Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Common Pool Politics and Inefficient Fishery Management

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Fisheries management often fails because total allowable catches (TACs) are set at inefficiently high levels. To study why decision-makers choose such high TACs, we model the annual negotiation on TACs as a dynamic game in discrete time. TACs are fixed by majority decision in a council consisting of decision-makers who are heterogeneous with respect to their discount rates. We show that the optimal feedback strategy for the less patient decision-makers will set inefficiently high TACs in Markov-perfect Nash equilibrium. A binding commitment to a long-term management plan could help solving this problem and lead to a more sustainable fishery management.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The TAC is then divided in form of quotas among the different members of the fisheries sector. Management systems differ in the allocation mechanisms. Under a system of individual transferable quotas (ITQs), fishing quotas belong to individual fishermen and are freely transferable. Other systems include individual vessel quotas (IVQ), or forms of non-transferable quotas. The common denominator of TAC/quota management systems is that they effectively prevent overfishing only if the TACs are set at sufficiently restrictive levels.

  2. Another difference that undoubtedly has an influence on the difference in efficiency of fisheries management programs between the two sets of countries is that New Zealand and Iceland have ITQ-based catch share programs, which are less common in the Europe, USA and Chile. We come back to this issue in the Discussion in Sect. 6.

  3. Note that this refers to the discount factors of decision-makers. The discount rates of individual fishermen, in turn, may be influenced by the management system resulting from the decision-making process (Asche 2001; The et al. 2013; Newell et al. 2005).

References

  • Antoniadou E, Kouluvatianos C, Mirman LJ (2013) Strategic exploitation of a common-property resource under uncertainty. J Environ Econ Manag 65(1):28–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asche F (2001) Fishermen’s discount rates in ITQ systems. Environ Resour Econ 19:403–410

  • Arnason R (1996) On the ITQ fisheries management system in Iceland. Rev Fish Biol Fish 6:63–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bailey M, Rashid Sumaila U, Lindroos M (2010) Application of game theory to fisheries over three decades. Fish Res 102(1–2):1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breton M, Keoula MY (2014) A great fish war model with asymmetric players. Ecol Econ 97:209–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Churchill R, Owen D (2010) The EC common fisheries policy, 1st edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Clark CW (1990) Mathematical Bioeconomics, 2nd edn. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Costello C, Gaines SD, Iynham J (2008) Can catch shares prevent fisheries collapse? Science 321:1678–1681

  • Daw T, Gray T (2005) Fisheries science and sustainability in international policy: a study of failure in the European Union’s Common Fisheries Policy. Mar Policy 29:189–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delaney AE, Hastie JE (2007) Lost in translation: differences in role identities between fisheries scientists and managers. Ocean Coast Manag 50:661–682

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2009) Green paper on the reform of the common fisheries policy

  • FAO Fisheries and Aquaculture Department (2012) The state of world fisheries and aquaculture 2012. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome

  • Franchino F, Rahming A (2003) Biased ministers, inefficiency and control in distributive policies: an application to the EU fisheries policy. Eur Union Polit 4:11–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Froese R (2011) Fishery reform slips through the net. Nature 475:7

  • Froese R, Branch T, Proelss A, Quaas M, Sainsbury K, Zimmermann C (2011) Generic harvest control rules for European fisheries. Fish Fish 12:340–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon H (1954) The economic theory of a common-property resource: the fishery. J Polit Econ 62:124–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hilborn R (2007) Defining success in fisheries and conflicts in objectives. Mar Policy 31:153–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Homans FR, Wilen JE (1997) A model of regulated open access resource use. Environ Econ Manag 32:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kapaun U, Quaas M (2013) Does the optimal size of a fish stock increase with environmental uncertainties? Environ Resour Econ 54(2):293–310

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khalilian S, Froese R, Proelss A, Requate T (2010) Designed for failure: a critique of the common fisheries policy of the European Union. Mar Policy 34:1178–1182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kronbak L, Lindroos M (2006) An enforcement-coalition model: fishermen and authorities forming coalitions. Environ Resour Econ 35(3):169–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland F, Prescott E (1977) Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. J Polit Econ 85:473–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leal C, Quinones R, Chavéz C (2010) What factors affect the decision making process when setting TACs?: the case of Chilean fisheries. Mar Policy 34:1183–1195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levhari D, Mirman LJ (1980) The great fish war: An example using a dynamic Cournot–Nash solution. Bell J Econ 11(1):322–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lock K, Leslie S (2007) New Zealand’s quota management system: a history of the first 20 years. Motu Working Paper No. 07-02

  • Mardle S, Pascoe S (2002) Modelling the effects of trade-offs between long and short-term objectives in fisheries management. J Environ Manag 65:49–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munro G (1979) The optimal management of transboundary renewable resources. Can J Econ 12(3):355–376

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newell RG, Sanchirico JN, Kerr S (2005) Fishing quota market. Environ Econ Manag 49:437–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quaas M, Froese R, Herwartz H, Requate T, Schmidt J, Voss R (2012) Fishing industry borrows from natural capital at high shadow interest rates. Ecol Econ 82:45–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okey TA (2003) Membership of the eight Regional Fishery Management Councils in the United States: are special interests over-represented? Mar Policy 27:193–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed WJ (1979) Optimal escapement levels in stochastic and deterministic harvesting models. J Environ Econ Manag 6:350–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riboni A (2010) Committees as substitutes for commitment. Int Econ Rev 51(1):213–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg AA, Swasey JH, Bowman M (2006) Rebuilding US fisheries: progress and problems. Front Ecol Environ 4:303–308

  • Sinn H-W (2008) Public policies against global warming: a supply-side approach. Int Tax Public Finance 15:360–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The LSL, The LCL, Sumaila UR, Cheung W (2013) Time discounting and the overexploitation of coral reefs. Environ Resour Econ 1–24. doi:10.1007/s10640-013-9674-7

  • UNCLOS (1982) United Nations convention on the law of the sea. United Nations, New York

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Julia Hoffmann.

Additional information

The authors are grateful to Florian Diekert and Linda Kleemann for helpful comments on a previous draft. This study was supported by the Kiel Cluster of Excellence Future Ocean.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Propositions 12

Assume a finite time horizon of \(T\) periods. In the last period \(T\), the optimal escapement levels are determined by the condition \(\pi '(s_T^*)=0\), for both types of decision-maker. In period \(T-1\), the Bellman equations thus read, using subscripts \(T-1\) for the corresponding value functions,

$$\begin{aligned} v_{T-1}(x,i)&=\max \limits _{0\le s\le x}\left[ \pi (x)-\pi (s)+\rho _i\,E_z\left[ \pi (z\,g(s))-\pi (s_T^*)\right] \right] \\&=\pi (x)-\pi (S_i^*(x))+\rho _i\,E_z\left[ \pi (z\,g(S_i^*(x)))-\pi (s_T^*)\right] \\ V_{T-1}(x,p)&=\max \limits _{0\le s\le x}\left\{ \pi (x)-\pi (s)+\rho _p\,E\left[ \pi (z\,g(s))-\pi (s_T^*)\right] \right\} \\&=\pi (x)-\pi (S_p^*(x))+\rho _p\,E_z\left[ \pi (z\,g(S_p^*(x)))-\pi (s_T^*)\right] \\ v_{T-1}(x,p)&=\pi (x)-\pi (S^*_p(x))+\rho _i\,E_z\left[ \pi (z\,g(S^*_p(x)))-\pi (s_T^*)\right] \\ V_{T-1}(x,i)&=\pi (x)-\pi (S^*_i(x))+\rho _p\,E\left[ \pi (z\,g(S^*_i(x)))-\pi (s_T^*)\right] \end{aligned}$$

where we have used the guess (which is to be verified) that \(S^*_j(x)=\min \{x,s_j^*\}\) is the optimal feedback policy for type \(j\in \{i,p\}\).

In \(T-2\), and in all periods before \(T-2\), the Bellman equation for the case where type \(p\) rules reads

$$\begin{aligned} V_{T-2}(x,p)\!&= \!\max \limits _{0\le s\le x}\left\{ \pi (x)\!-\!\pi (s)\!+\!\rho _p\,E_z\left[ q\,V_{T-1}(z\,g(s),i) +(1-q)\,V_{T-1}(z\,g(s),p)\right] \right\} \\&= \max \limits _{0\le s\le x}\Big \{\pi (x)-\pi (s)+\rho _p\,E_z \big [\pi (z\,g(s))\\&\quad +\,\,q\,\left( -\pi (S_i^*(z\,g(s)))+\rho _p\,E_{z'} \left[ \pi (z'\,g(S_i^*(z\,g(s))))\right] \right) \\&\quad +\,\,(1-q)\,\left( -\pi (S_p^*(z\,g(s)))+\rho _p\,E_{z'} \left[ \pi (z'\,g(S_p^*(z\,g(s))))\right] \right) \big ]-\rho _i\,\pi (s_T^*)\Big \} \end{aligned}$$

Using that \(s_p^*\) is self-sustaining, i.e. that \(g(s_p^*)>s_p^*\) with probability one, it follows for an interior solution for the optimization problem that \(S_p^*(\hat{s}_p)=s_p^*\). Since \(s_i^*<s_p^*\) this also implies \(S_i^*(\hat{s}_p)=s_i^*\). Thus, the first-order condition for the optimization problem is

$$\begin{aligned} \pi '(s)=\rho _p\,E_z\big [\pi '(z\,g(s))\,z\,g'(z)\big ], \end{aligned}$$

which is identical to the first-order condition (5) for the optimal escapement level for type \(p\). This proves Proposition 1.

In \(T-2\), the Bellman equation for the case where type \(i\) rules reads

$$\begin{aligned} v_{T-2}(x,i)&= \max \limits _{0\le s\le x}\left\{ \pi (x)-\pi (s)+\rho _i\,E_z\left[ q\,v_{T-1}(z\,g(s),i)+(1-q) \,v_{T-1}(z\,g(s),p)\right] \right\} \\&= \max \limits _{0\le s\le x}\big \{\pi (x)-\pi (s)+\rho _i\,E_z\big [\pi (z\,g(s)) +q\,\left( -\pi (S_i^*(z\,g(s)))\right. \\&\left. +\,\rho _i\,E_{z'}\left[ \pi (z'\,g(S_i^*(z\,g(s))))\right] \right) +(1-q)\,\left( -\pi (S_p^*(z\,g(s)))\right. \\&\left. +\,\rho _i\,E_{z'}\left[ \pi (z'\,g(S_p^*(z\,g(s)))) \right] \right) \big ]-\rho _i\,\pi (s_T^*) \big \} \end{aligned}$$

We start with the guess that the solution \(\hat{s}_i\) to the optimization problem is self-sustaining, i.e. \(z\,g(\hat{s}_i)>s_i^*\) with probability one, or equivalently \(\underline{z}\,g(\hat{s}_i)>s_i^*\). This guess will be verified by the result that \(\hat{s}_i\le s_i^*<\underline{s}\). Further, we use that \(S^*_p(z\,g(s))=\max \{z\,g(s),s_p^*\}\). Thus, \(S^*_p(z\,g(s))=z\,g(s)\) for \(z<s_p^*/g(s)\) and \(S^*_p(z\,g(s))=s_p^*\) else. Using these results, and using \(\varphi (z)\) to denote the probability density function of \(z\), we obtain the following Bellman equation

$$\begin{aligned} v_{T-2}(x,i)&= \max \limits _{0\le s\le x}\Bigg \{\pi (x)-\pi (s)+\rho _i\,E_z \bigg [\pi (z\,g(s))+q\,\left( -\pi (s_i^*)+\rho _i\,E_{z'} \left[ \pi (z'\,g(s_i^*))\right] \right) \\&+\,(1-q)\,\int _{\overline{z}}^{{s_p^*}/{g(s)}}\left( -\pi (z\,g(s)) +\rho _i\,E_{z'}\left[ \pi (z'\,g(z\,g(s)))\right] \right) \,\varphi (z)\,dz\bigg ]\\&+\,(1-q)\,\left( \int ^{\overline{z}}_{{s_p^*}/{g(s)}}\varphi (z)\,dz\right) \left( -\pi (s_p^*)+\rho _i\,E_{z'}\left[ \pi (z'\,g(s_p^*))\right] \right) -\rho _i\,\pi (s_T^*) \Bigg \} \end{aligned}$$

The first-order condition for the maximization problem reads

$$\begin{aligned} \pi '(s)&= \rho _i\,E_z\big [z\,\pi '(z\,g(s))\,g'(s)\big ] -(1-q)\\&\int _{\underline{z}}^{\frac{s_p^*}{g(s)}}\left( \pi '(z\,g(s))-\rho _i\,E_{z'}\left[ \pi '(z'\,g(z\,g(s))) \,z'\,\,g'(z\,g(s))\right] \right) \,z\,g'(s)\,\varphi (z)\,dz\nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(16)

This equation is solved by some \(\hat{s}_i\) which is independent of \(x\). Thus, the optimal policy for type \(i\) is a constant escapement policy as well.

Comparing (16) to the first-order condition (5) for the optimal escapement level for type \(i\), we find that the right-hand side of (16) is smaller than the right-hand side of (5), as the second term is negative: The term in brackets is monotone in \(s\) (as \(\pi \) and \(g\) are concave). It is negative both at the lower and upper bound of integration: At the lower bound it is negative because \(\underline{z}\,g(s)>s_i^*\), and

$$\begin{aligned}&\pi '(z\,g(s))-\rho _i\,E_{z'}\left[ \pi '(z'\,g(z\,g(s)))\,z'\,\,g'(z\,g(s))\right] \\&\quad >\pi '(s_i^*)-\rho _i\,E_{z'}\left[ \pi '(z'\,g(s_i^*))\,z'\,\,g'(s_i^*)\right] =0. \end{aligned}$$

At the upper bound it is negative because

$$\begin{aligned} \pi '(s_p^*)-\rho _i\,E_{z'}\left[ \pi '(z'\,g(s_p^*))\,z'\,\,g'(s_p^*)\right] >\pi '(s_p^*)-\rho _p\,E_{z'}\left[ \pi '(z'\,g(s_p^*))\,z'\,\,g'(s_p^*)\right] =0. \end{aligned}$$

This holds provided the upper bound of the integral is larger than the lower bound, i.e. if \(s_p^*>\underline{z}\,g(\hat{s}_i)\). As \(\hat{s}_i\ge s_i^*\), a sufficient condition for this to hold is \(s_p^*>\underline{z}\,g(s_i^*)\).

Proposition 4 follows directly, as the (negative) second term on the right-hand side of condition (16) is decreasing in \(s_p^\star \), which, in turn, is monotonically increasing in \(\rho _p\).

1.2 Proof of Proposition 3

From Proposition 2:

$$\begin{aligned} v(x,1)&=\pi (x)-\pi (g(\hat{s}_i))+\rho _i(q(\pi (g(\hat{s}_i))+(1-q)C_3))\\ \pi '(\hat{s}_i)&=q \;\rho _i g'(\hat{s}_i)\pi '(g(\hat{s}_i))\\ q \; \rho _i&= \frac{\pi '(\hat{s}_i)}{g'(\hat{s}_i)\pi '(g(\hat{s}_i))} \end{aligned}$$

The RHS is increasing in \(s\) (Reed 1979). Thus, if \(q\) increases, \(s\) has to increase, too.

1.3 Proof of Proposition 5

The optimal feedback-control rule \(\bar{s}(x)\) is characterized by the Bellman equation

$$\begin{aligned}&\alpha \,\bar{V}(x)+(1-\alpha )\,\bar{v}(x)\\&\qquad =\max \limits _{s}\left\{ \pi (x)-\pi (s)+E\left[ \alpha \,\rho _p\,\bar{V}(z\,g(x))+(1-\alpha )\,\rho _i\,\bar{v}(z\,g(s))\right] \right\} \nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(17)

We guess the following value functions:

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{V}(x)&=\pi (x)+\bar{C} \end{aligned}$$
(18)
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{v}(x)&=\pi (x)+\bar{c} \end{aligned}$$
(19)

with constants \(\bar{C}\) and \(\bar{c}\). With this guess, the first-order condition for the right-hand side of (17) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \pi '(s)=\left( \alpha \,\rho _p+(1-\alpha )\,\rho _i\right) \,E[\pi (z\,g(s))\,z\,g'(s)] \end{aligned}$$
(20)

This first-order condition is solved by a constant escapement level. This verifies the guess of the value function. Furthermore, the optimal escapement level that solves (20) is the same as the optimal escapement level for a hypothetical decision maker with discount factor \(\alpha \,\rho _p+(1-\alpha )\,\rho _i\), which is a convex mixture of the discount factors of the two groups, and hence in between the two.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hoffmann, J., Quaas, M.F. Common Pool Politics and Inefficient Fishery Management. Environ Resource Econ 63, 79–93 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9842-4

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9842-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation