1 Introduction

This article studies corporate risk when the substantial part of a firm’s debt is financed by one (or few) major creditor(s) along with other minute creditors. In the literature of structural models of corporate risk that follows Merton (1974) and Black and Cox (1976), a single creditor is typically assumed for simplification. In reality, if there is only one creditor, the creditor has an option of flexible private renegotiation whenever the firm encounters financial distress. For instance, under Japan’s so-called ‘main bank system’, the main bank of a firm often chooses private renegotiation rather than legal renegotiation that follows application of the Japan’s Corporate Reorganization Law.Footnote 1 This can have several implications on the firm’s debt and stock values and its default and bankruptcy probabilities.

We present a Merton (1974)-type structural model of credit risk in which the firm (debtor) refinances its debt, there is cost for bankruptcy, and the creditor has an option to extend maturity, one of the simplest forms of private renegotiation.Footnote 2 In our model, the firm’s debt is in the form of a short-term discount bond with a fixed face value and fixed time to maturity. Every time the maturity of the debt contract arrives, the firm (i.e., stockholders) chooses whether to repay through refinancing (issuing a new debt and putting up more equity capital) or simply to default on the debt. If default is chosen by the firm, then the creditor chooses whether to force bankruptcy or not. That is, if extending the maturity of the debt repayment and making the firm continue as a going concern leads to debt value that is higher than the payoff of bankruptcy (the firm’s asset value minus cost of bankruptcy), the creditor chooses to do so. In other words, the model features a two-sided option, the firm’s decision for default and the creditor’s decision for bankruptcy. The latter implies that default does not necessarily lead to bankruptcy, so default and bankruptcy become two distinct events.

By making some restrictions on what the creditor can do in the event of the firm’s default, we can prove the existence of a solution to the model that possesses certain characteristics. Then we numerically solve the model and compute the debt and stock values of the firm and its default and bankruptcy probabilities. We find that when the firm defaults on debt, the creditor might extend the maturity of debt if the firm’s asset is so low that the creditor cannot get much from liquidation.

Effects of such maturity extension include the following. First, when the bankruptcy cost is high, the presence of such a maturity extension option can lead to higher debt value than in the absence of such an option. Second, because of the higher possibility of avoiding bankruptcy, stock value can also be higher. Third, the bankruptcy probability can be substantially lower. This is important for other minute creditors of the firm; without taking into account the main creditor’s maturity extension option, they would overestimate the firm’s bankruptcy probability. Finally, the default probability can be lower with the presence of possible maturity extension. This is because the reduction of the bankruptcy probability raises the stock value, which in turn makes refinancing easier. That is, the effect of the bank’s maturity extension option on the firm’s bankruptcy risk is not only through the obvious channel that extension simply could prevent immediate bankruptcy but also through a kind of ‘multiplier effect’ that the reduction of long-run bankruptcy probability raises the stock value, facilitates refinancing, lowers default probability, and further pushes down bankruptcy risk.

As a feature of models with refinancing, the effect of asset volatility (i.e., risk-taking of a firm) also differs from that in the standard Merton model; that is, the increase in volatility has a non-monotonic effect on the firm’s debt and stock values. Specifically, stockholders avert risk when the asset level is high, and the creditor likes risk when the asset level is relatively low. The former is because high volatility lowers the debt value and worsens refinancing condition for stockholders. The latter is because when the asset level is relatively low, high volatility raises the stock price, which makes the firm’s refinancing easier and the default probability lower. Adding the creditor’s maturity extension option to the model magnifies this non-monotonicity.

In some models in the literature, the trigger of default, or the threshold of the borrower firm’s asset level below which the firm defaults, is exogenously given.Footnote 3 Other models such as Leland (1994) and Leland and Toft (1996) have a one-sided option; stockholders choose such a threshold but the creditor does not have any option. Stockholders in these models make decisions whether to repay the debt to maintain the firm or whether to go bankrupt and transfer the ownership to the creditor.Footnote 4 When the bankruptcy cost is high, however, there can be situations that the stockholders give up repayment and choose bankruptcy but the creditor wants to maintain the firm even by offering postponement of repayment, and this yields models with a two-sided option. However, there are not many pricing models of corporate bonds in which the creditor can renegotiate over the repayment condition of the debtor. Among the few such pricing models are Mella-Barral and Perraudin (1997) and Fan and Sundaresan (2000). These models consider a firm that issues ‘consols’ and do not consider refinancing. In our model, the firm refinances a discount bond by issuing a new bond, the value of which is low when the asset level of the firm is low. One can interpret the firm of our model as issuing ‘consols’ with variable coupons whose amount increases as the credit risk of the firm increases.

The structure of the rest of the paper is as follows. In Sect. 2, we present our model in several versions and establish existence of solutions. Section 3 numerically computes solutions and gives discussion. Section 4 concludes.

2 Model

2.1 Common environment

There is a firm whose date-t asset value \(A_t\) follows a geometric Brownian motion under a risk-neutral probability measure:

$$\begin{aligned} dA_t=A_t(r dt+\sigma dW_t), \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(\sigma \) is the volatility, r is the risk-free rate, and \(W_t\) is a standard Brownian motion with respect to the risk-neutral probability. The firm owes a single creditor (e.g. “main bank”) a debt with face value f and time to maturity \(\Delta \) years. To abstract from the optimal capital structure choice problem, we assume that both f and \(\Delta \) are exogenously given to the firm for some institutional reasons. Once the maturity arrives, the firm repays the debt by the following refinancing process. First, the firm rolls over the debt; that is, the firm makes another debt contract again with face value f and time to maturity \(\Delta \). Because the amount of funds raised from this new debt contract is not enough to repay f, the firm fills the gap by raising equity capital.Footnote 5 As long as the firm stays solvent, this refinancing process is repeated every \(\Delta \) years.Footnote 6 Since the face value of the firm’s debt always remains constant at f, the model has a kind of time-homogeneous structure; nothing depends on the calendar time but only on the remaining time to the maturity of debt.

If the firm’s asset value, say \(\tilde{A}\), at the date of debt maturity is very low, the firm cannot repay the debt; that is, the amount of funds the firm can raise from re-borrowing and stock issuance does not reach f.Footnote 7 We call that situation default. In the event of default, the creditor has two options: bankruptcy and postponement. If the creditor chooses the bankruptcy option, it lets the firm go bankrupt and receives \(\min (f,\alpha \tilde{A})\), where \(\alpha \in (0,1]\) is the asset recovery rate. The idea is that bankruptcy is costly; if the firm’s asset level upon default is \(\tilde{A}\), then \(1-\alpha \) proportion is lost as bankruptcy cost and only \(\alpha \) proportion is received by the creditor (and potentially by stockholders if \(\alpha \tilde{A}>f\)). On the other hand, if the creditor chooses the postponement option to extend the date of debt maturity, it keeps the same debt but the new date of maturity comes in another \(\Delta \) years.

In Sect. 2.2, we will consider four versions of the model with refinancing that differ in assumptions on the creditor’s postponement option. In Model I, the creditor does not have the option to extend the maturity date and thus always forces bankruptcy after default. Hence this version resembles Leland and Toft (1996) while it still differs from their model in that the date of maturity only arrives every \(\Delta \) years while it arrives continuously in their model. In Models II and III, the creditor has the option to extend the maturity date but only N times, where N is an exogenously given bound. The difference between II and III is whether or not the remaining number of postponements allowed is reset to N once the firm successfully repays the debt. In Model IV, the creditor can extend the maturity date an unlimited number of times.

One of our goals is to demonstrate possible impacts of maturity extension in a simple model and provide complete proof for existence of a solution that applies a fixed-point theorem.Footnote 8 For that purpose, we have made several restrictive assumptions as above on what the creditor can do. First, our model has no benefit of debt and hence does not allow to study the optimal amount of debt (or optimal capital structure), so a fixed amount of debt is imposed. While this simplification seems to be a good step toward a model in which the amount of debt is endogenous, it remains an open question whether such a full-fledged model has very different implications. Second, it is assumed that the length of extension is always \(\Delta \). In reality, the creditor should choose between, for example, extending by 1 month and extending by 1 year. However, we can assume in our framework that \(\Delta \) is short (such as 1 month) and N is, say, twelve. In such an environment, the creditor is allowed to extend the maturity both for 1 month and for 12 months in total, which resembles the maturity choice by the creditor. Third, N, the maximum number of maturity extensions the creditor can give, is exogenously fixed in Models II and III. Although it is certainly less restrictive than existing models that do not allow maturity extension at all, it may appear somewhat arbitrary. One interpretation is that some past history or the creditor’s reputation has led investors to expect that the creditor gives extension at most a fixed number of times and not unlimitedly. We consider the case of an unlimited number of maturity extensions in Model IV.

2.2 Model variations and propositions

We focus on the prices of debt and stock right after the refinancing/maturity extension: that is, when the time to debt maturity is exactly \(\Delta \) years.Footnote 9 Let A be the level of the firm asset today and \(\tilde{A}\) be the (future) asset value at the date of debt maturity, which is \(\Delta \) years from today. Throughout the section, \(E_{\tilde{A}|A}[\cdot ]\) denotes expectation with respect to the risk-neutral probability conditional on the current asset level A. All proofs of propositions are in the “Appendix”.

2.3 Model I: no postponement

We start with the case where the creditor does not have the option to extend the maturity on the firm’s default, that is, when \(N=0\). In this case, the firm’s default always leads to bankruptcy. Let \(F^0(A)\) and \(S^0(A)\) denote the debt and stock values when the current level of the firm asset is A and the time to maturity of the debt is \(\Delta \) years. When the maturity arrives and the firm asset value at that time is \(\tilde{A}\), the firm repays f by issuing a new debt valued \(F^0(\tilde{A})\), and new stocks that are worth \(f-F^0(\tilde{A})\). After this process, the total stock value is \(S^0(\tilde{A})\) and hence the value of old stocks is the difference \(S^0(\tilde{A})-(f-F^0(\tilde{A}))\). This means that if this difference is nonnegative, the firm has positive net worth and can be successfully refinanced (hence no default).Footnote 10 Otherwise, the firm is bankrupt and the creditor recovers \(\min (f,\alpha \tilde{A})\). Let \(\bar{A}^0\) denote the default threshold, defined by

$$\begin{aligned} S^0(\tilde{A})-(f-F^0(\tilde{A}))\left\{ \begin{array}{lll}>0 &{}\quad \text {if }&{} \tilde{A}>\bar{A}^0\\ =0 &{}\quad \text {if}&{} \tilde{A}=\bar{A}^0\\<0 &{}\quad \text {if}&{} \tilde{A}<\bar{A}^0\\ \end{array}\right. . \end{aligned}$$
(2)

Then, as we explain below, the default threshold and the security prices should satisfy the following system of integral equations:

$$\begin{aligned}&F^0(A)=e^{-r\Delta }E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^0\}}f+\mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}<\bar{A}^0\}}\alpha \tilde{A}\right] , \quad \forall A>0, \end{aligned}$$
(3)
$$\begin{aligned}&S^0(A)=e^{-r\Delta }E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^0\}}(S^0(\tilde{A})-(f-F^0(\tilde{A})))\right] , \quad \forall A>0, \end{aligned}$$
(4)
$$\begin{aligned}&F^0(\bar{A}^0)+S^0(\bar{A}^0)=f. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

where \(\mathbf{1}_{\{\cdots \}}\) is the indicator function.

The interpretation of (3)–(5) is as follows. Any security price is the discounted future payoffs, discounted by the risk-free rate and the risk-neutral probability. The right side of (3) means that the future payoff to the creditor is f if the future asset level \(\tilde{A}\) is above the default threshold \(\bar{A}^0\), and it is \(\alpha \tilde{A}\) otherwise. The right side of (4) means that the future payoff to the stockholders is \(S^0(\tilde{A})-(f-F^0(\tilde{A}))\) if the future asset level is above the default threshold and is zero otherwise. Equation (5) only re-states the equality in (2).Footnote 11 We have the following proposition.

Proposition 2.1

A solution \((F^0(\cdot ), S^0(\cdot ), \bar{A}^0)\) to (3)–(5) exists, and it satisfies

  1. (i)

    \(\alpha A<F^0(A)+S^0(A)<A, \quad \forall A>0\),

  2. (ii)

    \( \alpha \bar{A}^0<f<\bar{A}^0\), and

  3. (iii)

    \(F^0(\cdot )+S^0(\cdot )\) is strictly increasing.

\(\square \)

The inequalities (i) are somewhat intuitive because no matter when cash flow occurs, the sum of payments to the creditor and stockholders never exceeds \(\tilde{A}\) or goes below \(\alpha \tilde{A}\), whose present values by the risk-neutral probability measure are A and \(\alpha A\), respectively. The inequality (ii) follows (i) and (5) and implies \(\min (f,\alpha \tilde{A})=\alpha \tilde{A}\) if \(\tilde{A}<\bar{A}^0\). Finally, (iii) confirms that the default threshold is well-defined by (2). Note that with the presence of bankruptcy cost, there is a region for \(\tilde{A}\) that is higher than the debt face value but still leads to default and bankruptcy, namely \({[}f,\bar{A}^0)\).

Due to the existence of bankruptcy cost and the absence of positive sides of debt such as tax advantage, the firm’s value defined as the sum of the stock and debt values is strictly smaller than the firm’s asset value A [see (i)]. Consequently, the optimal capital structure in the model would be ‘no debt at all’ if f were not exogenous to the firm.Footnote 12

Equation (3) implies that once the threshold \(\bar{A}^0\) is given, we can obtain the analytical solution for the debt value:Footnote 13

$$\begin{aligned} F^0(A; \bar{A}^0)=\alpha A \Phi (-x_1)+f e^{-r\Delta } \Phi (x_2), \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(\Phi (\cdot )\) is the cumulative density function of the standard normal distribution and

$$\begin{aligned} x_1, x_2 = \frac{\log \left( A/\bar{A}^0\right) +\left( r \pm \sigma ^2/2\right) \Delta }{\sigma \sqrt{\Delta }}. \end{aligned}$$
(7)

In the special case of \(\alpha =1\), the solution satisfies \(F^0(A)+S^0(A)=A, \; \forall A>0\) and (ii) reduces to \(\bar{A}^0=f\). In this case, (6)–(7) coincide with Merton (1974), a model without refinancing. If \(\alpha <1\), the present model differs from the Merton model even if the latter is augmented with the same bankruptcy cost. This is because in our model of refinancing the default threshold is strictly greater than f, while it remains f in the Merton model.

We conclude Model I with the following proposition.

Proposition 2.2

There exists a unique \(\underline{A}^1>0\) such that \(\tilde{A}\lesseqgtr \underline{A}^1 \Leftrightarrow F^0(\tilde{A}) \gtreqless \alpha \tilde{A}, \forall \tilde{A}\). \(\square \)

As will become clear, this proposition indicates that if the creditor were allowed to postpone the firm’s repayment once, the creditor would do so if and only if the firm’s asset at the point of that decision is below some threshold. We will use the existence of this threshold in models with maturity extension.

2.4 Model II: finite postponements without resetting

In this version of the model, the creditor has an option to extend the maturity date of the debt if the firm defaults. When the firm does not repay the debt at the maturity date, the creditor compares the debt value after such maturity extension is given and the immediate payoff of forcing bankruptcy. If the former is higher, the creditor extends the debt maturity by another \(\Delta \) years. After \(\Delta \) years, the same situation arises and this process can be repeated until the creditor extends the firm’s repayment N times in total, where N is an exogenous bound on the number of times the creditor can postpone the firm’s repayment.

Let \(F^N(A)\) and \(S^N(A)\) be the debt and stock values when the current level of the firm asset is A, the time to maturity is \(\Delta \) years, and the number of remaining postponement options is N. If the firm defaults with asset level \(\tilde{A}\) and if \(N\ge 1\), the creditor receives \(\min (f, \alpha \tilde{A})\) by forcing bankruptcy or \(F^{N-1}(\tilde{A})\) by extending the maturity. So the payoff to the creditor is whichever is larger. The default threshold, denoted \(\bar{A}^N\), is defined in a similar manner to (2) of Model I, namely by \(S^{N}(\bar{A}^{N})-(f-F^{N}(\bar{A}^{N}))=0\). When \(N=0\), this model reduces to Model I. Given \(F^0(\cdot ), S^0(\cdot )\), and \(\bar{A}^0\) defined in Model I, we inductively define the system of integral equations for \(N\ge 1\):

$$\begin{aligned} F^N(A)= & {} e^{-r\Delta } E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^N\}}f+\mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}<\bar{A}^N\}}\max \left( \alpha \tilde{A}, F^{N-1}(\tilde{A})\right) \right] , \quad \forall A>0, \end{aligned}$$
(8)
$$\begin{aligned} S^N(A)= & {} e^{-r\Delta } E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^N\}}(S^N(\tilde{A})-(f-F^N(\tilde{A})))\right. \nonumber \\&+\left. \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}<\bar{A}^N\}}{} \mathbf{1}_{\{\alpha \tilde{A}<F^{N-1}(\tilde{A})\}}S^{N-1}(\tilde{A}))\right] , \quad \forall A>0, \end{aligned}$$
(9)
$$\begin{aligned}&F^N(\bar{A}^N)+S^N(\bar{A}^N)=f. \end{aligned}$$
(10)

Being analogous to (3)–(4) of Model I, Eq. (8) and (9) imply that both the debt and stock values are the discounted expected future payoffs. Equation (10) is the re-statement of the definition of the default threshold.

Given \(\underline{A}^1\) obtained in Proposition 2.2, we can show the following proposition.

Proposition 2.3

Suppose that parameters are such that \(\bar{A}^0\le \underline{A}^1\) holds. Then for each N, a solution \((F^N(\cdot ), S^N(\cdot ), \bar{A}^N)\) to (8)–(10) exists, and it satisfies:

  1. (i)

    \(\alpha A<F^N(A)+S^N(A)<A, \forall A>0\),

  2. (ii)

    \(\alpha \bar{A}^N<f<\bar{A}^N\),

  3. (iii)

    \(F^N(\cdot )+S^N(\cdot )\) is strictly increasing, and

  4. (iv)

    the creditor always chooses to exercise the maturity extension option whenever possible.

Moreover, in this solution, the higher N is, the less likely is the next default;

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{A}^0>\bar{A}^1>\cdots >\bar{A}^N, \end{aligned}$$
(11)

and both the debt and stock values are increasing in N; that is, for all \(A>0\),

$$\begin{aligned}&F^0(A)<F^1(A)<\cdots <F^N(A), \,\text {and} \end{aligned}$$
(12)
$$\begin{aligned}&S^0(A)<S^1(A)<\cdots <S^N(A). \end{aligned}$$
(13)

\(\square \)

Proof is done inductively, using the result of Model I as the terminal condition.

Consider the \(N=1\) case and suppose that the firm defaults for the first time with asset value \(\tilde{A}\). The creditor compares the liquidation value \(\alpha \tilde{A}\) with the new debt value that it can get by postponing the firm’s repayment once and for all, namely \(F^0(\tilde{A})\). Proposition 2.2 implies that the creditor chooses to postpone if and only if the asset value is lower than \(\underline{A}^1\), the level we call the postponement threshold. Notice that how likely it is that the firm will be able to repay does not matter much to this decision of the creditor. It is when the firm’s asset level is sufficiently low that the creditor puts more value on a small chance of the firm recovering from distress than on the immediate cash from liquidating the firm.

We denote the postponement threshold in general as \(\underline{A}^N, N \in \mathbb {N}\). We have not been able to show analytically the existence of such threshold for general N. However, we carried out computation with various parameter values and always found a unique threshold. If such a threshold exists, the postponement-triggering condition in (9), namely \(\alpha \tilde{A}<F^{N-1}(\tilde{A})\), is written as \(\tilde{A}<\underline{A}^N\), and the integral equations are re-written accordingly. That is, (9) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} S^N(A)= & {} e^{-r\Delta } E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^N\}}\left( S^N(\tilde{A})-\left( f-F^N(\tilde{A})\right) \right) \right. \\&+\left. \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}<\bar{A}^N\}}{} \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}<\underline{A}^N\}}S^{N-1}(\tilde{A}))\right] , \quad \forall A>0. \end{aligned}$$

2.5 Model III: finite postponements with resetting

In this version of the model, N is an exogenous bound on the number of maturity extensions that the creditor can make consecutively. As was the case with Model II, if the firm defaults and the creditor extends the date of the debt maturity N times in a row, then at the next date of maturity, the creditor can no longer extend the maturity. However, in this version, it is assumed that once the firm repays its debt, the remaining number of possible maturity extensions is reset to N again.

Let M \((0\le M \le N)\) be the remaining number of successive extensions allowed. Let \(F^{N,M}(A)\) and \(S^{N,M}(A)\) denote the debt and stock values when the current asset level of the firm is A and the time to maturity is \(\Delta \) years. Denote the default threshold by \(\bar{A}^{R,N}\), where R stands for ‘reset’. The threshold is defined, as in (2), by \(S^{N,N}(\bar{A}^{R,N})-(f-F^{N,N}(\bar{A}^{R,N}))=0\). As is understood in (15) below, the default threshold does not depend on M because once the firm repays, M is reset to N, and hence only \(S^{N,N}\) and \(F^{N,N}\) matter to refinancing. In the event of default, the creditor exercises its maturity extension option if and only if \(F^{N,M-1}(\tilde{A})>\alpha \tilde{A}\). The default threshold and the security prices should satisfy the following system of integral equations: \(\forall A>0\),

$$\begin{aligned}&F^{N,M}(A)=\left\{ \begin{array}{lll} e^{-r\Delta }E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^{R,N}\}}f+\mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}<\bar{A}^{R,N}\}}\alpha \tilde{A}\right] &{}\quad \text {if}&{}M=0\\ e^{-r\Delta }E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^{R,N}\}}f+\mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}<\bar{A}^{R,N}\}}\max (\alpha \tilde{A}, F^{N,M-1}(\tilde{A}))\right] &{}\quad \text {if}&{}M\ge 1 \end{array}\right. , \end{aligned}$$
(14)
$$\begin{aligned}&S^{N,M}(A)=\left\{ \begin{array}{lll} e^{-r\Delta }E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^{R,N}\}}(S^{N,N}(\tilde{A})-(f-F^{N,N}(\tilde{A})))\right] &{}\quad \text {if}&{}M=0\\ \begin{array}{l}e^{-r\Delta }E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^{R,N}\}}(S^{N,N}(\tilde{A})-(f-F^{N,N}(\tilde{A})))\right. \\ \quad +\left. \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}<\bar{A}^{R,N}\}}{} \mathbf{1}_{\{\alpha \tilde{A}<F^{N,M-1}(\tilde{A})\}} S^{N,M-1}(\tilde{A}))\right] \end{array}&\quad \text {if}&M\ge 1 \end{array}\right. \end{aligned}$$
(15)
$$\begin{aligned}&F^{N,N}(\bar{A}^{R,N})+S^{N,N}(\bar{A}^{R,N})7=f. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Proposition 2.4

Suppose that parameters are such that \(\bar{A}^0\le \underline{A}^1\). Then for each N, there exist \(\{F^{N,M}(\cdot ), S^{N,M}(\cdot )\}_{M=0,1,\ldots ,N}\) and \(\bar{A}^{R,N}\) that are a solution to (14)–(16), and such that

  1. (i)

    \(\alpha A<F^{N,M}(A)+S^{N,M}(A)<A,\;\; \forall A>0, \forall M=0, 1, \ldots , N\),

  2. (ii)

    \(\alpha \bar{A}^{R,N}<f<\bar{A}^{R,N}<\bar{A}^0\),

  3. (iii)

    \(F^{N,M}(\cdot )+S^{N,M}(\cdot )\) is strictly increasing, and

  4. (iv)

    the creditor always chooses to exercise the maturity extension option whenever possible.

Moreover, both the debt and stock values are increasing in M: that is, for all \(A>0\),

$$\begin{aligned}&F^{N,0}(A)<F^{N,1}(A)<\cdots <F^{N,N}(A), \quad \text {and} \end{aligned}$$
(17)
$$\begin{aligned}&S^{N,0}(A)<S^{N,1}(A)<\cdots <S^{N,N}(A). \end{aligned}$$
(18)

\(\square \)

Although the change from Model II to Model III is seemingly minor, the proof approach is very different from that of Proposition 2.3. This is because for given N, the \(2(1+N)\) functions \(\{F^{N,M}(\cdot ), S^{N,M}(\cdot )\}_{M=0,1,\ldots , N}\) are dependent on one another, so their existence must be established simultaneously, not inductively. Consequently, while properties (i)–(iv) of Proposition 2.3 are carried over to Model III, the monotonicity in terms of N, namely (11)–(13), is not. Inequalities (17)–(18) represent monotonicity in terms of the remaining number of postponements, M, for a fixed N.

2.6 Model IV: unlimited postponements

Lastly, assume that the creditor’s option to postpone the firm’s repayment in the event of default is unlimited. This corresponds to \(N=\infty \) in Models II and III. Therefore, by the analogous logic, the default threshold, denoted \(\bar{A}^{\infty }\), and security prices, denoted \(F^{\infty }(\cdot )\) and \(S^{\infty }(\cdot )\), satisfy the following system of integral equations:

$$\begin{aligned} F^{\infty }(A)= & {} e^{-r\Delta }E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^ {\infty }\}}f+\mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}<\bar{A}^{\infty }\}}\max (\alpha \tilde{A},F^{\infty }(\tilde{A}))\right] , \quad \forall A>0\qquad \quad \end{aligned}$$
(19)
$$\begin{aligned} S^{\infty }(A)= & {} e^{-r\Delta }E_{\tilde{A}|A}\left[ \mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}\ge \bar{A}^{\infty }\}}(S^{\infty }(\tilde{A})-(f-F^{\infty }(\tilde{A})))\right. \nonumber \\&\left. +\mathbf{1}_{\{\tilde{A}<\bar{A}^{\infty }\}}{} \mathbf{1}_{\{\alpha \tilde{A} <F^{\infty }(\tilde{A})\}}S^{\infty }(\tilde{A})\right] , \quad \forall A>0, \end{aligned}$$
(20)
$$\begin{aligned}&S^{\infty }(\bar{A}^{\infty }) -(f - F^{\infty }(\bar{A}^{\infty }))=0. \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Suppose that the assumption of Propositions 2.3 and 2.4 holds. Proposition 2.3 then implies that as N goes to infinity, \(\bar{A}^N\) converges to some limit \(\bar{A}^{\infty }\ge f\). Also, Proposition 2.3 [(i), (12) and (13)] implies that the debt and stock values also converge to some \(F^{\infty }(\cdot )\) and \(S^{\infty }(\cdot )\). What happens in the limit is shown by the following proposition and it is somewhat intuitive.

Proposition 2.5

Suppose \(\bar{A}^0<\underline{A}^1\). Then a solution \((F^{\infty }(\cdot ), S^{\infty }(\cdot ), \bar{A}^{\infty })\) to (19)–(21) exists, and it satisfies \(\bar{A}^{\infty }=f\), and \(F^{\infty }(A)+S^{\infty }(A)=A\) for all A. Moreover, the creditor always chooses postponement whenever default occurs. \(\square \)

That is, if parameters imply \(\bar{A}^0<\underline{A}^1\), which typically is the case when \(\alpha \) is small, the creditor always postpones the firm’s repayment following its default and hence bankruptcy never happens. As Proposition 2.5 shows, in this case the default threshold coincides with the face value of the debt f and the sum of the debt and stock values is equal to the asset value itself, which is the case with the Merton model. However, Model IV still differs from the Merton model even if the latter is augmented by the same bankruptcy cost. When the asset value is below f, the payoff to the stockholder is zero in the Merton model but it is not in our model because the postponement option is exercised and the firm continues.

The proposition predicts that for some \(\alpha \) (e.g. small \(\alpha \) due to very firm-specific asset), default never leads to bankruptcy, so the size of \(\alpha \) does not affect the default threshold nor the security values. In reality, the presence of asymmetric information between the firm and the creditor is likely to make the creditor force bankruptcy after the firm defaults a finite number of times. Nevertheless, this endogenously bankruptcy-free situation is theoretically interesting.

Table 1 Threshold values of the firm asset

3 Numerical analysis

3.1 Probabilities and values

In this section, we present numerical results. Throughout this section, parameter values we use are \(f=1, r=0.01, \sigma =0.2\) and \(\Delta =1\). Table 1 shows the default and postponement thresholds for each of the four cases: Model I (\(N=0\)), Model II (\(N=1\) without resetting), Model III (\(N=1\) with resetting) and Model IV (\(N=\infty \)). The tables at the top and at the bottom correspond to \(\alpha =0.8\) and \(\alpha =0.5\), respectively. Table 2 shows the 1-year default probability of an outstanding debt and the probabilities of bankruptcy within 1, 2, 5 and 10 years when the current asset level is \(A_0=1, 1.5\) and 2. All the probabilities are under the risk-neutral probability measure.Footnote 14 Figures 1 and 2 show the debt and stock values as a function of the current level of the firm asset for each of the four versions of our model and also for the “augmented” Merton model, the Merton model to which bankruptcy cost is added for comparison.

Table 2 Default/bankruptcy probabilities
Fig. 1
figure 1

Debt values. (i) \(\alpha =0.8\) (top) and (ii) \(\alpha =0.5\) (bottom) The figures give the debt values for \(\alpha =0.8\) and 0.5 as a function of the current asset level

Fig. 2
figure 2

Stock values. (i) \(\alpha =0.8\) (top) and (ii) \(\alpha =0.5\) (bottom) The figures give the stock values for \(\alpha =0.8\) and 0.5 as a function of the current asset level

First we look at Model I. As is seen in Table 1, the default threshold, below which the stockholders choose not to repay debt, depends upon the size of \(\alpha \), showing high values for small \(\alpha \). The reason is that when the firm repays debt partly by issuing a new debt, the value of this new debt is low if \(\alpha \) is small. Therefore, the asset value itself must be higher to successfully raise the funds that are needed for repayment. Next, comparing Fig. 1(i) and (ii) indicates that the debt value is lower when \(\alpha \) is low. Similarly, comparing Fig. 2(i) and (ii) indicates that the stock value is also lower when \(\alpha \) is low. The reason for the lower debt value is straightforward; low \(\alpha \) means low bankruptcy/liquidation value and hence low debt value. On the other hand, the bankruptcy/liquidation value itself does not matter to the stockholders so the reason for the lower stock value is not so obvious. The reason is that low \(\alpha \) leads to high default threshold, which in turn makes future bankruptcy more likely. In comparison with the Merton model, our \(N=0\) model shows lower stock values as are seen in Fig. 2(i)–(ii). The Merton model, while we augment it with the same bankruptcy cost, does not involve refinancing so the default threshold still remains f. In contrast, the default threshold in our model exceeds f and hence default/bankruptcy becomes more likely, which in turn lowers the stock value compared with the Merton model.

Next we look into Model II (\(N=1\)). As is seen by comparing Models I and II in Table 2(i) and Fig. 1(i) and 2(i), the effect of allowing for maturity extension on debt/stock values and default/bankruptcy probabilities is almost zero when the asset recovery rate is high (\(\alpha =0.8\)). If \(\alpha \) is high, liquidation on default is not so costly and is attractive most of the time. Table 1(i) indicates that the creditor chooses to exercise the postponement option only when the firm’s asset value is extremely low. In such situations, however, the debt and stock values are very low anyway. In contrast, when \(\alpha \) is low, introducing the postponement option has a large impact. Figures 1(ii) and 2(ii) show that the debt and stock values of Model II are significantly higher than those of Model I. Also, Table 2(ii) shows that for Model II, the probabilities of bankruptcy within 1, 2, 5 and 10 years are lower than for Model I. As is seen in Table 1(ii), when \(\alpha \) is as low as 0.5, the postponement threshold is higher than the default threshold. Therefore, whenever default occurs, the creditor routinely postpones the repayment, which is the case described in Proposition 2.3. This simply makes the 1-year bankruptcy probability zero. The mechanism for the reduction of the 2-year bankruptcy probability is more complex; it is not only because the probability of the first-year bankruptcy is zero but also because the postponement option has made the default threshold lower. The introduction of postponement into the model lowers future bankruptcy risk and raises the present debt and stock values. Since our model assumes refinancing that uses these debt and stock, the increase of their values makes the default risk (i.e., the default threshold) go down.Footnote 15 If the firm does not default for the first year, then the creditor keeps the postponement option for the second year. In this way, the second-year bankruptcy probability further goes down.

Now we examine Model III (\(N=1\)) in comparison with Model II (\(N=1\)) when \(\alpha =0.5\), to see the impact of the reset assumption. First, Table 1(ii) shows a lower default threshold for Model III, and correspondingly, Table 2(ii) shows a smaller 1-year default probability for Model III. When the present asset values are 1, 1.5 and 2, the 1-year default probabilities for Model II are 0.992, 0.640 and 0.141, respectively, while they are 0.987, 0.572 and 0.105 for Model III. The reset assumption directly lowers future bankruptcy risk, raises the debt and stock values, making refinancing easier, and lowers the default threshold. Moreover, 2-year bankruptcy probabilities of the model with reset, (0.939, 0.446, 0.072) are lower than those of the model without it (0.967, 0.545, 0.108). This is not only because the 1-year default risk is lower in the former model, but also because of the following reason. Once the creditor exercises the postponement option in the \(N=1\) model without reset, then it becomes the \(N=0\) model, and the default threshold increases from \(\bar{A}^1\) to \(\bar{A}^0\). On the other hand, as we saw in Proposition 2.4, in the model with resetting, even if the creditor exercises the postponement option, the default threshold does not change. So the probability of bankruptcy conditional on one default in the past is lower in the model with resetting. At first look, one may expect that whether there is resetting or not does not matter much to short-term risk of default or bankruptcy. The fact is that the reduction in the long-term bankruptcy risk by reset assumption raises the present stock value, making refinancing easier, and in turn reduces the short-term default/bankruptcy risk.

The above effect is even bigger for larger N. In the extreme case of \(N=\infty \) and \(\alpha =0.5\), that is the endogenously bankruptcy-free case of Proposition 2.5, the bankruptcy probability is zero and debt/stock values are even higher. Also, the default threshold coincides with the principal of the debt. These facts make the model resemble the Merton model at high asset values. At a low asset level, our \(N=\infty \) model gives a higher stock value than Merton because the payoff to the stock holder when the asset value is below the debt principal is zero in the Merton model but not zero in our model.

3.2 Asset volatility and stock/debt values

In this subsection, we investigate the relation between the volatility of the firm asset, \(\sigma \), and the debt and stock values. First we look at the stock value. In the standard Merton model, the stock price is the Black-Scholes price of an European call option for which the underlying asset is the firm asset. Therefore, high asset volatility yields high stock price. In particular, when the asset value is around the at-the-money level, high volatility leads to high stock value because the potential gain to stockholders becomes large while the potential loss is bounded. When the asset level is deep-in-the-money, the increase in the asset volatility affects the stockholders’ potential gains and losses in a similar way, leading to very little effect on the stock value.

The effect of change in \(\sigma \) on the stock value in our model is presented in Fig. 3 (top). In this figure, the vertical axis is the partial derivative of the stock value with respect to \(\sigma \) evaluated at \(\sigma =0.2\), and the horizontal axis is the current level of the firm asset.Footnote 16 Because qualitative features are similar across Models I-III, we focus on Model I. In the low asset region, the derivative is always positive, indicating that the increase in \(\sigma \) leads to the increase in the stock value. That is, when the firm asset level is relatively low, the aforementioned positive effect of volatility on the stock value in the standard Merton model is also present in our model of refinancing. The effect is larger due to the refinancing multiplier between the stock value and the default probability.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Partial derivative of stock and debt values with respect to \(\sigma \) Numerical first-derivatives of the stock (top) and debt (bottom) values with respect to \(\sigma \) evaluated at \(\sigma =0.2\). The x-axis is the current asset value. (\(\alpha =0.5\))

In the high asset region, on the other hand, our model exhibits a negative effect of \(\sigma \) on the stock price, unlike the Merton model. This is because our model with refinancing is different from Merton in that the default threshold is no longer constant but depends on the magnitude of asset volatility. While the increase in the asset volatility has the direct positive effect on stock price that is present in the Merton model, it also lowers the debt value around the default threshold and hence increases the default threshold, which turns into a negative effect on the stock value. When the asset value is deep-in-the-money, the latter effect dominates the former, and thus high \(\sigma \) lowers the stock value.

Next we examine the relation between \(\sigma \) and the debt value. In the standard Merton model without bankruptcy cost, the debt price resembles the short-selling of the (Black-Scholes) European put option for which the underlying asset is the firm asset. Therefore, in the standard Merton model, high asset volatility always yields low debt price. With the presence of bankruptcy cost, however, that is not always the case. In particular, in the Merton model augmented with bankruptcy cost \(\alpha <1\), one can show that there is a cutoff asset level \(\hat{A}\) such that \(\partial F(A)/\partial \sigma >(<)0\) if \(A<(>)\hat{A}\). That is, if the current asset level is sufficiently low, high volatility yields high debt value. This is due to the discontinuity that \(\alpha \) causes. When the asset level is in the low region so the costly bankruptcy is likely, the benefit of high volatility is larger than the downside of high volatility because high volatility means a good chance of avoiding costly bankruptcy. This is a direct channel through which the increase in \(\sigma \) has a positive effect on the debt value for the low asset region.

In the model with refinancing (Model I), there is also a rather indirect channel through which higher volatility can lead to higher debt value. As we saw, higher volatility leads to higher stock value when the asset level is relatively low. In the model with refinancing, higher stock value implies a better chance of successful refinancing, lowering the default probability and increasing the debt value. Moreover, because the positive effect of high volatility on the stock value in the model of refinancing is even larger when there is a possibility of maturity extension, so is its indirect impact on the debt value [see Model II and III in Fig. 3 (bottom)].

One common statement in the field of corporate finance is that stockholders are risk-takers as residual claimants while debt holders avert risk and prefer safe business. This is not necessarily the case in models with bankruptcy cost and refinancing. When the asset value is high, stockholders may prefer lower business risk to avoid bad refinancing conditions. When the asset value is relatively low, creditors may prefer higher business risk because that raises the stock value, makes successful refinancing more likely, and lowers the default/bankruptcy probability.

4 Conclusion

In this article we study a structural model of corporate credit risk in which the debt repayment is made by refinancing. We further extend the model by incorporating the creditor’s option to extend the date of debt maturity, partly motivated by the observation that under Japan’s main creditor system, the main creditor of a firm often postpones the firm’s repayment on default. In our refinancing model without such a postponement option, the lower asset recovery rate \(\alpha \) leads to higher bankruptcy risk and lower debt/stock values. While introducing the creditor’s postponement option has a very limited effect when \(\alpha \) is high, it reduces bankruptcy risk and raises the debt/stock values significantly when \(\alpha \) is low.

Our model sheds light on some easily overlooked channels through which the possibility of flexible maturity extension affects the default and bankruptcy probabilities of a firm. One such channel is a multiplier effect of refinancing on default probabilities; an initial reduction of bankruptcy risk by the possibility of flexible maturity extension raises debt/stock prices, facilitates refinancing, and further pushes down the default/bankruptcy risk. Another channel is the effect of reduction in the long-run bankruptcy risk on the short-run bankruptcy risk. This effect was found in the comparison of Models II and III. That is, an arrangement that seemingly decreases only the long-run risk can also lower the short-run risk because the former affects the current security prices, which matter to the latter in the process of refinancing.

In this article we assume that the amount of debt is exogenously fixed. In a more realistic environment, it should be the decision of a firm that solves the optimal capital structure problem facing advantages of debt (e.g. tax benefit) and disadvantages of debt (e.g. cost of bankruptcy). Whether our existence proof can be extended to such an environment is not known. Nevertheless, our simple framework serves a basis for the argument that both refinancing and renegotiation such as maturity extension are important to corporate risk analysis.