Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The transaction cost economics (TCE) theory of trading favors

  • Published:
Asia Pacific Journal of Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Trading favors is a pervasive business practice, especially in emerging economies. To date, a range of theories has been utilized to explore trading favors, but most extant studies focus especially on negative aspects of favors (e.g., corruption and bribery). We adopt transaction cost economics (TCE) to analyze systematically trading favors as an economizing practice serving efficiency purposes. From the TCE perspective, trading favors is a component of the relational contracting portion of transaction governance, and contributes to economizing on bounded rationality and bounded reliability. We hypothesize that trading favors will be more prevalent in (1) macro-contexts characterized by a vacuum of formal institutions as well as by excessive formal rules; (2) cultural contexts where in-group membership is highly valued; (3) high bounded rationality/low bounded reliability contexts where frequent opportunities exist for indirect reciprocity; and (4) cases whereby no asset-specific investment(s) in innovation need to be made by the supplier of the favor. Enforcement mechanisms such as in-group sanctions, access to formal contracting as a complement to favors, possibility of image scoring and incentive compatibility can function as critical components of the trading favors practice. We suggest a classification of favor trading practices based on their link to formal contracting and rate of recurrence, and describe a range of likely impacts.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Good faith reprioritization captures instances whereby economic actors make ex ante commitments in good faith (with benevolent intent), but the importance of those commitments diminishes over time (preferences are reordered). Time discounting bias (placing a lower value on future events than more proximate events) can also cause economic actors to reprioritize, and postpone efforts to make good on commitments to the point that such commitments can no longer be fulfilled. Scaling back on overcommitment results from the tendency of managers to make excessive commitments ex ante, that then need to be scaled back ex post.

  2. Linguistically, protetzia is in fact a borrowing from the Russian “протекция,” literally meaning “protection.” Both the word and the practice were likely influenced by extensive Russian emigration to Israel.

  3. Our viewpoint is different from Husted’s (1994), who looked solely at corruption (associated with an extreme type of trading favors with substantial negative spill-overs) as a distinct class of transactions, involving a private exchange between two parties, and associated with abuse of a public or collective responsibility.

  4. Zhou and Peng’s study focused specifically (and more narrowly) on bribery. To the extent that bribery can be interpreted as a specific (albeit potentially damaging) form of favors, their study does provide partial evidence that favors are more prevalent in underdeveloped institutional contexts.

  5. It should be noted that in real world situations a complete vacuum of formal rules is unlikely, as even newly emerging economies usually possess burdensome regulations in some policy areas. However, these economies simultaneously suffer from the lack of efficient, local intermediary firms. The institutional voids referred to in Hypothesis 1 pertain to the vacuum of helpful/business-friendly regulations and institutions that facilitate transactions and ensure their transparency, the information disclosure associated with them, and their legality.

  6. Here, we assume that business groups do not engage in questionable practices such as profit tunneling discussed in a previous example, and we use business group governance only as a generic illustration of how institutional voids can be filled.

References

  • Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. 1972. Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62: 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, R. W. 1992. An empirical investigation of international marketing ethics: Problems encountered by Australian firms. Journal of Business Ethics, 11(3): 161–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnes, J. W., Crook, M. H., Koybaea, T., & Stafford, E. 1997. Why our Russian alliances fail. Long Range Planning, 30(4): 540–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, L. 1990. The choice between public and private law. Discussion paper no. 70, Program in Law and Economics, Harvard Law School, Harvard, Cambridge, MA.

  • Bertrand, M., Mehta, P., & Mullainathan, S. 2002. Ferreting out tunnelling: An application to Indian business groups. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1): 121–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & McLaren, J. 1993. Taxes and bribery: The role of wage incentives. Economic Journal, 103(416): 119–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bramoulle, Y., & Goyal, S. 2009. Favouritism. Working paper no. 09–41, Centre Interuniversitaire sur le Risque, les Politiques Economiques et l’Empoli, Quebec City, PQ, Canada.

  • Cai, S., Jun, M., & Yang, Z. 2010. Implementing supply chain information integration in China: The role of institutional forces and trust. Journal of Operations Management, 28: 257–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, A., & Unger, J. 1982. Grey and black: The hidden economy of rural China. Pacific Affairs, 55(3): 452–471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, C. J. P., Ding, Y., & Kim, S. 2010. High-level politically connected firms, corruption, and analyst forecast accuracy around the world. Journal of International Business Studies, 41: 1505–1524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chua, A. 2003. Globalization and ethnic hatred. Phi Kappa Phi Forum, 83(4): 13–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica, NS4: 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cockroft, L. 1996. Transnational bribery: Is in inevitable?. Business Strategy Review, 7(3): 30–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, M. W. 2002. Explaining corruption: An institutional choice approach. Crime, Law and Social Change, 38(1): 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connor, K., & Prahalad, C. 1991. A resource-based theory of the firm: Knowledge versus opportunism. Organization Science, 7(5): 477501.

    Google Scholar 

  • David, R. J., & Han, S. K. 2004. A systematic assessment of the empirical support for transaction cost economics. Strategic Management Journal, 25(1): 39–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. H., & Ruhe, J. A. 2003. Perceptions of country corruption: Antecedents and outcomes. Journal of Business Ethics, 43(4): 275–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, R., & Wang, Y. 2010. Trading favours within Chinese business groups. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 100: 429–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freuchen, P. 1961. Book of the Eskimos. Cleveland, OH: World Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghoshal, S. 2005. Bad management theories are destroying good management practices. Academy of Management Learning and Education, 4(1): 75–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghoshal, S., & Moran, P. 1996. Bad for practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 21(1): 13–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91: 481–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grøgaard, B., & Verbeke, A. 2012. Twenty key hypotheses that make internalization theory the general theory of international strategic management. In A. Verbeke & H. Merchant (Eds.). Handbook of research in international strategic management: 7–30. Cheltenham, UK: Elgar.

  • Groseclose, T. 1996. An examination of the market for favours and votes in congress. Economic Inquiry, 34: 320–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. 1988. The fatal conceit: The errors of socialism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, C. W. L. 1990. Cooperation, opportunism, and invisible hand: Implications for transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 15: 500–513.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. 2004. Opportunism is not the only reason why firms exist: Why an explanatory emphasis on opportunism may mislead management strategy. Industrial and Corporate Change, 13: 401–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoskisson, R. E., Eden, L., Lau, C.-M., & Wright, M. 2000. Strategy in emerging economies. Academy of Management Journal, 43: 249–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Husted, B. W. 1994. Honour among thieves: A transaction-cost interpretation of corruption in the third world countries. Business Ethics Quarterly, 4(1): 17–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Husted, B. W. 1999. Wealth, culture, and corruption. Journal of International Business Studies, 30(2): 339–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jagannathan, N. V. 1986. Corruption, delivery systems, and property rights. World Developmet, 14: 127–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M., Li, Q., & Rahman, A. 2010. Understanding corruption and firm responses in cross-national firm-level surveys. Journal of International Business Studies, 41: 1481–1504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalla, S. J. 2010. Essays in favour-trading. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.

  • Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. 1997. Why focused strategies may be wrong for emerging markets. Harvard Business Review, 75: 41–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. 2000. Is group affiliation profitable in emerging markets? An analysis of diversified Indian business groups. Journal of Finance, 55(2): 867–891.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khanna, T., & Yafeh, Y. 2007. Business groups in emerging markets: Paragons or parasites?. Journal of Economic Literature, 45: 331–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, R. G. 1989. The human career. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kramarz, F., & Thesmar, D. 2006. Social networks in the boardroom. SSNR working paper no. 5496, Social Science Research Network, Rochester, New York.

  • Ledeneva, A. V. 1998. Russian’s economy of favours: Blat, networking and informal exchange. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, K., Qian, G., Yu, J. H., & Ho, Y. 2005. Trading favours for marketing advantage: Evidence from Hong Kong, China, and the Unites States. Journal of International Marketing, 13(1): 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, P. P. 2007. Social tie, social capital, and social behaviour: Toward an integrative model of informal exchange. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24(2): 227–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, W., He, A., Lan, H., & Yiu, D. 2012. Political connections and corporate diversification in emerging economies: Evidence from China. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 29(3): 799–818.

    Google Scholar 

  • Llewellyn, K. N. 1931. What price contract? An essay in perspective. Yale Law Journal, 40: 704–751.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luo, Y. 2000. Guanxi and business. Hackensack, NJ: World Scientific.

    Google Scholar 

  • Macrae, J. 1982. Underdevelopment and the economics of corruption: A game theory approach. World Development, 10: 677–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maine, H. 1959. Ancient law. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, K. E., & Peng, M. W. 2004. Identifying leading theories for research on Central and Eastern Europe: Transactions, resources, and institutions. Working paper, Copenhagen Business School and The Ohio State University, Copenhagen and Columbus.

  • Morck, R., Wolfenzon, D., & Yeung, B. 2005. Corporate governance, economic entrenchment, and growth. Journal of Economic Literature, 43: 655–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mudambi, R., & Navarra, P. 2003. Political culture and foreign direct investment: The case of Italy. Economics of Governance, 4(1): 37–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mudambi, R., Navarra, P., & Delios, A. 2012. Government regulation, corruption and FDI. Mimeo. doi:10.1007/s10490-012-9311-y.

  • Mudambi, R., Navarra, P., & Nocosia, D. 1996. Plurality vs. proportional representation: An analysis of Sicillian elections. Public Choice, 86(3–4): 341–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. 1993. Why is rent-seeking so costly to growth?. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 83(2): 409–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal, G. 1970. Corruption as a hindrance to modernization in South Asia. In A. J. Heidenheimer & M. Johnston (Eds.). Political corruption: Concepts and contexts. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. 1965. The logic of collective action. Boston: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pande, R. 2003. Can mandated political representation increase policy influence for disadvantaged minorities? Theory and evidence from India. American Economic Review, 93(4): 1132–1151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peng, M. W. 2003. Institutional transitions and strategic choices. Academy of Management Review, 28(2): 275–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peng, M. W., Lee, S.-H., & Wang, D. Y. L. 2005. What determines the scope of the firm over time? A focus on institutional relatedness. Academy of Management Review, 30(3): 622–633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peng, M. W., Lu, Y., Shenkar, O., & Wang, D. 2001. Treasures in the China shop: A review of management and organizational research on Greater China. Journal of Business Research, 52: 95–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollak, R. 1985. A transaction cost approach to families and households. Journal of Economic Literature, 23: 581–608.

    Google Scholar 

  • Puffer, S. M., McCarthy, D. J., & Boisot, M. 2009. Entrepreneurship in Russia and China: The impact of formal institutional voids. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 34(3): 441–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riordan, M., & Williamson, O. 1985. Asset specificity and economic organization. International Journal of Industrial Organisation, 3: 365–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A., D’Cruz, J., & Verbeke, A. 1995. Internationalisation and de-internalisation: Will business networks replace multinationals?. In G. Boyd (Ed.). Competitive and cooperative macromanagement—The challenges of structural interdepence: 107–128. Aldershot, UK: Elgar/RSH.

  • Semaw, S., Renna, P., Harris, J. W. K., Fiebel, C. S., Bernor, R. L., Fesseha, N. Y., & Mowbray, K. 1997. 2.5 million-year-old stone tools from Gona, Ethiopia. Nature, 385: 333–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shalin, D. N. 1999. Review of “Russian’s Economy of Favours: Blat, Networking and Informal Exchange”. Contemporary Psychology, 28(5): 558–560.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. 1961. Administrative behaviour, 2nd ed. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. 1998. The two faces of Adam Smith. Southern Economic Journal, 65(1): 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. 2005. Hayek and experimental economics. Review of Austrian Economics, 18(2): 135–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, D. 2000. The causes of corruption: A cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics, 76(3): 399–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsang, E. W. K. 2006. Behavioral assumptions and theory development: The case of transaction cost economics. Strategic Management Journal, 27: 999–1001.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verbeke, A. 2009. International business strategy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verbeke, A., & Greidanus, N. S. 2009. The end of the opportunism vs. trust debate: Bounded reliability as a new envelope concept in research on MNE governance. Journal of International Business Studies, 40: 1471–1495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verbeke, A., & Kano, L. 2010. Transaction cost economics (TCE) and the family firm. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 34: 1173–1182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verbeke, A., & Kano, L. 2012a (forthcoming). The transaction cost economics theory of the family firm: Family-based human asset specificity and the bifurcation bias. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice.

  • Verbeke, A., & Kano, L. 2012b. International business strategy. In C. R. Thomas & W. F. Shughart II (Eds.). Oxford handbook in managerial economics: Ch. 18. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volkema, R. 1999. Ethicality in negotiations: An analysis of perceptual similarities and differences between Brazil and the United States. Journal of Business Research, 45: 59–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Hippel, E. 1987. Cooperation between rivals: Informal know-how trading. Research Policy, 16: 291–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wall, J. A., Jr. 1990. Managers in the People’s Republic of China. Executive, 4(2): 19–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wan, W. P. 2005. Country resource environments, firm capabilities, and corporate diversification strategies. Journal of Management Studies, 42: 161–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. 1981. The modern corporation: Origins, evolution, attributes. Journal of Economic Literature, 19: 1537–1568.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. 1993. Opportunism and its critics. Managerial and Decision Economics, 14: 97–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. 1996. The Mechanisms of governance. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wong, Y. H., & Tam, J. L. M. 2000. Mapping relationships in China: Dynamic approach. Journal of Business and Industrial Marketing, 15(1): 57–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamagashi, T., Mifune, N., Liu, J. H., & Pauling, J. 2008. Exchanges of group-based favours: Ingroup bias in the prisoner’s dilemma game with minimal groups in Japan and New Zealand. Asian Journal of Social Psychology, 11: 196–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, M. 1988. The modernity of power in the Chinese socialist order. Cultural Anthropology, 3: 408–427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou, J. Q., & Peng, M. W. 2012. Does bribery help or hurt firm growth around the world?. Asia Pacific Journal of Management. doi:10.1007/s10490-011-9274-4.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alain Verbeke.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Verbeke, A., Kano, L. The transaction cost economics (TCE) theory of trading favors. Asia Pac J Manag 30, 409–431 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-012-9324-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-012-9324-6

Keywords

Navigation