Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How Disagreement About Social Costs Leads to Inefficient Energy-Productivity Investment

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Public energy-productivity investment influences the amount of future energy consumption. If a present government expects its successor to value the social costs of fuel usage differently, this adds a strategic component to its investment considerations. We analyze this governmental time-inconsistency situation as a sequential game. In particular, we show how the expectation of a more conservative party taking over makes a “green” government choose an investment level that is inefficient, in that neither of the parties would prefer it to the investment level of a permanent green government. Under some circumstances, the opposition would even prefer the government definitely to stay in power: The gain from avoiding a strategic investment then outweighs the loss of not being able to regulate energy consumption. We also analyze the welfare gains from binding agreements.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In this article, “energy productivity” describes the technical rate with which physical energy sources translate into economically useful energy or “energy services” providing utility—for example, higher energy productivity means that a given amount of fuel or electricity produces more hours of a warm living room. The literature uses the terms “energy efficiency”, “engineering efficiency” (Brookes 2000), “technical” or “thermal efficiency” (Sorrell and Dimitropoulos 2008). We use “productivity” instead of “efficiency” to avoid confusion, as we classify the level of investment as either efficient or inefficient.

  2. Both reactions are possible, depending on the demand elasticities—see Saunders (2000) and other texts mentioned below on “rebound effects”.

  3. In this article, the terms “conservative” and “green” are used to describe environmental-policy preferences only. While this should not be controversial regarding the Greens, a reviewer pointed out that the term “conservative” may be associated with income differences. Here, “conservative” is used to describe the Greens’ counterpart, due to the political constellation in many countries, but in this sense, “left-wing” parties can also be conservative. No ethical appraisal of the positions or of the factual correctness is implied.

  4. The IEA justifies many measures by mentioning alleged or actual market failures.

  5. The analysis can be understood as referring to one sector or to a whole economy.

  6. The \(\tau ,\,F,\,E\) concepts are borrowed from the energy efficiency literature; the variables follow Saunders (2008), who calls \(\tau \) an “engineering efficiency parameter”. The way productivity augments the energy services derived from a given amount of fuel use reflects the way energy productivity is commonly understood: For example, with better insulation, a certain amount of heating oil will produce a warm living-room for a longer time.

  7. We assume positive and diminishing marginal benefits of energy services \((B'(E)>0,\,B''(E)<0)\) and the usual requirements (following Inada 1963) to ensure an interior solution \((\lim \limits _{E\rightarrow 0}{B'(E)} = \infty ,\,\lim \limits _{E\rightarrow \infty }{B'(E)} = 0)\). Marginal costs of fuel consumption and marginal costs of investment are globally non-negative and finite for finite values of \(F\), and the functions are convex (\(\infty > Z\ge 0\) for \(\infty > F \ge 0,\,Z> 0\) for \(F > 0,\,Z'(F) \ge 0,\,Z''(F) \ge 0\) and \(\infty > T \ge 0\) for \(\infty > \tau \ge 0,\,T > 0\) for \(\tau > 0,\,T'(\tau ) \ge 0,\,T''(\tau ) \ge 0\)).

  8. The strict sequence between investment and fuel usage is due to the two-period structure of the model. As pointed out by a reviewer, the choices would often take place simultaneously in real life. However, investment has a lasting effect, so that fuel-consumption may be changed, whereas the investment decision cannot be reversed.

  9. The signs of \(\beta \) and \(\theta \) are implied by our assumptions of positive and diminishing marginal benefits of energy services and a convex cost function, respectively.

  10. In this model, the government directly chooses fuel consumption. In reality, governments would indirectly choose it by setting a cap on emissions or raising a Pigou tax.

  11. The cost function’s convexity implies \(\varphi \ge 0\). For \(\beta >0\), see (3.5).

  12. For a further discussion of consumption reactions on productivity changes in a consumer-demand context, see Wirl (1997). Saunders (2000, 2008) defines the “rebound” of an economy as \(R \equiv 1 + \eta \). A rebound of \(R\) means that \((1-R) \cdot 100\,\%\) of technological productivity gains are translated into actual fuel conservation. Saunders (2008) distinguishes between five cases: \(R>1\) is “backfire”, \(R=1\) is “full rebound”, \(0<R<1\) is “partial rebound”, \(R=0\) is “zero rebound” and \(R<0\) is “super-conservation”. In our setting, the rebound is given by

    $$\begin{aligned} R&= 1 + \frac{ 1 - \beta }{ \beta + \varphi } = \frac{ 1 + \varphi }{ \beta + \varphi } \end{aligned}$$

    and it must be positive; so “zero rebound” and “super-conservation” cannot occur. Also note that \(R\) is the elasticity of energy services with respect to productivity, so in our setting, higher productivity always translates into more energy services being used.

  13. All example figures are generated for constant-\(\beta \) benefit functions, constant-\(\theta \) investment cost functions and constant-\(\varphi \) fuel consumption cost functions, which makes \(\omega ,\,\eta \) and \(\xi \) constant as well: \(B(E) = b \cdot E^{1-\beta }/(1-\beta ),\,T(\tau ) = k \cdot \tau ^{1+\theta }/(1+\theta )\), and \(K^i(F) = \kappa _i \cdot F^{1+\varphi }/(1+\varphi )\).

  14. Even if we had not assumed monotonic functions above, the slopes of the two curves would have to be both positive or both negative at their intersection point, because the sign of \(1 - \beta \) determines the signs of both slopes.

  15. As explained in Sect. 3.2, both parties would find \(\tau ^*(F)\) optimal, given any fuel consumption level \(F\). Therefore, the allocations on \(\tau ^*(F)\) are Pareto-optimal (so \(\tau ^*(F)\) is the parties’ contract curve), which is used in Sect. 4.4 for the cooperative solution.

  16. Also, our results depend on the assumption that the elasticity of fuel usage with respect to productivity is approximately constant. See footnote 17.

  17. If it is not, little can be said about optimality. Our model constitutes a second-best problem for the first-period government, which requires some assumptions about cost and benefit functions (cf. Lipsey and Lancaster 1956–1957).

References

  • Abrego L, Perroni C (2002) Investment subsidies and time-consistent environmental policy. Oxf Econ Pap 54(4):617–635

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt TS (1998) Political internalization of economic externalities and environmental policy. J Public Econ 69(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alcott B (2005) Jevons’ paradox. Ecol Econ 54(1):9–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Tabellini G (1990) A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt. Rev Econ Stud 57(3):403–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt US (2004) Unilateral actions, the case of international environmental problems. Resour Energy Econ 26(4):373–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brookes L (2000) Energy efficiency fallacies revisited. Energy Policy 28(6–7):355–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunner S, Flachsland C, Marschinski R (2012) Credible commitment in carbon policy. Climate Policy 12(2):255–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A (2000) Political economy in macroeconomics. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Frondel M, Lohmann S (2011) The European Commission’s light bulb decree: another costly regulation? Energy Policy 39(6):3177–3181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greening LA, Greene DL, Difiglio C (2000) Energy efficiency and consumption–the rebound effect–a survey. Energy Policy 28(6–7):389–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helm D, Hepburn C, Mash R (2003) Credible carbon policy. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 19(3):438–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herring H (1999) Does energy efficiency save energy? The debate and its consequences. Appl Energy 63(3):209–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IEA (2011) 25 energy efficiency policy recommendations: 2011 update. International Energy Agency

  • Inada K-I (1963) On a two-sector model of economic growth: comments and a generalization. Rev Econ Stud 30(2):119–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner G, Schneider F (2003) On the political economy of environmental policy. Public Choice 115(3–4):369–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey RG, Lancaster K (1956–1957) The general theory of second best. Rev Econ Stud 24(1):11–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List JA, Sturm DM (2006) How elections matter: theory and evidence from environmental policy. Q J Econ 121(4):1249–1281

    Google Scholar 

  • Marsiliani L, Renström TI (2000) Time inconsistency in environmental policy: tax earmarking as a commitment solution. Econ J (Conference Papers) 110(462):C123–C138

    Google Scholar 

  • McKibbin WJ, Wilcoxen PJ (2002) The role of economics in climate change policy. J Econ Perspect 16(2):107–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE, Portney PR (2003) The political economy of environmental policy. In: Mäler K-G, Vincent JR (eds) Handbook of environmental economics, vol 1, 1st edn, chap 8. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 325–354

  • Persson T, Tabellini G (2000) Political economics–explaining economic policy. Zeuthen lecture book series. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Svensson LEO (1989) Why a stubborn conservative would run a deficit: policy with time-inconsistent preferences. Q J Econ 104(2):325–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Portney PR, Parry IWH, Gruenspecht HK, Harrington W (2003) The economics of fuel economy standards. J Econ Perspect 17(4):203–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saunders HD (1992) The Khazzoom–Brookes postulate and neoclassical growth. Energy J 13(4):131–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saunders HD (2000) A view from the macro side: rebound, backfire, and Khazzoom–Brookes. Energy Policy 28(6–7):439–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saunders HD (2008) Fuel conserving (and using) production functions. Energy Econ 30(5):2184–2235

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sorrell S, Dimitropoulos J (2008) The rebound effect: microeconomic definitions, limitations and extensions. Ecol Econ 65(3):636–649

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini G, Alesina A (1990) Voting on the budget deficit. Am Econ Rev 80(1):37–49

    Google Scholar 

  • Wirl F (1997) The economics of conservation programs. Kluwer, Boston

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Achim Voß.

Additional information

This article was written at the University of Münster as part of the author’s PhD thesis. Thanks to Alfred Endres, Kai Flinkerbusch, Aloys Prinz, Kerstin Roeder, Daniel Schultz, Wolfgang Ströbele, participants of the 19th EAERE Conference, of the 68th IIPF Congress, and of the 14th INFER Conference, and two referees of this journal for helpful comments and suggestions. Thanks to Brian Bloch for editing and proofreading the manuscript. Special thanks to Jörg Lingens.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Second-Order Condition for Optimal Investment in the Reelection Case

To ensure that we have a maximum at \(\tau _x^*, F_x^*\), it is necessary that the following condition holds at this point:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_x(\tau ), \tau ) }{ \partial \tau ^2 }&= - \frac{\partial ^2 T}{\partial \tau ^2} + \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial E_{x}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 \nonumber \\&\quad + \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 E_{x}}{\partial \tau ^2} - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial Z}{\partial F} \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 F_{x}}{\partial \tau ^2} < 0 . \end{aligned}$$
(6.1)

Substituting \(\partial ^2 E_x / \partial \tau ^2 = 2 \cdot \partial F_x / \partial \tau + \tau \cdot \partial ^2 F_x / \partial \tau ^2\) and the optimal fuel use condition (3.6) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_x(\tau ), \tau )}{\partial \tau ^2}&= - \frac{\partial ^2 T}{\partial \tau ^2} + \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial E_{x}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 \nonumber \\&\quad - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 + 2 \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } . \end{aligned}$$
(6.2)

In an energy-saving situation, \(\partial F_x/\partial \tau \) is negative, so that all summands are negative; then the second-order condition is always fulfilled. Thus, we have to determine under which circumstances the second-order condition is fulfilled in a backfire situation. Factoring out \(\partial B / \partial E\) and \(F_x/\tau \) and substituting the first-order conditions (3.6) (for \(\lambda = x\)) and (4.3), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_x^*, \tau _x^*)}{\partial \tau ^2}&= \frac{F_x^*}{\tau _{x}^{*}} \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \nonumber \\&\quad \cdot \Biggl [ - \theta - \beta \cdot \left( \frac{\partial E_{x}}{\partial \tau } \cdot \frac{1}{F_{x}^{*}} \right) ^2 - \varphi \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_{x}/F_{x}^{*}}{\partial \tau /\tau _{x}^{*}} \right) ^2 + 2 \cdot \frac{\partial F_{x} / F_{x}^{*}}{\partial \tau / \tau _{x}^{*}} \Biggr ] . \end{aligned}$$

Noting that \((\partial E_{x}/\partial \tau ) \cdot 1/F_{x} = 1 + \eta _{x}\), we can substitute the elasticities and simplify:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_{x}^{*}, \tau _{x}^{*})}{\partial \tau ^2}&= \frac{F_x^*}{\tau _{x}^{*}} \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \left( 1 - \beta \right) \cdot \left( {\eta _{x}} - \frac{1}{\omega } \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(6.3)

Thus, in a backfire situation (where \(1-\beta > 0\)), the second-order condition is fulfilled if \(\eta _{x} < 1/\omega \), which means that an \(F, \tau \) combination can be a utility maximum if for these values the \(F_x(\tau )\) function is less steep than the inverse of the \(\tau ^*(F)\) function. In an energy-saving case (where \(1 - \beta < 0\)), \(\eta _{x} > 1/\omega \) is implied, so that the \(F_x(\tau )\) function is steeper than the \(\tau ^*(F)\) function. Substituting \(\eta _x\) and \(\omega \) in (6.3), we see that the general requirement for the inequality to be fulfilled is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ 1 - 2 \cdot \beta - \theta \cdot \varphi - \theta \cdot \beta - \varphi \cdot \beta }{\beta + \varphi }&< 0 \end{aligned}$$

at the optimum. After further rearrangements, we can state this condition as

$$\begin{aligned} 1 - \beta < \frac{(1 + \varphi ) \cdot (1 + \theta )}{ (1 + \varphi ) + (1 + \theta ) }. \end{aligned}$$
(6.4)

In (3.10), we assumed \(\varphi \ge 1, \theta \ge 1\); as \(\beta > 0\), this is sufficient for (6.4) to be fulfilled and then, any extremum of the utility function is a maximum.

1.2 The Impact of Fuel Usage Cost Valuation on Investment in the Reelection Case

We differentiate (4.2) with respect to \(\kappa _x\) and \(\tau \). This yields:

$$\begin{aligned} 0&= \left( \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \tau - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial Z}{\partial F} \right) \cdot d\left( \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } \right) \nonumber \\&\quad + \Biggl \{ \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \left[ {F_x}^2 + 2 \cdot E_x \cdot \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } + \tau ^2 \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_x}{ \partial \tau } \right) ^2 \right] \nonumber \\&\quad - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 + 2 \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \frac{\partial F_x}{ \partial \tau } - \frac{\partial ^2 T}{\partial \tau ^2} \Biggr \} \cdot d \tau \nonumber \\&\quad + \Biggl [ \left( \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} + \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot E_x \right) \cdot \frac{\partial F_x}{ \partial \kappa _x } - \frac{\partial Z}{\partial F} \cdot \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } \nonumber \\&\quad + \left( \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \tau ^2 - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \right) \cdot \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } \cdot \frac{\partial F_x}{ \partial \kappa _x } \Biggr ] \cdot d \kappa _x . \end{aligned}$$
(6.5)

The first line of the right-hand side equals zero, because of the period-2 government’s optimality condition. The square-bracketed term in the second line can be replaced as

$$\begin{aligned} {F_x}^2 + 2 \cdot E_x \cdot \frac{\partial F_x}{\partial \tau } + \tau ^2 \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2&= \left( \frac{\partial E_{x}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 . \end{aligned}$$
(6.6)

Doing so and rearranging yields:

$$\begin{aligned} 0&= \Biggl [ - \frac{\partial ^2 T}{\partial \tau ^2} + \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial E_x}{ \partial \tau } \right) ^2 - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 + 2 \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \frac{\partial F_x}{ \partial \tau } \Biggr ] \cdot \frac{ d \tau }{ d \kappa _x } \nonumber \\&\quad + \Biggl [ \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \left( 1 - \beta \right) \cdot \frac{\partial F_x}{ \partial \kappa _x } - \frac{\partial Z}{\partial F} \cdot \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } \nonumber \\&\quad + \left( \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \tau ^2 - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \right) \cdot \frac{\partial F_x}{ \partial \kappa _x } \cdot \frac{\partial F_{x}}{\partial \tau } \Biggr ] . \end{aligned}$$
(6.7)

The square-bracketed term in the first line is equivalent to \(\partial ^2 W^x/\partial \tau ^2\), as given in (6.2). We can also substitute the elasticities, factor out \(\partial B/\partial E\) and \(F_x/\kappa _x\), substitute the optimality condition (3.6) and rearrange to obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial \tau _x^{*} }{ \partial \kappa _x }&= \Biggl [ \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(\kappa _x, \tau )}{\tau ^2} \Biggr ]^{-1} \cdot \frac{F_x^{*}}{\kappa _{x}} \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \eta _{x} . \end{aligned}$$
(6.8)

Now substitute \(\partial ^2 W^x/\partial \tau ^2\) from (6.3):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial \tau _x^{*} }{ \partial \kappa _x }&= \Biggl [ \frac{F_{x}^*}{\tau _{x}^*} \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \left( 1 - \beta \right) \cdot \left( {\eta _{x}} - \frac{1}{\omega } \right) \Biggr ]^{-1} \cdot \frac{F_{x}^*}{\kappa _{x}} \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \eta _{x}. \end{aligned}$$
(6.9)

Simplifying finally yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \psi _{x} \equiv \frac{ \partial \tau _x^{*}/\tau _x^{*} }{ \partial \kappa _x/\kappa _x }&= - \xi _{x} \cdot \Biggl ( {\eta _{x}} - \frac{1}{\omega } \Biggr )^{-1}. \end{aligned}$$

1.3 Second-Order Condition for Optimal Investment in the Voting-Out Case

To ensure a Party-\(x\) utility maximum for \(\tau _x^\#, F_y^\#\), it is necessary that the following condition holds at this point:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_{y}(\tau ), \tau )}{\partial \tau ^2}&= - \frac{\partial ^2 T}{\partial \tau ^2} + \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial E_{y}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_{y}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 \nonumber \\&\quad + \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 E_{y}}{\partial \tau ^2} - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial Z}{\partial F} \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 F_{y}}{\partial \tau ^2} <0 . \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(\partial ^2 E_{y} / \partial \tau ^2 = 2 \cdot \partial F_{y} / \partial \tau + \tau \cdot \partial ^2 F_{y} / \partial \tau ^2\) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_{y}(\tau ), \tau )}{\partial \tau ^2}&= - \frac{\partial ^2 T}{\partial \tau ^2} + \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial E_{y}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 - \kappa _{x} \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_{y}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 \nonumber \\&\quad + 2 \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \frac{\partial F_{y}}{\partial \tau } \nonumber \\&\quad + \left( \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \tau - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial Z}{\partial F} \right) \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 F_{y}}{\partial \tau ^2} . \end{aligned}$$
(6.10)

Substituting the first-order conditions (3.6) (for \(\lambda = y\)) and (4.9), and factoring out \(\partial B/\partial E\) and \(F_y/\tau \), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_{y}(\tau _{x}^{\#}), \tau _{x}^{\#})}{\partial \tau ^2}&= \frac{F_{y}^{\#} }{ \tau _{x}^{\#} } \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \Biggl \{ - \theta \cdot \left[ 1 + \left( 1 - \frac{\kappa _x}{\kappa _y} \right) \cdot \eta _y \right] \nonumber \\&\quad - \beta \cdot \left( \frac{\partial E_{y}}{\partial \tau } \cdot \frac{ 1 }{F_{y}^{\#}} \right) ^2 - \frac{\kappa _{x}}{\kappa _{y}} \cdot \varphi \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_{y}/F_{y}^{\#}}{\partial \tau /\tau _{x}^{\#}} \right) ^2 \nonumber \\&\quad + 2 \cdot \frac{\partial F_{y}/F_{y}^{\#}}{\partial \tau /\tau _{x}^{\#}} + \tau _{x}^{\#} \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{ \kappa _x }{\kappa _y} \right) \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 F_{y}}{\partial \tau ^2} \cdot \frac{ \tau _{x}^{\#} }{F_{y}} \Biggr \}. \end{aligned}$$
(6.11)

For the second derivative of the period-2 government’s fuel consumption choice with respect to energy productivity, rearranging and differentiating (3.9) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 F_{y}}{\partial \tau ^2}&= \frac{F_{y}}{\tau } \cdot \left[ \frac{\partial \eta _{y}}{\partial \tau } + \frac{1}{\tau } \cdot \eta _{y} \cdot \left( \eta _{y} - 1 \right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(6.12)

Substituting (6.12) and \((\partial E_{y}/\partial \tau ) \cdot 1/F_{y} = 1 + \eta _{y}\) into (6.11) and simplifying yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_{y}(\tau _{x}^{\#}), \tau _{x}^{\#})}{\partial \tau ^2}&= \frac{F_{y}^{\#}}{ \tau _{x}^{\#} } \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \left( 1 - \beta \right) \cdot \Biggl \{ \eta _{y} - \frac{1}{\omega } \nonumber \\&\quad + \frac{1}{\beta + \varphi } \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{ \kappa _x }{\kappa _y} \right) \cdot \left[ \eta _{y} \cdot \left( 1 + \varphi \right) - 1 - \theta \right] \nonumber \\&\quad + \frac{1}{\beta + \varphi } \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{ \kappa _x }{\kappa _y} \right) \cdot \left( \frac{\partial \eta _{y}/\eta _{y}}{\partial \tau /\tau _{x}^{\#}} \right) \Biggr \} . \end{aligned}$$

With some rearrangements, we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_{y}(\tau _{x}^{\#}), \tau _{x}^{\#})}{\partial \tau ^2}&= \frac{F_{y}^{\#}}{ \tau _{x}^{\#} } \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \left( 1 - \beta \right) \cdot \Biggl \{ \left( \eta _{y} - \frac{1}{\omega } \right) \cdot \left[ 1 + \eta _{y} \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{ \kappa _x }{\kappa _y} \right) \right] \nonumber \\&\quad + \frac{1}{\beta + \varphi } \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{ \kappa _x }{\kappa _y} \right) \cdot \left( \frac{\partial \eta _{y}/\eta _{y}}{\partial \tau /\tau _{x}^{\#}} \right) \Biggr \}. \end{aligned}$$
(6.13)

We assume that the elasticity of \(\eta _y\) with respect to \(\tau \) is negligible.Footnote 17 Then, determining under which conditions this second derivative is smaller than zero is equivalent to finding out whether the following inequality holds:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1 - \beta \right) \cdot \left( \eta _{y} - \frac{1}{\omega } \right) \cdot \left[ 1 + \eta _{y} \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{ \kappa _x }{\kappa _y} \right) \right]&< 0 . \end{aligned}$$
(6.14)

From Sect. 6.1, we know that the product of the first two multiplicands is negative, so we now have to analyze whether the third multiplicand is positive. Note that \(1 - \kappa _x/\kappa _y\) is bounded between \(-\infty \) (for \(\kappa _x \rightarrow \infty \) and \(\kappa _y \rightarrow 0\)) and 1 (for \(\kappa _x \rightarrow 0\) and \(\kappa _y \rightarrow \infty \)) and that \(1 > \eta _{y} > 0\) in the backfire case and \(0 > \eta _{y}> -1\) in the energy-saving case, given our assumptions in Sect. 3.4.

First consider the energy-saving case in which \(\eta _y < 0\). Then for \(\kappa _x > \kappa _y\), no term in the square brackets is negative. For \(\kappa _x < \kappa _y\), the square-bracketed term must be larger than \(1 + (-1) \cdot 1 = 0\), so the energy-saving case is never a problem.

Now consider the backfire case with \(\eta _{y} > 0\). For \(\kappa _x < \kappa _y,\,1 - \kappa _x/\kappa _y\) is positive, so the whole term is again positive. However, for \(\kappa _x > \kappa _y\), the square-bracketed term can take negative values. The condition for this not to happen is:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\kappa _y}{\kappa _x} > \frac{1 - \beta }{1 + \varphi }. \end{aligned}$$

To sum up, the second-order condition is always fulfilled with energy-saving benefit functions. For a backfire case, the second-order condition is fulfilled if the investing government is more conservative than its successor \((\kappa _x < \kappa _y)\), or if the future government will not raise fuel consumption too much in optimum.

1.4 The Impact of the Period-2 Government’s Fuel-Usage Cost Valuation on Investment

To analyze how a change in the period-2 government’s valuation parameter \(\kappa _{y}\) changes the Party-\(x\) government’s investment, we proceed along the lines of Sect. 6.2, but now it is not the period-1 government’s own cost valuation parameter that varies, but its successor’s. First, we differentiate the strategic first-order condition (4.8) with respect to \(\tau \) and \(\kappa _{y}\). Rearranging yields:

$$\begin{aligned} 0&= \Biggl [ - \frac{\partial ^2 T}{\partial \tau ^2} + \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial E_{y}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 - \kappa _{x} \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \cdot \left( \frac{\partial F_{y}}{\partial \tau } \right) ^2 \nonumber \\&\quad + 2 \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \frac{\partial F_{y}}{\partial \tau } + \left( \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \tau - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial Z}{\partial F} \right) \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 F_{y}}{\partial \tau ^2} \Biggr ] \cdot \frac{ d \tau }{ d \kappa _y} \nonumber \\&\quad + \Biggl [ \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \left( 1 - \beta \right) \cdot \frac{\partial F_{y}}{ \partial \kappa _{y} } + \left( \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \tau ^2 - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \right) \cdot \frac{\partial F_{y}}{\partial \tau } \cdot \frac{\partial F_{y}}{ \partial \kappa _{y} } \nonumber \\&\quad + \left( \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \tau - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial Z}{\partial F} \right) \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 F_{y}}{\partial \tau \partial \kappa _{y}} \Biggr ] . \end{aligned}$$
(6.15)

The square-bracketed term in the first two lines is equivalent to \(\partial ^2 W^x(F_{y}(\tau ), \tau )/\partial \tau ^2\), as given in (6.10). From the definitions of \(\xi _{\lambda }\) and \(\eta _{\lambda }\) in (3.8) and (3.9), we can derive the following equivalence for \(\partial ^2 F_{y}/\partial \tau \partial \kappa _y\):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 F_{y}}{\partial \tau \partial \kappa _{y} }&= \eta _{\lambda } \cdot \frac{F_{y}}{\tau \cdot \kappa _{y} } \cdot \left( \frac{ \partial \eta _{y}/\eta _{y} }{\partial \kappa _{y}/\kappa _{y}} + \xi _{y} \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(6.16)

Substituting both findings and rearranging yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ d \tau }{d \kappa _{y}}&= - \Biggl [ \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_{y}(\tau ), \tau )}{\partial \tau ^2} \Biggr ]^{-1} \nonumber \\&\quad \cdot \Biggl [ \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \left( 1 - \beta \right) \cdot \frac{\partial F_{y}}{\partial \kappa _{y}} + \left( \frac{\partial ^2 B}{\partial E^2} \cdot \tau ^2 - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial ^2 Z}{\partial F^2} \right) \cdot \frac{\partial F_{y} }{\partial \tau } \cdot \frac{\partial F_{y}}{\partial \kappa _{y}} \nonumber \\&\quad + \left( \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \tau - \kappa _x \cdot \frac{\partial Z}{\partial F} \right) \cdot \eta _{\lambda } \cdot \frac{F_{y}}{\tau \cdot \kappa _{y} } \cdot \left( \frac{ \partial \eta _{y}/\eta _{y} }{\partial \kappa _{y}/\kappa _{y}} + \xi _{y} \right) \Biggr ]. \end{aligned}$$
(6.17)

We factor out \(\partial B(E_{y})/\partial E\) and \(F_{y}/\kappa _{y}\) and substitute the period-2 government’s optimality condition, (3.6) for \(\lambda = y\):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial \tau _x^{\#}}{\partial \kappa _{y}}&= - \Biggl [ \frac{\partial ^2 W^x(F_{y}(\tau ), \tau )}{\partial \tau ^2} \Biggr ]^{-1} \cdot \Biggl [ \varphi \cdot \xi _{y} + \left( \frac{ \partial \eta _{y}/\eta _{y} }{\partial \kappa _{y}/\kappa _{y}} + \xi _{y} \right) \Biggr ] \nonumber \\&\quad \cdot \frac{F_{y}}{\kappa _{y}} \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \eta _{y} \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{\kappa _{x}}{\kappa _{y}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Now substitute \(\partial ^2 W^x(F_{y}(\tau ), \tau )/\partial \tau ^2\) from (6.13), and assume that the elasticity of \(\eta _y\) with respect to \(\kappa _y\) (and, as we assumed before, with respect to \(\tau \)—see footnote 17) is neglectable:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial \tau _x^{\#}}{\partial \kappa _{y}}&= - \Biggl \{ \frac{F_{y}}{ \tau _{x}^{\#} } \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \left( 1 - \beta \right) \cdot \left( \eta _{y} - \frac{1}{\omega } \right) \cdot \left[ 1 + \eta _{y} \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{ \kappa _x }{\kappa _y} \right) \right] \Biggr \}^{-1} \nonumber \\&\quad \cdot \left[ \varphi \cdot \xi _{y} + \xi _{y} \right] \cdot \frac{\partial B}{\partial E} \cdot \frac{F_{y}}{\kappa _{y}} \cdot \eta _{y} \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{\kappa _{x}}{\kappa _{y}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(6.18)

Simplifying yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \mu \equiv \frac{ \partial \tau _x^{\#} / \tau _x^{\#}}{\partial \kappa _{y} / \kappa _{y} }&= \left( \xi _{y} \right) ^2 \cdot \left( \eta _{y} - \frac{1}{\omega } \right) ^{-1} \cdot \left( 1 + \varphi \right) \nonumber \\&\quad \cdot \left[ 1 + \eta _{y} \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{ \kappa _x }{\kappa _y} \right) \right] ^{-1} \cdot \left( 1 - \frac{\kappa _{x}}{\kappa _{y}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Voß, A. How Disagreement About Social Costs Leads to Inefficient Energy-Productivity Investment. Environ Resource Econ 60, 521–548 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9778-8

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9778-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation