Skip to main content
Log in

Tullock on the organization of scientific inquiry

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In (Tullock, The organization of inquiry, Duke University Press, Durham, NC, 1966), Gordon Tullock sets out to establish how knowledge is developed and dispersed in science, to such a high degree of reliability, despite the lack of formal organizational structure. He contrasts this against the unreliability of the “non-sciences”. In this essay, I review his perspective and consider the validity of his proposed reforms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For recent insights from insiders, see Caldwell (2008) and Levy and Peart (2012) who confront some of the issues discussed in the present essay but generally focus on other aspects of intellectual thought related to Organization.

  2. On the other hand, perhaps not. Gordon once stopped me outside of another scholar’s office and told me not to go in because “it would just make the both of you dumber”.

  3. “Sociology, oddly enough, involves a lot of repetitive research without real repetition. The conundrum results from the fact that sociologists apparently do not have very original minds and tend to partially copy each other’s research. They almost never, however, copy the previous research completely, with the consequence that their work never constitutes a real repetition”. (p. 122).

  4. While working on my dissertation, I expressed concern to an economic history professor over the quality of the historical data I was reconstructing. I was then informed by him that “all data are crap; its just that economic historians know their data are crap”.

  5. Even more disheartening, this is about double the rates they report for the fields of management and marketing.

  6. Somewhat surprisingly, McCullough (2009) notes that the recently created “open-access” journals typically do not have policies requiring archiving data and code on their websites.

  7. Sandler (2015) discusses extensions to Olson which include heterogeneous contributions.

  8. As explained below, Tullock himself falls prey to a similar error.

  9. Tullock added an opening footnote, the likes of which I have never seen before or since, to the published paper stating: “The editor of the journal has accepted and published this article because he feels it is important to get research started in the area. The weaknesses of Laband’s approach, which are fully recognized by Laband, are obvious, but the editor at the moment can think of no way of doing better. Can the readers do better than both Laband and the editor?” In fact, this statement remains the only publicly-viewable part of the paper on the journal website.

  10. In an advice piece for reviewers, Choi (1998/2002) suggested to be timely, but not too timely, because a reputation for timeliness will impose upon the reviewer the private cost of receiving additional requests to review.

References

  • Breit, W. (1987). Creating the ‘Virginia School’: Charlottesville as an academic environment in the 1960s. Economic Inquiry, 25, 645–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1987). The qualities of a natural economist. In C. Rowley (Ed.), Democracy and public choice: Essays in honor of Gordon Tullock (pp. 9–19). Oxford: Basil Blackwell Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, B. (2008). Gordon Tullock’s the organization of inquiry: A critical appraisal. Public Choice, 135, 23–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, J., & Lai, C.-C. (2001). Is it worthwhile to pay referees? Southern Economic Journal, 68, 457–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, K. (1998/2002). How to publish in top journals. http://www.bus.lsu.edu/hill/writing/choi.

  • Coase, R. H. (1981). How should economists choose? In The G. Warren Nutter lectures in political economy. American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research. (Reprinted in: Essays on economics and economists, edited by R. H. Coase, 1994, Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.)

  • Feigenbaum, S., & Levy, D. M. (1993). The market for (ir)reproducible econometrics. Social Epistomology, 7, 215–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferson, W. E., Sarkissian, S., & Simin, T. T. (2003). Spurious regressions in financial economics? Journal of Finance, 58, 1393–1414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L., & Katz, E. (1984). Risk-averse rent seekers and the social cost of monopoly power. Economic Journal, 94, 104–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh, D. S. (1994). Facts and myths about refereeing. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, 153–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hubbard, R., & Vetter, D. E. (1996). An empirical comparison of published replication research in accounting, economics, finance, management, and marketing. Journal of Business Research, 35, 153–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64, 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laband, D. N., & Sophocleus, J. P. (1988). The social cost of rent-seeking: First estimates. Public Choice, 58, 269–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, D. M., & Peart, S. J. (2012). Tullock on motivated inquiry: Expert-induced uncertainty disguised as risk. Public Choice, 152, 163–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, T. (1980). Economics as a hard science: Realistic goal or wishful thinking? Economic Inquiry, 18, 165–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCullough, B. D. (2009). Open access economics journals and the market for reproducible economic research. Economic Analysis and Policy, 39, 117–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1983a). Tests of a rational theory of the size of government. Public Choice, 41, 403–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1983b). Rejoinder to Gordon Tullock. Public Choice, 41, 423–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1983). Towards a mature social science. International Studies Quarterly, 27, 29–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1962). Economists and the history of ideas. American Economic Review, 52, 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (2015). Collective action: Fifty years later. Public Choice, 164, 195–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (2003). The origin rent-seeking concept. International Journal of Business and Economics, 2, 1–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1993). Are scientists different? Journal of Economic Studies, 20, 90–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1991). Casual reflections of an editor. Public Choice, 71, 129–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1988). Rent-seeking and tax reform. Contemporary Policy Issues, 6, 37–47. (Reprinted in Readings in public choice economics, pp. 40–52, by Jac C. Heckelman, Ed., 2004, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.)

  • Tullock, G. (1983). Further tests of a rational theory of the size of government. Public Choice, 41, 419–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5, 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1966). The organization of inquiry. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1965). The politics of bureaucracy. Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jac C. Heckelman.

Additional information

I thank Roger Congleton for suggesting this topic to me and Dan Hammond for his comments on the first draft of this paper.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Heckelman, J.C. Tullock on the organization of scientific inquiry. Const Polit Econ 28, 1–17 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-016-9209-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-016-9209-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation