1 Introduction

One important ingredient for achieving stabilization targets of 450 ppm or lower, which has moved to the centre of the debate over the past decade, is the option of deploying Negative Emission Technologies (NETs) also known as Carbon Dioxide Removal (CDR) options (Obersteiner et al. 2001). Azar et al. (2010), for example, test three different large-scale energy models and find a significant proportion of biomass-based energy with carbon capture and storage (BECCS) as part of an energy mix optimized to stabilize at 350 ppm. While this is a promising avenue for future mitigation strategy, the question arises what the interaction between NETs and other elements of the mitigation portfolio is.

The importance of accounting for natural sinks when determining the optimal policy mix to avoid temperature increases beyond 2°C has been widely discussed, e.g. in the context of Reduced Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation (REDD). However, different models project rather different trajectories for global sinks, as can be observed through the discrepancies between estimates in the IPCC’s Third and Fourth Assessment Reports for terrestrial carbon sinks (Fischlin et al. 2007).

While a number of existing studies look at the opportunities of REDD and the implications of its implementation in much detail (e.g. Bosetti and Lubowski 2010), none of them really considers its risk profile to determine the optimal composition of a mitigation portfolio given the uncertainty surrounding these sinks (Fuss 2010). In this paper, we therefore model the natural sink stochastically and as a function of atmospheric Greenhouse Gas (GHG) concentration accounting for possible climate feedbacks. We analyze different emissions targets and identify the best hedging strategies in the technosphere given the uncertainty in the biosphere with explicit focus on their interrelation and potential climate feedbacks. Finally, we focus the analysis on the potential for BECCS, which is by no means certain, as estimates differ across the supply chain starting with sustainably harvestable biomass for bioenergy and ending with the potential for safe and permanent storage.

2 Literature discussion

The relevant literature concerns both methodologies to find optimal mitigation strategies in the face of uncertainty and the different options (e.g. abatement, BECCS) underlying such strategies in the presence of natural (stochastic) sinks. In addition, the literature on the effect of including sinks in mitigation optimization is discussed. Starting with the literature on mitigation portfolios, it is important to note that previous analyses of optimal policy portfolios have typically neglected NETs (e.g. Gerlagh et al. 2009). Evidently, this is in the process of changing, as most global assessments now acknowledge the importance of emissions turning negative in order to achieve the two-degree target. For example, the Global Energy Assessment (GEA 2012) finds that almost zero or negative emissions are needed in the second half of the century for all their scenarios. The new scenarios by the International Energy Agency, ETP2012, (IEA 2012) also show a rapid deployment of BECCS being essential for reaching the two-degree target with large potential in industry. While these assessments are deterministic, the focus of this paper is on the effect of uncertainty on the composition of the optimal mitigation portfolio.

Both the PAGE (Policy Analysis of the Greenhouse Effect) model, which has been used in the Stern Review (Hope 2006), and the Dynamic Integrated model of Climate and the Economy (DICE) (Nordhaus 2008), for example, consider the impacts of climate change and the effects of parametric uncertainty. In a stochastic version of DICE, Nordhaus (2008) includes normal distributions of the growth rate of total factor productivity (TFP), the sensitivity of temperature change to changes in GHG concentrations and the sensitivity of reductions in output to temperature changes. He finds that uncertainty does not play a large role for climate policy decisions, which is in contrast to the findings of PAGE and also our findings.Footnote 1 In addition, our interest is more focused on the availability of NETs, which are neither included in the stochastic DICE version nor in PAGE.

In a very recent paper by McInerney et al. (2012), the DICE model with parametric uncertainty is further explored for the impact that different decision criteria might have on abatement and the robustness of mitigation strategies. They find that criteria giving more weight to the mitigation strategy’s performance under worst-case scenarios lead to more near-term abatement and higher robustness, i.e. strategies trade off a low drop in expected performance against a large increase in the performance in the worst case scenario. The aim of McInerney et al’s paper is thus rather on expanding methods for decision-making and does neither explore NETs nor the importance of sinks and their associated uncertainties.

Bosetti et al. (2008) use the stochastic version of the regional hybrid integrated assessment model WITCH to analyze the optimal mitigation portfolio given uncertainty about the future stabilization target. They find a large hedging effect implying that overall mitigation is much higher than in the deterministic case, with public R&D into energy efficiency and investment into carbon-free technology (nuclear energy) being the main elements of the mitigation portfolio. There are no strategies pertaining to carbon sinks and also no NETs.

Lemoine et al. (2012) have implemented a dynamic portfolio of abatement, R&D, and NET policies under an exogenous CO2 constraint and with stochastic technological change. Their results show that near-term abatement is not sensitive to the availability of R&D policies, but if NETs are expected to become available, near-term abatement will be reduced substantially In this paper, we also include NETs, but we are less interested in strategies on R&D. Instead, we focus on (a) the relatively unexplored effect that the inclusion of natural sinks and the uncertainty that surrounds them has on robust and cost-minimizing mitigation strategies and overall policy costs and (b) the impact of expectations about BECCS potentials.

Further on the different strategies, a considerable body of literature is currently emerging on BECCS individually. BECCS was first put forth as an option by Obersteiner et al. (2001), Kraxner et al. (2003) and later in the 2005 Working Group III Report of the IPCC. Even though generally recognized as an option to potentially reduce emissions by up to 10 Gt of CO2 per year (IEAGHG 2011), certain caveats remain. These include uncertainties surrounding storage potentials, issues of social acceptance and possible problems of leakage (van der Zwaan and Gerlagh 2009). While the latter demonstrates that BECCS has its own risks, which do not apply to NETs not using geological storage (by e.g. applying biochar to soils (Lehmann 2007)), we adopt in this paper a relatively conservative number of 2,100 Gt CO2 for the storage potential, which we find not to be a binding constraint in the analysis, unless we substantially lower the target or significantly lower the BECCS potential.Footnote 2 In addition, any assessment of BECCS relies heavily on the assumption of sustainable forestry and minimization of indirect land use change effects due to increased demand for biomass (see e.g. Kraxner et al. 2012).

Next to BECCS and other carbon dioxide removal (CDR) techniquesFootnote 3, the role of accounting for and management of natural sinks have come to the forefront of the public debate about mitigation since Marrakech 2001. Efforts to analyze the implications from land use and management changes for carbon policy started even earlier (e.g. Ahlig et al. 1997) and forest carbon sequestration in particular has been at the centre of continuing research (e.g. Stavins 1999, and Sohngen and Mendelsohn 2003). Marginal costs of carbon sequestration have been found to be competitive and partially much cheaper than those of the options related to energy technologies. Van’t Veld and Plantinga (2005) implement a dynamic model of optimizing abatement and mitigation through sequestration under different expectations of carbon price developments. They find that for increasing prices abatement is unchanged and that also the absolute amount of sequestration in the mitigation portfolio might ultimately not be lower. However, the timing of sequestration changes, as rising carbon prices represent an incentive to delay, which is unique for sequestration activities. This is broadly in line with earlier findings by Sohngen and Mendelsohn (2003), but at odds with the general “consensus” that sequestration should happen as early as possible, which is due to that literature’s assumption on constant carbon prices according to van’t Veld and Plantinga (2005).

Notwithstanding the findings from such deterministic analysis, many uncertainties remain with respect to enhancing sinks, not only pertaining to management, but especially concerning the nature and dynamic behavior of the sinks themselves. Le Quéré et al. (2009) analyze trends and volatility in terrestrial and ocean sinks and find major uncertainties related to the former. Canadell and Raupach (2008) emphasize the risk emanating from disturbances such as fire and insect outbreaks having turned Canadian forests from a sink (before 2000) to a source of CO2. They point to the uncertainty about the future size and stability of the terrestrial carbon sink and stock and also stress the uncertainty related to parameters underlying the analysis such as the magnitude of the fertilization effect. As such properties have implications for the composition of the optimal mitigation portfolio, we account for this by modeling sinks stochastically. Furthermore, feedbacksFootnote 4 of decisions to sinks need to be taken into account: more GHG emissions will lead to a certain degree of fertilization up to a specific point. Such effects on the sink are modeled explicitly in the study at hand, but we also conduct sensitivity analyses to shed more light on the implications that uncertainty around this effect have on the composition of the optimal mitigation portfolio. Finally, geo-engineering has been suggested as a “savior of last resort” in the context of global warming. One suggestion is to inject sulphur into the stratosphere to achieve a temporary cooling effect (Crutzen 2006), which can be categorized as a solar radiation management (SRM) strategy. As this is a very immature field with little data and evidence on side effects such as eventual acidification of oceans due to high CO2 absorption, we have chosen to not consider such an option in our analysis.Footnote 5

3 Model

In this paper we use a stylized model to analyze the optimal dynamic mitigation strategy in the presence of NETs, CO2 sinks and uncertainty. A global decision-maker plans abatement and NET deployment bound by a cumulative emission target over the 21st century. The decision-maker selects the most cost-effective policy plan with two available options: (1) abatement and (2) deployment of NETs/CDR consisting of BECCS and Direct Air Capture (DAC). The technologies differ in their cost structure and mitigation levels. We assume abatement to be viable up to the level of base emissions with its marginal cost depending on the fraction of base emissions abated. For the deployment of NETs, the marginal costs for each technology are constant, BECCS being significantly cheaper, but its potential limited. DAC, on the other hand, is available at any mitigation level. The CO2 sink is modeled similar to Friedlingstein et al. (2006) to account for the feedback between atmospheric CO2 concentration, the change in temperature and the sink, with additional stochastic shocks representing extreme events like forest fires, pests, etc (Moore and Allard 2008). The probability of shock occurrence is modeled as being positively dependent on the cumulative emissions. The focus of the analysis will be the role of NETs deployment in the optimal policy plan and its interrelation with the stochastic CO2 sink.

We assume a global decision-maker whose objective is to select in each period t a policy portfolio minimizing the cost of ultimately meeting an exogenous constraint e* on the cumulative CO2 emissions of the whole planning horizon. The options available are different levels of abatement \( \left\{ {{a_t}} \right\}_{t=1}^{T-1 } \) and NET deployment \( \left\{ {{n_t}} \right\}_{t=1}^{T-1 } \) Footnote 6. The maximum level of abatement in each period is given by the business-as-usual (BAU) emissions e t , the marginal abatement and NET cost functions are denoted MAC (a t , e t , t), MNC (n t , e t , t) respectively. The increase in cumulative CO2 emissions in period t, \( ghg\_inc{r_t} \), is given by

$$ ghg\_inc{r_t}={e_t}-{a_t}-{n_t}-{s_{t+1 }} $$
(1)

with S t+1 denoting the sink capacity at the beginning of period t + 1, i.e. the end of period t. The sink is modeled following Friedlingstein et al. (2006) with the addition of random shocks X t to account for extreme events (Moore and Allard 2008). The evolution of the cumulative CO2 emissions ghg t and sink S t is modeled by coupled difference equations

$$ gh{g_{t+1 }}=gh{g_t}+{e_t}-{a_t}-{n_t}-{s_{t+1 }} $$
(2)
$$ {s_{t+1 }}={s_t}+\beta ghg\_inc{r_t}{X_t} $$
(3)

where β is the land (ocean) carbon sink sensitivity to atmospheric CO2. We model the probability that the shock X t occurs as being positively dependent on the current cumulative emissions ghg t , and the probability distribution of the shock X t is given by

$$ {X_t}=\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {1-\delta, \mathrm{with}\,\mathrm{probability}\,\alpha +\left( {1-\alpha } \right){{{\left( {\sum\nolimits_{i=1}^t {{e_i}} } \right)}}^{-1 }}gh{g_t}} \\ {\quad 1,\mathrm{with}\,\mathrm{probability}\left( {1-\alpha } \right)\left( {1-{{{\left( {\sum\nolimits_{i=1}^t {{e_i}} } \right)}}^{-1 }}gh{g_t}} \right)} \\ \end{array}} \right. $$
(4)

where δ is the size of the negative shock to the sink and α is a constant increasing the likelihood of a negative shock.

The whole model can be thus formulated as

$$ \mathop{\min}\limits_{{{a_t},{n_t}}}\mathbb{E}\left[ {\sum\limits_{t=1}^{T-1 } {{{{\left( {1+r} \right)}}^{-t }}} \left( {\int_0^{{{a_t}}} {MAC\left( {x,{e_t},t} \right)\ dx+\int_0^{{{n_t}}} {MNC\left( {y,{e_t},t} \right)dy} } } \right)} \right] $$
(5)

subject toFootnote 7

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {{s_{t+1 }}=\frac{1}{{1+\beta {X_t}}}{s_t}+\left( {1-\frac{1}{{1+\beta {X_t}}}} \right)\left( {{e_t}-{a_t}-{n_t}} \right)} \hfill & {\mathrm{for}} \hfill & {t=1,2,\ldots,\ T-1} \hfill \\ {gh{g_{t+1 }}=gh{g_t}+{e_t}-{a_t}-{n_t}-{s_{t+1 }}} \hfill & {\mathrm{for}} \hfill & {t=1,2,\ldots,\ T-1} \hfill \\ {{s_1}=0} \hfill & {} \hfill & {} \hfill \\ {gh{g_1}=0} \hfill & {} \hfill & {} \hfill \\ {{a_t}\in \left[ {0,{e_t}} \right]} \hfill & {\mathrm{for}} \hfill & {t=1,2,\ldots,\ T-1} \hfill \\ {{{\mathbb{E}}_{T-1 }}\left[ {gh{g_T}} \right]\leq {e^{*}}} \hfill & {} \hfill & {} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$

As formulated, the model is a stochastic optimal control model and can be solved backwards. Each model run yields the optimal mitigation portfolio in each period conditional on previous sink shocks and abatement and NET policies and also the associated expected cost, which is later on referred to as portfolio cost. This enables us to derive the expected values of respective mitigation options, assuming the decision-maker behaves optimally and the sink capacity follows Eq. (3). At the same time, the different cost structure of BECCS and DAC allows us to identify which technology is deployed and to which extent. For the analysis of the results, we report expected abatement, BECCS and DAC levels in the respective periods, and also the total levels for the whole planning period.

4 Data

In the analysis we consider three periods - 2010–2029, 2030–2049 and 2050–2099, chosen so that they approximately correspond to the near-term, intermediate-term and long-term periods for which the CO2 emission goals are discussed. The Business as Usual (BAU) emissions e t (in Gt CO2) for the respective periods were taken from the new RCP8.5 prepared for the Fifth Assessment Report of the IPCC.

$$ {e_1}=820,\ {e_2}=1171,\ {e_3}=5721 $$

While the new reference concentration pathway can be considered a revision of the A2 scenario with assumptions derived from the latter, RCP8.5 also takes into account enhancements in land use and land cover change projections (Riahi et al. 2011). The cumulative CO2 emissions of the 21st century have to meet the specified constraint e*, cumulative emissions being considered a robust indicator of total temperature change (Allen et al 2009; Matthews et al 2009; National Research Council 2011). We set the exogenous constraint in the baseline to 880 Gt CO2, which corresponds to a year 2100 CO2 concentration of 435 ppm (Lemoine et al. (2012), assuming a constant airborne fraction of 0.45 (Denman et al. 2007)), other levels are used for sensitivity analysis and discussed later.

The land (ocean) carbon sink sensitivity β representing the feedback between atmospheric CO2 concentration, the temperature and the sink, is from Friedlingstein et al. (2006), who provide numbers for the so-called “gain factor”, which estimates the effect of climate-induced changes in the carbon budget on the rate of increase of atmospheric CO2. We use the average of the land and ocean factors reported in the paper as the sensitivity estimate for the feedback between atmospheric CO2 concentration, the temperature and the sink, i.e. β = 0.4261. The levels of the sink shock parameters (α, δ) are varying between the model runs, as their impact on the robustness of results is tested.

As for the discount rate, we assume a rate of 5 % per year in the base case. However, we acknowledge the huge debate surrounding discounting in climate mitigation analysis and test for a range of 0–10 %.

For the functional form of the abatement cost, we assume that its average cost depends on the fraction of BAU emissions abated. For its estimation, marginal abatement cost curves (MAC) have been taken from the literature (van Vuuren et al. 2009), where several bottom-up and top-down approaches were compared with the IPCC AR4 results. They show that - especially at low costs - there are hardly any differences in MACs and they fit an exponential function, which we use as the MAC function:

(6)

This implies that it is possible to reduce emissions in 2030 by around 50 % at 100 US$/tCO2 compared to the baseline.

A second type of cost function applies to the deployment of NETs. We represent NETs as BECCS and DAC. We assume that DAC is available at any level, its marginal cost according to American Physical Society et al. (2011) being estimated to amount to 550 US$ for a scenario considered to be realistic. The potential of BECCS, on the other hand, is constrained. According to Hoogwijk et al. (2005), the final energy supply based on bioenergy from land-based feedstocks (without biofuels) for the A1 scenario of the IPCC in 2030 is 41 EJ/year, in 2050 it is 132 EJ/year and in 2100 it is 225 EJ/year. For the calculation of BECCS constraints, we assume that no more BECCS can be installed than can be served by fully exploiting these biomass potentials. This gives us (seeing that a power plant produces approximately 7 GJ/tCO2 captured (Rhodes and Keith 2005)Footnote 8) the maximum negative emission potential of BECCS for electricity deployment as 5.85 GtCO2/year in 2030, 18.8 GtCO2/year in 2050 and 32.1 GtCO2/year in 2100.Footnote 9 For the costs, Gough and Upham (2011) report an upper-limit BECCS cost of 105 US$/tCO2. While presenting a review of many expert opinions, they conclude that care needs to be taken not to overestimate the BECCS potential mainly because the cost of connecting bio-processing infrastructure with CO2 storage sites is not well researched and also because scenarios of global bioenergy potential remain contentious. The latter is largely due to the difficulty of fully accounting for competition for land, which again depends on other uncertain parameters, and which could change the cost for BECCS (Rhodes and Keith 2005).

The implications for DAC are that, even if its marginal costs fall significantly, “coherent CO2 mitigation would result in DAC deployment only after nearly all significant point sources of fossil CO2 emissions are eliminated, either by substitution of non-fossil alternatives or by capture of nearly all of their CO2 emissions” (American Physical Society et al. 2011). The marginal NET cost function MNC (n t , e t , t) thus becomes:

$$ MNC\left( {{n_t},{e_t},t} \right)=\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {} \hfill & {\mathrm{if}\,{n_t} < 117\,GtC{O_2}\;and\,t=1} \hfill \\ {105\ US\$} \hfill & {\mathrm{if}\,{n_t} < 377\,GtC{O_2}\;and\,t=2} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & {\mathrm{if}\,{n_t} < 1605\,GtC{O_2}\;and\,t=3} \hfill \\ {550\ US\$} \hfill & {\mathrm{else}} \hfill \\ \end{array}} \right. $$
(7)

It should be noted that, as not all parameterizations could benefit from a full calibration to empirical work, the relative effects of the various variables are analysed and extensive sensitivity analyses with respect to the numbers of the key parameters is conducted in order to ensure the robustness of our results. The goal of the analysis, therefore, is not to provide specific levels of the policy variables, but rather to assess the robustness of the optimal portfolios and identify the crucial parameters affecting them.

5 Results

The base case uses the data introduced in Section 4 and ignores any shock to the sink, i.e. the values for the shock size (δ) and the probability of a shock (α) are zero. We would expect the NETs deployment to be sensitive to changes in the perception of future costs, i.e. the discount rate the decision–maker employs, as NETs are quite expensive and thus will be shifted into the future the more one discounts future cost. A variable often discussed is the feedback effect of the carbon sink to the CO2 in the atmosphere (Higgins and Harte 2012), i.e. β. The higher this factor, the less mitigation is needed in total. As NETs are an expensive option to mitigate emissions, we thus expect the NETs deployment to fall with an increase in the feedback effect. Connected to both uncertainty in the climate agreement negotiation process (Bosetti et al. 2008), but also scientific uncertainty with respect to e.g. climate sensitivity (Caldeira et al. 2003), we also do not know the “true” cumulative emission constraint the decision-maker must target. A lower target would increase the deployment of NETs as more mitigation is needed in total. On the other hand, due to the uncertainty in the sink, NETs can act as a reversal option in the last period in case of overshooting the target because of a shock. Finally, the size and probability of occurrences of sink shocks are uncertain in the literature so far. Due to the argument above, we expect NETs deployment to rise in the last period with increases in either the probability or the size of shocks to the sink.

Our baseline results, as summarized in Table 1, without any shock to the sink (i.e. δ = 0 and α = 0) show that totally 4,260 GtCO2 are mitigated by abatement and 1,605 GtCO2 by NETs. All mitigation by NETs occurs in the last period and by deployment of BECCS (1,605 GtCO2 is the maximum amount of BECCS in the third period). Abatement on the other hand is split between the three periods (first period: 140 GtCO2, second period: 360 GtCO2, third period: 3,760 GtCO2). The corresponding MACs of the last unit mitigated are increasing from 4.7 $US per tCO2 in the first period to 443.4 $US per tCO2 in the third period, which is just short of the $550/tCO2 that would bring forth DAC. In the third period the abatement option is used for the first 2,879 GtCO2, afterwards deployment of BECCS is cheaper and employed to the maximum potential (1,605 GtCO2). Finally, abatement is used until the MAC rise up to the cost of DAC.

Table 1 Values for baseline scenario

These baseline results are now tested for their sensitivity to changes in key parameters. We begin by assuming different levels of discount factors in Eq. (5). The results using discount rates of 0 %, 2.5 %, 5 %, 7.5 % and 10 % are shown in Fig. 1. There are two main points of interest at the extreme values of the scale: if the discount rate increases, it is optimal to shift more and more mitigation into the last period, even above the point where the relatively expensive DAC is deployed. For example, at a discount rate of 10 % the optimal portfolio consists of abatement of 60 GtCO2 in period 2 and 3,880 GtCO2 in period 3, BECCS of 1,605 GtCO2 and DAC of 175 GtCO2 in period 3. Thus the cost of the last unit mitigated by NETs in Period 3 will be $550/t, given the assumptions of the model. At the opposite end, without discounting, it becomes optimal to deploy BECCS already in the second period and shift more and more abatement towards the first periods. In our example the abatement quantities in period 1, 2 and 3 are 340 GtCO2, 600 GtCO2, 3,240 GtCO2 respectivelyFootnote 10 and the BECCS deployment in period 2 and 3 is 377 GtCO2 and 1,605 GtCO2 respectively at a discount rate of 0 %. This implies that without discounting about 40 % of the emissions are already mitigated in the first period and even 80 % of the new emissions in the second period.

Fig. 1
figure 1

GtCO2 mitigated for different discount rates in time periods 2010–2029, 2030–2049, 2050–2099

Furthermore, we investigate the sensitivity of our results to changes in the sink’s sensitivity to atmospheric CO2, β. While there seems to be a general agreement that CO2 fertilization does have a positive impact on the sink, the exact number for the sink’s sensitivity to atmospheric CO2 is uncertain. The results of the sensitivity analysis with respect to β displayed in Fig. 2 illustrate that the deployment of BECCS (and DAC) is indeed very much dependent on this sensitivity. For the value taken from Friedlingstein et al. (2006) or higher, NETs occupy a relatively stable share in the mitigation portfolio, which is equal to the maximum BECCS potential. The amount of abatement, on the other hand, decreases as the sink takes up more of the emissions. However, when the feedback effect is smaller, the amount of CO2 abated with NETs increases, i.e. deployment of DAC starts and increases (for a β of 0.3 deployment of DAC is 35 GtCO2, for 0.2 it is 215 GtCO2 and for β of 0 deployment of DAC is 695 GtCO2). The lower the sink’s sensitivity β, the larger these increases are. This result is not surprising, as it implies that the amount of “free” mitigation through uptake by natural sinks decreases and NETs have to make up for the difference.

Fig. 2
figure 2

GtCO2 mitigated for different values for β (sink’s sensitivity to atmospheric CO2) in time periods 2010–2029, 2030–2049, 2050–2099

In Fig. 3 we compare the optimal portfolios with different cumulative emission targets. We look at targets that correspond to year 2100 CO2 concentration of 390 ppm, 435 ppm, 490 ppm and 550 ppmFootnote 11, i.e. 88 GtCO2, 880 GtCO2, 1,500 GtCO2 and 2,900 GtCO2 respectively. In terms of NETs deployment we see that if the decision-maker aims for the least stringent cumulative emissions target (2,900 GtCO2), NETs are not part of the optimal portfolio anymore. All mitigation is done through abatement, where especially in the medium and long term the amount can also be reduced. At the other end of the spectrum, if the decision maker aims for the lowest target (88 GtCO2), the optimal portfolio in the last period contains the maximum amount of BECCS (1,605 GtCO2) plus some 1,035 GtCO2 of DAC, as we need so much abatement in the last period that DAC becomes cheaper than the marginal unit of abatement. Independently of the target, period 1 abatement changes from 140 GtCO2 for the 88 and 880 targets to only 80 GtCO2 for the 1,500 and 2,900 targets.

Fig. 3
figure 3

GtCO2 mitigated and PV of optimal portfolio costs in bill. US$ for different cumulative emission targets (e *) in time periods 2010–2029, 2030–2049, 2050–2099

The present value (PV) of the portfolio cost increases exponentially with the stricter cumulative emissions targets. As can be seen in Fig. 3, the costs of the portfolio aiming at the 88 GtCO2 target is 22 times higher than for the portfolio aiming at the 2,900 GtCO2 target, and 2.5 times higher than for the 880 GtCO2 target.

As many results regarding NETs deployment depend on the potential for BECCS, we perform a sensitivity analysis regarding this variable. The results are shown in Fig. 4, as the BECCS potential introduced in Section 4 is multiplied with 0.5 to 1.5 in every period. We see that even though BECCS is used only in the third period, its potential has a direct impact on the optimal abatement already in the first and second periods. An increase of 50 % in the potential of BECCS is reflected in an over 40 % (20 %) decrease in the first (second) period abatement. Thus, an underestimation of the real potential would lead to unnecessary high abatement in the first periods, resulting in a lower BECCS deployment in the third period.

Fig. 4
figure 4

GtCO2 mitigated and PV of optimal portfolio costs in bill. US$ for different BECCS potentials in relation to baseline assumption in time periods 2010–2029, 2030–2049, 2050–2099

If BECCS potentials are higher than in our baseline, i.e. for multipliers of 1.25 or 1.5, the present value of the portfolio costs as shown in Fig. 4 decrease as we deploy more BECCS up to the new maximum. But this decrease is relatively small compared to the increase if the BECCS potential is lower than in the baseline, i.e. for multipliers of 0.5 or 0.75. In this case, the PV of the costs almost doubles because of the increased deployment of DAC in the last period.

To conclude, we investigate the reaction of our optimal portfolio to changes in the size (δ) and probability (α) of a shock to the carbon sink. The respective total emissions to be mitigated by the two options are shown in Fig. 5. It can be seen that with increasing shock size, more mitigation needs to be carried out to get to the target in the last period in total. The larger part of this increase is achieved through NETs deployment. As the potential of BECCS is already fully exploited in the baseline case, the increase can here only happen via a deployment in DAC. With a higher probability of a shock to the sink, this increase with the shock size gets steeper. The PV of the optimal portfolio costs is depicted in Fig. 5. In line with our expectations, the costs increase with the probability and the size of a shock to the carbon sink.

Fig. 5
figure 5

GtCO2 mitigated over the whole planning horizon and PV of the optimal portfolio cost in bill. US$ for different values of the shock size (δ) and shock probability (α)

6 Conclusion

In this paper, we have addressed the question of how the optimal mitigation portfolio, in which negative emission technology is available to achieve ambitious stabilization targets, is affected by the inclusion of natural sinks conducting a number of sensitivity analyses to account for uncertainty in the underlying parameters.

Results that were shown to be robust across all sensitivity runs indicate that abatement is generally used in all periods, whereas BECCS only in the long-term. Thus, not having BECCS at full disposal for large-scale deployment now might not preclude following the optimal strategy. Furthermore, near-time optimal abatement changes with the expectations of BECCS potentials in the future. Further research to decrease the uncertainty surrounding these potentials is therefore necessary. Another central result of our paper is that sink uncertainty has a positive impact on the cost-optimal adoption of negative emission technologies. If we compare the baseline to the case where shocks are applied to the sink, NETs deployment increases. This implies that neglecting sink stochasticity leads to underestimating the necessary mitigation needs and NETs in particular.

While the qualitative results appear to be stable across different sensitivity analyses of key parameters, there is substantial uncertainty about the true value of climate sensitivity of the sink to the concentration of CO2 (β). Future research should look into inclusion of uncertainty about this sensitivity and also about the impact of learning about carbon cycle feedbacks on the structure and temporal deployment of mitigation. Obviously, the result will be influenced by risk preferences, the availability of NETs to offset larger amounts of emissions in the last period and the possibility to overshoot in the medium term. Finally, other sources of uncertainty such as the cost of abatement have not been explicitly modeled in this paper, but would be of interest for future research seeking to identify and quantify further tradeoffs within the mitigation portfolio. The same is true for stranded assets as multiple bio-options are deployed over the century. Lastly, the modeling exercise abstracts from issues pertaining to social inertia and public acceptance in particular: specifically pipelines and storage in connection with fossil-based emission sources have been met with significant resistance from residents in affected areas (Wallquist et al. 2012).