

  • The winners will be notified by email. A summary of the study and the verification of the amount of deleted certificates will be published on the website of the Faculty of Business Administration of the Leipzig University of Applied Sciences.

Appendix 4: Cheap Talk Script

In surveys is often observed that some respondents state to be willing to pay large amounts for environmental goods such as clean air. Probably these respondents do not account in this moment that they would have to dispense with other things, if they had to actually pay he amount of money they stated in the survey. We therefore ask you to decide in the following situations as if your decision would have real consequences, that means as if you actually received either the cash payment or the certificate. The results of the study will be published on the website of the Faculty of Business Administration of the Leipzig University of Applied Sciences.

Appendix 5: Calculation of Turnbull WTP

The lower bound Turnbull is computed in the following steps:

  1. 1.

    Calculate the share of no answers: \(\hbox {F}_{\mathrm{j}}=\hbox {N}_{\mathrm{j}}/\hbox {T}_{\mathrm{j}}\)

  2. 2.

    Compare \(\hbox {F}_{\mathrm{j}}\) with \(\hbox {F}_{\mathrm{j+1}}\), if \(\hbox {F}_{\mathrm{j}}< \hbox {F}_{\mathrm{j+1}}\) continue, if \(\hbox {F}_{\mathrm{j}}>= \hbox {F}_{\mathrm{j+1} }\) these cells are pooled and the combined no shares of these cells calculated: \(\hbox {F}_{\mathrm{j}}\)*= \(\hbox {N}_{\mathrm{j}}\)*/\(\hbox {T}_{\mathrm{j}}\)*

  3. 3.

    This is repeated until a monotonously increasing cdf is formed.

  4. 4.

    Calculate \(\hbox {f}_{\mathrm{j}}\)*= \(\hbox {F}_{\mathrm{j+1}}\)*- \(\hbox {F}_{\mathrm{j}}\)* for each bid level t. This corresponds to a consistent estimator of the probability that WTP falls between the price j and price j+1.

  5. 5.

    Multiply every bid with the according probability that WTP falls between this bid and the next higher bid t+1.

  6. 6.

    Sum over the quantities of step 5 to obtain lower bound Turnbull WTP, which is then: \(E_{LB} (WTP)=\sum _{j=0}^M {t_j (F_{j+1}^*-} F_j^*)\), and can be interpreted analogous to the consumer surplus as sum of the marginal value multiplied by the adapted quantitites, or the integer over the quantity of a demand curve (Haab and McConnell 2003).

  7. 7.

    Calculate the variance: \(V\left( {E_{LB} } \right) =\sum _{j=1}^{M^{*}} \frac{F_j^*\left( {1-F_j^*} \right) }{T_j^*}\left( {t_j -t_{j-1} } \right) ^{2}\), where \(\hbox {T}_{\mathrm{j}}^{*}\) is the common amount of observations of the eventually pooled bid cell.

Appendix 6

See Table 13.

Table 13 Lower bound Turnbull for REAL_Coll without five observations at bid=30

Appendix 7

See Table 14.

Table 14 Turnbull WTP (fitted) for REAL_Ind and REAL_Coll

Appendix 8

See Table 15.

Table 15 Covariates for the attitudes towards the environment and climate policies

Appendix 9

See Table 16.

Table 16 Hypothetical bias without different income categories (Ind)

Appendix 10

See Table 17.

Table 17 Hypothetical bias without different income categories (Coll)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Uehleke, R., Sturm, B. The Influence of Collective Action on the Demand for Voluntary Climate Change Mitigation in Hypothetical and Real Situations. Environ Resource Econ 67, 429–454 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0028-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0028-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation