Skip to main content
Log in

Environmental Standards and Cournot Duopoly: A Stability Analysis

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper the dynamic effects of public environmental policies are investigated in a Cournot duopoly with both heterogeneous and homogeneous expectations in a context of limited rationality. It is shown that the increase in upper limits to emissions always tends to destabilise markets and generate a chaotic market dynamics in both cases. The policy implication of this result is that the use of environmental policies may favour market stability. It is also shown that higher costs of abatement technology entail a higher likelihood of stability loss (although in the heterogeneous expectations case also a decrease in costs may destabilise).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Environmental standards are requirements that set specific limits to the amount of pollutants that can be released into the environment by firms. More details are given in the Appendix.

  2. For a duopoly model with pollution in a static context see, for instance, Bárcena-Ruiz and Garzón (2003, 2006).

  3. Alternatively, we could assume environmental taxes which are also increasingly implemented by public agencies (European Environment Agency 2000). This is left for further research.

  4. Given the dynamic focus of this paper in a context of disequilibrium dynamics and limited information, we abstract from the choice of “optimal” environmental standards by public agency, as is the rule in the static duopoly games literature. Therefore we study the effects of exogenously given (rather than endogenously—optimally—chosen) environmental standards.

  5. Under the assumption of Cournot-naïve expectations, Theocharis (1959) showed for the standard case with linear demand and cost functions in a homogeneous duopoly that the (quantity) adjustment process always converges to the Nash equilibrium. Since then, the case with naïve expectations has been analysed in depth, taking into consideration alternative features of the demand and cost functions, (see, for instance, Puu 1997), revealing complicated dynamics specifically due to the non-linearity introduced in the alternative demand and cost functions.

  6. The existence, stability and uniqueness of the Cournot oligopoly equilibrium under adaptive expectations was studied by Okuguchi (1976).

  7. Note that there exists another equilibrium, in which firm 1 does not produce and thus firm 2 is a monopolist. Since the focus of the paper is on market stability in a strategic duopolistic context in which both firms compete, monopolistic equilibrium is not analysed here.

  8. Note that, as regards the results presented in the rest of the paper, this inequality holds not only at equilibrium but also for every dynamic path (i.e. \(q(t)\ge e(t)\), with \(t\epsilon (0,\propto ))\). I am grateful to the editor Hassan Benchekroun for having pointed out to me the relevance of such a constraint.

  9. However, while the stability loss of the positive equilibrium is exhaustively analysed through the “stability triangle”, the dynamic behaviour in the “large” after the loss of stability may be more complicated and often investigated only by numerical methods: I refer to Bischi et al. (2010) for a thorough analysis of the dynamics of oligopolies. Also, the global dynamics of the present model is numerically investigated in Sect. 3.2.

  10. The proof of Proposition 3 straightforwardly derives from \(\alpha ^{F}-a^{H}=\frac{(2+k)(3+k)(1-4-k^{2}-4k)}{(a+ek)(5+k^{2}+4k)}<0\).

  11. Note that there are three other equilibrium points, where: (1) neither firm produces; (2) only firm 1 produces; (3) only firm 2 produces (see also footnote 7).

  12. Note that the yellow (red) regions are the basin of attraction of the period-4 regular cycle (four-piece ring-shaped chaotic attractor): the basins appear to be disconnected and to have a fractal dimension.

  13. This list strictly follows the taxonomy reported in the Royal Commission on Environmental Pollution (RCEP), (1998).

References

  • Agiza HN, Elsadany AA (2003) Nonlinear dynamics in the Cournot duopoly game with heterogeneous players. Phys A 320:512–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Garzón MB (2003) Strategic environmental standards, wage incomes and the location of polluting firms. Environ Res Econ 24:121–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Garzón MB (2006) Mixed oligopoly and environmental policy. Span Econ Rev 8:139–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (1994) Strategic environmental policy and international trade. J Public Econ 54:325–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bischi GI, Chiarella C, Kopel M, Szidarovszky F (2010) Nonlinear oligopolies: stability and bifurcations. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bluffstone R, Panayotou T (2000) Environmental liability in central and eastern Europe: toward an optimal policy. Environ Res Econ 17:335–352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cournot A (1838) Recherches sur les Principes Mathématiques de la Théorie des Richesses. Hachette, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Den Haan WJ (2001) The importance of the number of different agents in a heterogeneous asset-pricing model. J Econ Dyn Control 25:721–746

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK (1986) Comparative statics for oligopoly. Int Econ Rev 27:107–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Environment Agency (2000) Environmental taxes: recent developments in tools for integration. Environmental Issues Series No 18

  • Fanti L, Gori L (2012) The dynamics of a differentiated duopoly with quantity competition. Econ Model 29(2):421–427

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gandolfo G (2010) Economic Dynamics, 4th edn. Springer, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoel M (1997) Environmental policy with endogenous plant locations. Scand J Econ 99:241–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katsoulakos Y, Xepapadeas A (1996a) Emission taxes and market structure. In: Carraro C, Katsoulakos Y, Xepapadeas A (eds) Environmental policy and market structure. Kluwer, The Netherlands

    Google Scholar 

  • Katsoulakos Y, Xepapadeas A (1996b) Environmental innovation, spillovers and optimal policy rules. In: Carraro C, Katsoulacos Y, Xepapadeas A (eds) Environmental policy and market structure. Kluwer, The Netherlands

    Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy P (1994) Equilibrium pollution taxes in open economies with imperfect competition. J Environ Econ Manag 27:49–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leonard D, Nishimura K (1999) Nonlinear dynamics in the Cournot model without full information. Ann Oper Res 89:165–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen JR (1997) Costly pollution abatement, competitiveness and plant location decisions. Res Energy Econ 19:299–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen JR, Morey ER, Olewiler N (1995) Competition in regional environmental policies when plant locations are endogenous. J Public Econ 56:55–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Medio A (1992) Chaotic dynamics: theory and applications to economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (UK)

    Google Scholar 

  • Okuguchi K (1976) Expectations and stability in oligopoly models. Lecture notes in economics and mathematical systems, vol 138. Berlin, Heidelberg, New York

  • Puu T (1997) Nonlinear economic dynamics. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Royal Commission on Environmental Pollution (RCEP) (1998) Environmental standards and public values. A summary of the twenty-first report of the royal commission on environmental pollution. The Stationery Office, London

  • Theocharis RD (1959) On the stability of the Cournot solution on the oligopoly problem. Rev Econ Stud 27:133–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tramontana F (2010) Heterogeneous duopoly with isoelastic demand function. Econ Model 27:350–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ulph A (1996) Environmental policy and international trade when governments and producers act strategically. J Environ Econ Manag 30:256–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van der Ploeg F, de Zeeuw AJ (1992) International aspects of pollution control. Environ Res Econ 2:117–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J, Da Q, Wang Y (2007) Analysis of nonlinear duopoly game with heterogeneous players. Econ Model 24:138–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luciano Fanti.

Appendix

Appendix

Although in the paper’s models the environmental standard in question has been represented, as usual, in a stylised way through an allowed level of polluting production, environmental standards may take different forms. They include not only numerical and legally enforceable limits, but standards which may be: (1) not only mandatory but contained in guidelines, codes of practice or sets of criteria for deciding individual cases; (2) not only set by governments but also by entities endowed with a certain degree of authority, such as scientific committees or firms with large market power.

The following is a brief list of the various forms of environmental standards (with corresponding examples):Footnote 13 (1) biological standards: e.g. European Community (EC) reference level for the concentration of lead in blood; (2) exposure standards: e.g. EC dose limits for external radiation; tolerable daily intake of a substance from all routes determined under the International Programme on Chemical Safety; (3) quality standards: e.g. World Health Organization guideline values for air quality; EC quality standards for bathing waters; EC guidelines for heavy metals in agricultural soils; (4) emission standards: e.g. Protocols under the Convention on Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution of the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe; EC limit values for emissions for road vehicles; (5) product standards, e.g. EC standards for motor fuels; EC limit and guide values for drinking water quality; (6) process standards, e.g. Guidance Notes issued by the Environment Agency for processes subject to Integrated Pollution Control and by the Secretary of State for processes which are regulated by local authorities for emissions to air; (7) life cycle-based standards, e.g. EC ecolabelling scheme; (8) use standards: e.g. bans and restrictions under the EC Marketing and Use Directive; EC and UK procedures for authorising plant protection, industrial chemicals, biocidal and veterinary medicinal products; (9) management standards: e.g. International Organization for Standardization standard ISO 14001 for environmental management systems.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fanti, L. Environmental Standards and Cournot Duopoly: A Stability Analysis. Environ Resource Econ 61, 577–593 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9807-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9807-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation