Skip to main content
Log in

The jobs at risk from globalization: the French case

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article analyzes the effect of outward foreign direct investment (FDI) on the workforce composition in French firms. We use a detailed employer-employee database constructed with four comprehensive datasets of French manufacturing firms over the period 2002–2007, in order to analyze changes in the workforce composition in terms of skills and tasks. To deal with endogeneity issues, we propose an IV strategy where the level of infrastructure and GDP per capita in the host countries are used as instruments. The fixed effect results show that FDI to low-income countries raises significantly the share of executives and reduces the share of blue-collar workers in company workforces in France. Outward FDI to high-income countries affects negatively the share of workers performing non-routine manual tasks. When controlling for endogeneity, the IV results further show an overall positive effect of offshoring for employees performing interactive and analytical tasks, such as engineers and managers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Antràs (2003) develops a framework in which there are two inputs, one controlled by the final-goods producer, the other by the supplier. Ownership is favored concerning the party whose investment contributes most to the value of the relationship. If the final-good is capital intensive, the final producer will prefer vertical integration in capital-intensive processes and arm’s length transaction in labor intensive processes.

  2. Grossman and Helpman (2002) identify different types of costs and gains depending on the mode of integration. On the one hand, a vertically integrated firm may face higher production costs, because such a firm has many divisions to manage, and because the organization does not benefit from the learning that comes with specializing in a single activity. On the other hand, arm’s length transaction costs stem from incomplete contracts and the search for partners.

  3. Many countries and particularly France lack information on the task content of occupations. French studies often use Robert Reich’s classification that defines occupation categories according to the type of work performed: persons with routine occupations, symbol managers, officials and farmers. The Reich classification shows that routine occupations are more sensitive to offshoring than are farmers or officials (Allain et al. 2011). Becker et al. (2013) and Spitz-Oener (2006) used a task classification based on German data.

  4. A group is composed of an independent parent company and all other entities controlled by the parent company. We include information at the group level because we argue that FDI could not only impact employment inside the investing firm but also inside all other firms belonging to the same business group.

  5. The underlying idea is that when industries and occupations are highly concentrated, tasks performed in these occupations may a priori be performed remotely from a single work site. They add information on occupational task characteristics to complement their analysis.

  6. Vertical offshoring often takes place in low-income countries, whereas horizontal FDI is generally realized in high-income countries. Statistics suggest that FDI to low-income countries is expanding rapidly with the development of emerging economies. In 2013, FDI flows to all major developing regions accounted for 54 % of global inflows (UNCTAD 2013).

  7. This idea is close to the productivity effect developed in Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (2008).

  8. The access to the data was carried through the CASD dedicated to researchers authorized by the French “Comité du secret statistique”.

  9. We do not take into account information after 2007 because it could capture the labor market effect of the recent economic crisis. We do not use the data before 2002 because the occupational categories we use to define the groups of occupations (see below) changed that year.

  10. These include a group of skilled/unskilled workers, a group of managers and blue-collar workers, and a group of production/non- production workers for instance. A detailed description of occupational groups is given in the following sections.

  11. We only keep firms for which at least 90 % of their workforce composition is referenced.

  12. As information on the task content of an occupation is very difficult to obtain, even more so because the given data is not available in every country, we use the US database of the Department of Labor’s Occupational Information Network (ONET). We assume that the task content of occupations is identical in the United States and in France, so we can use the ONET classification to analyze the job content of French occupations.

  13. For occupations where it was difficult to sample workers, experts were identified and sampled from professional and/or trade association membership lists to answer to the questionnaire.

  14. Three examples on the level of tasks are given at rank 2, 4 and 6 to help respondent answering to the question on the level of tasks. For instance, to the question ’what level of getting information is needed to perform the current job’, a level of 2 corresponds to follow a standard blueprint, the level of 4 corresponds to review a budget and the level of 6 corresponds to study international tax laws. The index of getting information corresponds to the average level of all respondents in a given occupation.

  15. Table 12 in “Appendix 1” gives examples of occupations in the metal industry, ranging from engineer to assembler. This table shows that engineers have a higher index of non-routine tasks and assemblers a higher index than manual tasks.

  16. However, because the ONET database does not provide information on workers, we are unable to follow the evolution of task requirements within a given occupation. Therefore, our empirical estimations only analyze inter-occupational change by assuming that there are no intra-occupation variations. This limitation can be avoided by using data that provides for the evolution of each task within an occupation, over time. This is the case with the British Skills Survey and with the German Labor Workforce Survey, BIBB/AB.

  17. Details on the importance of tasks performed within occupations are given in “Appendix 1”.

  18. White-collar workers are composed of managers, accountants or sales representatives.

  19. A small number of these firms are perfect joint ventures, i.e. two mother companies hold exactly 50 % each of the subsidiary’s voting stock. Thus, we are unable to identify a unique parent company. In order to reconstruct the group perimeter by allocating one parent company to each legal entity, we decided to drop information about joint ventures. In 2007, there were 15,006 joint ventures, representing 6 % of our sample.

  20. High-income countries are countries listed as high-income OECD members countries by the World Bank, excluding the Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Poland, the Czech Republic and Estonia that are referenced in the group of East European countries. East European countries are composed of countries which joined the European Union after 2004; European countries include countries which joined the EU before 2004; and low-income countries are composed of other Asian, African and South American countries.

  21. The Hausman test fails to reject the hypothesis of random attrition. Still, we find similar results with the unbalanced panel data and our principal conclusions are not altered.

  22. Foreign investment may be undertaken by constructing new operational facilities from the ground up (greenfield or brownfield investment), or without actually creating a new subsidiary (merger and acquisition).

  23. We have tested the impact of a change in the share of voting stocks held in a foreign subsidiary on the share of employment in the investing firm. Results reveal that increases in the share of voting stock in a firm’s subsidiary raises significantly the share of executives and reduces the share of blue-collar workers. Results are available in the online appendix of the authors’ website.

  24. For example, a firm having 2 subsidiaries controlled at 40 and 100 % has a measure \(\kappa \) equals to 1.4.

  25. A firm has the possibility to veto certain decisions at general meetings of shareholders when the firm owns more than 33 % of the foreign subsidiary.

  26. However, we report results by including wages in “Appendix 2”, and do not alter our conclusions.

  27. We have used different proxies for technological change, such as investment in R&D, total factor productivity and software investment. Whatever the variable retained, our results are not altered. However, we prefer the measure of proximity to the technology frontier for several reasons. First, the software investment variable is not referenced for all firms. Second the R&D variable is built from the EAE survey that accounts for fixed R&D, i.e., R&D accounted as capital expenditure in the balance-sheet rather than as an expense of research and development.

  28. This result holds in a world with no outsourcing and if the final good is intensive in inputs brought by the final-good producer.

  29. All French subsidiaries controlled by another company are considered as French subsidiary.

  30. The first two are composed of production workers. On the one hand, we define skilled production workers (i.e., engineers, technicians, foremen, skilled blue-collar workers), and on the other hand unskilled production workers (i.e., unskilled blue-collar workers). The last two are composed of non-production workers. The first are skilled (administrative managers and administrative intermediate professions, mostly composed of skilled secretaries) and the second are unskilled, mostly made up of administrative employees (i.e., receptionists, unskilled secretaries and typists).

  31. Biscourp and Kramarz (2007) found a negative effect of imports of intermediate inputs on the share of unskilled production workers, while Head and Ries (2002) found a positive effect of increasing employment in low-wage subsidiaries on the share of skilled non-production workers.

  32. For instance, the coefficient associated with technicians is positive while the coefficient associated with foremen is negative, while there are both captured in the group of intermediate occupations.

  33. We split the data into the three main sectors composing our sample. Results are reported in “Appendix 5”.

  34. See Table 22 in “Appendix 5”.

  35. Our analysis is conducted at the firm level, rather than at the plant level, so we do not account for the replication of establishments in other countries.

  36. Some strategies may be linked to reasons of market access: for example, in Germany, the United Kingdom and the Benelux countries. Other FDI strategies may be carried out to take advantage of factor cost differentials: for example, in Portugal, Spain and Ireland.

  37. In France, for example, these assembly phases are concentrated in the North Eastern region, to be close to the EU market. We have run the equation per region and the region that leads these results are Alsace and Lorraine, which are two regions close to the German border. Trade in parts and components produced in the CEEC-10 for export to the OECD countries now accounts for approximately 30 % of the OECD’s total trade (Yeats 1998).

  38. These statistics are calculated from Comext, Eurostat sources stemming from aggregate input–output tables in national accounts. Intermediate goods are identified in three broad categories with the BEC classification (BEC 420, BEC 530, BEC 220).

  39. We build the measure described in Eq. 2 by summing the number of subsidiaries of the business group. We attribute this measure to each firm belonging to the same group. All other variables are determined at the firm level. For simplicity, we only retained firms in our sample that did not change their parent company during the whole period of observation.

  40. The inclusion of firm fixed effects considerably reduces the bias, since only 1138 firms observed during the period changed nationality. The inclusion of the firm’s nationality does not alter the conclusions (see Tables 14, 15 in “Appendix 2”).

  41. Correspondence tables exist between NC8 classification and the CPA classification (classification of products by activity) for which each product is associated to a single activity (NACE code).

  42. Other studies, including Becker et al. (2013), Hansson (2005) and Head and Ries (2002) approximated transfers within multinationals by a multinational company’s share of employment by subsidiaries in total employment.

  43. We have assumed clustered errors, i.e., that observations for firms in two different time periods are correlated, but not observations between different firms. Hence, in order to relax the assumption that the correlation of a firm’s observations within a group is constant, we run a feasible, efficient two-step GMM, as described in Baum et al. (2002, 2007).

  44. Over-identification tests are based on the assumption that one of the instruments is valid. We have therefore decided to report the IV results in a just-identified equation, by using GDP per capita on the one hand, and the level of infrastructure on the other hand. The results are reported in the online appendix and depict similar findings. In both cases the instruments are sufficiently strong. We prefer to report the over-identified results to prove the validity of our instruments.

  45. We use the Kleibergen–Paap rk statistic F statistic, as we do not assume i.i.d errors.

  46. In each case, the F statistic also exceeds the conventional ’rule of thumb’ of the minimum standard of power of F=10. However, as we have multiple endogenous variables, this indicator may not be sufficiently informative (Baum et al. 2002). In this respect, the use of the Shea Partial R2 is preferable, as it accounts for the inter-correlations among the instruments. The Shea measure is always close to the partial R2. We therefore conclude that our instruments are relevant.

  47. We are very grateful to Professor Kea Tijdens for having allowed us to use this database.

  48. A blocking minority represents one quarter or one third of the shares plus one share, depending on the country and the legal form of the company.

  49. This corresponds to the gross value of shares owned in the foreign subsidiary, in thousands of euros. This measure corresponds to a book value and does not reflect the market value of the firm. The amount is identified in euros. Therefore, we deflate this nominal value by using the CPI base 2005, provided by INSEE

  50. We highlight a positive coefficient associated with change in a firm’s nationality on the share of executives. We interpret the positive coefficient as a positive correlation between high-skilled firms and foreign-acquisition, reflecting the fact that foreign-owned firms are on average more skills-intensive than French-owned firms. Theories of ownership have shown that acquisition can result in a reduction of employment, because takeovers are a good way for shareholders to get rid of non-value-maximizing managers (Huttunen 2007). However, changes in employment are likely to take time, because of attendant adjustment costs.

References

  • Abraham, F., Konings, J., & Slootmaekers, V. (2010). FDI spillovers, firm heterogeneity and degree of ownership: Evidence from Chinese manufacturing. (Technical Report 243360, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven).

  • Acemoglu, D., & Autor, D. (2011). Chapter 12 of skills, tasks and technologies: Implications for employment and earnings, edited by O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, Volume 4 of Handbook of labor economics (pp. 1043–1171). Elsevier.

  • Allain, B., Collobert, J., & Fraboul, S. (2011). Emplois exposés en Pays de la Loire: une nouvelle approche. Institute for statistics and economic studies (INSEE) 24.

  • Almeida, R. (2007). The labor market effects of foreign owned firms. Journal of International Economics, 72(1), 75–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderton, B., & Brenton, P. (1999). Outsourcing and low-skilled workers in the UK. Bulletin of Economic Research, 51(4), 267–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antràs, P. (2003). Firms, contracts, and trade structure. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1375–1418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antràs, P. (2005). Incomplete contracts and the product cycle. The American Economic Review, 95(4), 1054–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antràs, P., & Helpman, E. (2004). Global Sourcing. Journal of Political Economy, 112(3), 552–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D., Dorn, D., Hanson, G. H., & Song, J. (2013). Trade adjustment: Worker level evidence. (NBER working papers 19226, National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.)

  • Autor, D., Levy, F., & Murnane, R. (2003). The skill content of recent technological change: An empirical exploration. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1279–1333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barba Navaretti, G., & Castellani, D. (2004). Investments abroad and performance at home: Evidence from Italian multinationals. (CEPR discussion papers 4284, Center for Economic and Policy Research).

  • Barba Navaretti, G., Castellani, D., & Disdier, A.-C. (2010). How does investing in cheap labour countries affect performance at home? Firm-level evidence from France and Italy. Oxford Economic Papers, 62(2), 234–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baum, C., Schaffer, M., & Stillman, S. (2002). Instrumental variables and GMM: Estimation and testing. (Boston college working papers in economics 545, Boston College Department of Economics).

  • Baum, C., Schaffer, M., & Stillman, S. (2007). Enhanced routines for instrumental variables/GMM estimation and testing. (Boston college working papers in economics 667, Boston College Department of Economics).

  • Becker, S. O., & Muendler, M.-A. (2008). Job creation abroad and worker retention at home. In The analysis of firms and employees: Quantitative and qualitative approaches, NBER Chapters (pp. 309–344). National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.

  • Becker, S. O., & Muendler, M.-A. (2014). Trade and tasks: An exploration over three decades in Germany. (NBER working papers 20739, National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.)

  • Becker, S. O., Ekholm, K., & Muendler, M.-A. (2013). Offshoring and the onshore composition of tasks and skills. Journal of International Economics, 90(1), 91–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy-Quéré, A., Coupet, M., & Mayer, T. (2007). Institutional determinants of foreign direct investment. The World Economy, 30(5), 764–782.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berle, A., & Means, G. (1932). The modern corporation and private property (2nd edn). New York: Harcourt. Brace and World. 1967.

  • Bernard, A., Jensen, J. B. & Schott, P. (2009). Importers, exporters and multinationals: A portrait of firms in the US that trade goods. In Producer dynamics: New evidence from micro data (pp. 513–552). University of Chicago Press.

  • Bircan, C. (2011). Foreign direct investment and wages: Does the level of ownership matter?. (Technical Report 618).

  • Biscourp, P., & Kramarz, F. (2007). Employment, skill structure and international trade: Firm-level evidence for France. Journal of International Economics, 72(1), 22–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A. S., & Krueger, A. B. (2013). Alternative measures of offshorability: A survey approach. Journal of Labor Economics, 31(2 Part 2), S97–S128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A. S. (2009). How many US jobs might be offshorable? World Economics, 10(2), 41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blonigen, B. A., Fontagné, L., Sly, N. & Toubal, F. (2012). Cherries for sale: export networks and the incidence of cross-border M&A. (NBER working papers 18414, National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.)

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (2000). GMM estimation with persistent panel data: An application to production functions. Econometric Reviews, 19(3), 321–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brainard, S. L., & Riker, D. A. (1997). Are U.S. multinationals exporting U.S. Jobs? (NBER working papers 5958, National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.)

  • Brouthers, K. D., & Brouthers, L. E. (2001). Explaining the national cultural distance paradox. Journal of International Business Studies, 32(1), 177–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conconi, P., Sapir, A., & Zanardi, M. (2013). The internationalization process of firms: From exports to FDI. (CEPR discussion papers 9332, Center for Economic and Policy Research).

  • Crinò, R. (2009). Offshoring, multinationals and labour market: A review of the empirical literature. Journal of Economic Surveys, 23(2), 197–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crinò, R. (2010). Service offshoring and white-collar employment. The Review of Economic Studies, 77(2), 595–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cuyvers, L., Dumont, M., Rayp, G., & Stevens, K. (2005). Home employment effects of EU firms activities in Central and Eastern European Countries. Open Economies Review, 16(2), 153–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debaere, P., Hongshik, L., & Joonhyung, L. (2010). It matters where you go: Outward foreign direct investment and multinational employment growth at home. Journal of Development Economics, 91(2), 301–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H., & Lehn, K. (1985). The structure of corporate ownership: Causes and consequences. The Journal of Political Economy, 93(6), 1155–1177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, M. A., Foley, C. F., & Hines, J. R. (2009). Domestic effects of the foreign activities of US multinationals. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1(1), 181–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ebenstein, A., Harrison, A., McMillan, M., & Phillips, S. (2014). Estimating the impact of trade and offshoring on American workers using the current population surveys. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(4), 581–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edamura, K., Hering, L., Inui, T., & Poncet, S. (2011). The overseas subsidiary activities and their impact on the performance of Japanese parent firms. (Discussion papers 11069, Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI)).

  • Ekholm, K., & Hakkala, K. (2005). The effect of offshoring on labor demand: Evidence from Sweden. (Working paper series 654, Research Institute of Industrial Economics).

  • Falk, M., & Koebel, B. (2002). Outsourcing, imports and labour demand. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 104(4), 567–586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, M., & Wolfmayr, Y. (2008). The impact of outward FDI in Central and Eastern Europe on employment in the EU-15 countries. (FIW research reports series I-016, Austrian Institute of Economic Research).

  • Feenstra, R., & Hanson, G. (1996). Globalization, outsourcing and wage inequality. American Economic Review, 86(2), 240–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R., & Hanson, G. (1999). Producctivity measurement and the impact of trade and technology on wages: Estimates for the US, 1972–1990. Quaterly Journal of Economics, 3(114), 907–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R., & Hanson, G. H. (2005). Ownership and control in outsourcing to China: Estimating the property-rights theory of the firm. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 729–761.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fontagne, L., & Mayer, T. (2005). Determinants of location choices by multinational firms: A review of the current state of knowledge. Applied Economics Quarterly, 51(Suppl.), 9–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fontagné, L., & Toubal, F. (2010, 04). Investissement direct étranger et performances des entreprises. La documentation française, Conseil d’Analyse Economique, Direction de l’information légale et administrative.

  • Foster-McGregor, N., Stehrer, R., & de Vries, G. J. (2013). Offshoring and the skill structure of labour demand. Review of World Economics, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 149(4), 631–662.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gamberoni, E., Lanz, R., Piermartini, R. (2010). Timeliness and contract enforceability in intermediate goods trade. (Policy research working paper series 5482, The World Bank).

  • Gatignon, H., & Anderson, E. (1988). The multinational corporation’s degree of control over foreign subsidiaries: An empirical test of a transaction cost explanation. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 4(2), 305–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gazaniol, A. (2012). The location choices of multinational firms: The role of internationalization experience and group affiliation. (Technical Report 9018, Economics Papers from University Paris-Dauphine).

  • Glickman, N., & Woordward, D. (1989). New competitors: How foreign investors are changing the US economy. New York: Basik Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goos, M., Manning, A., & Salomons, A. (2009). Job polarization in Europe. The American Economic Review, 99(2), 58–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2002). Integration versus outsourcing in industry equilibrium. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 85–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2005). Outsourcing in a global economy. The Review of Economic Studies, 72(1), 135–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2008). Trading tasks: A simple theory of offshoring. American Economic Review, 98(5), 1978–1997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M. (2013). Heterogeneous workers and international trade. Review of World Economics, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 149(2), 211–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., Helpman, E., & Szeidl, A. (2006). Optimal integration strategies for the multinational firm. Journal of International Economics, 70(1), 216–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grover, A. (2008). Vertical FDI versus outsourcing: A welfare comparison from the perspective of the host country. (Technical Report c013009, DEGIT, Dynamics, Economic Growth, and International Trade).

  • Gryczka, M. (2010). Changing role of BRIC countries in technology-driven international division of labor. Business and Economic Horizons, 2(2), 89–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hakkala Nilsson, K., Heyman, F., & Sjöholm, F. (2014). Multinational firms, acquisitions and job tasks. European Economic Review, 66(C), 248–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansson, P. (2000). Relative demands for skilled in Swedish manufacturing: Technology or trade? Review of International Economics, 8(3), 533–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansson, P. (2005). Skill upgrading and production transfer within Swedish multinationals. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 107(4), 673–692.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayter, S. (2004). The social dimension of global production systems: A review of the issues. (ILO working papers 374997, International Labour Organization).

  • Head, K., & Ries, J. (2002). Offshore production and skill upgrading by Japanese manufacturing firms. Journal of International Economics, 58(1), 81–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., Melitz, M., & Yeaple, S. R. (2004). Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review, 94(1), 300–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hijzen, A., Görg, H., & Hine, R. C. (2005). International outsourcing and the skill structure of labour demand in the United Kingdom. The Economic Journal, 115(506), 860–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hijzen, A., Jean, S., & Mayer, T. (2011). The effects at home of initiating production abroad: Evidence from matched French firms. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 147(3), 457–483.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hummels, D., Jørgensen, R., Munch, J., & Xiang, C. (2011). The wage effects of offshoring: Evidence from Danish matched worker-firm data. (NBER working papers 17496, National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.)

  • Huttunen, K. (2007). The effect of foreign acquisition on employment and wages: Evidence from Finnish establishments. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(3), 497–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Javorcik, B. S., & Wei, S.-J. (2009). Corruption and cross-border investment in emerging markets: Firm-level evidence. Journal of International Money and Finance, 28(4), 605–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, J. B., & Kletzer, L. G. (2010, 09). Measuring tradable services and the task content of offshorable services jobs. In Labor in the New Economy, NBER Chapters (pp. 309–335). National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.

  • Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J.-E. (1977). The internationalization process of the firm—A model of knowledge development and increasing foreign market commitments. Journal of International Business Studies, 8(1), 23–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohler, W. (2003). The distributional effects of international fragmentation. German Economic Review, 4(1), 89–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konings, J., & Murphy, A. (2006). Do multinational enterprises relocate employment to low-wage regions? Evidence from European multinationals. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 142(2), 267–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (2008). Trade and wages, reconsidered. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 39(1), 103–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R. E. (2004). Home- and host-country effects of foreign direct investment. In Challenges to globalization: Analyzing the economics, NBER Chapters (pp. 333–382). National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.

  • Mansfield, E., & Romeo, A. (1980). Technology transfer to overseas subsidiaries by U.S.-based firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 95(4), 737–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen, J. R. (1995). The boundaries of multinational enterprises and the theory of international trade. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(2), 169–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martínez-Zarzoso, I., Voicu, A., & Vidovic, M. (2011). CEECs integration into regional and global production networks. (Center for european, governance and economic development research discussion papers 125, University of Goettingen, Department of Economics).

  • Melitz, M. J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695–1725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moati, P., & Mouhoud, E. M. (2005). Les nouvelles logiques de décomposition internationale des processus productifs. Revue d’économie politique, 115(5), 573–589.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moran, T. (2004). How does foreign direct investment affect host country development: Do we already know the answer? Using industry case studies to make reliable generalizations. The impact of foreign direct investment on development: New measures, new outcomes, new policy approaches. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

  • Moran, T. H. (2001). Parental supervision: The New Paradigm for Foreign Direct Investment and Development. Policy Analyses in International Economics no. 64. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

  • Morrison, C., & Siegel, D. (2001). The impacts of technology, trade and outsourcing on employment and labor composition. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 103(2), 241–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muendler, M.-A., & Becker, S. O. (2010). Margins of multinational labor substitution. American Economic Review, 100(5), 1999–2030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunnenkamp, P., & Andrés. M. S. (2013). Ownership choices of Indian direct investors: Do FDI determinants differ between joint ventures and wholly-owned subsidiaries?. (Kiel working papers 1841, Kiel Institute for the World Economy).

  • Oldenski, L. (2012). The task composition of offshoring by U.S. multinationals. Economie Internationale, 131, 5–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pietrzak, J., & Klug, M. (2007). Market entry strategies in Eastern Europe in the context of the European Union: An empirical research into german firms entering the polish market. Germany: Springer Science & Business Media.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramondo, N., Rappoport, V., & Ruhl, K. J. (2014). Horizontal vs. vertical FDI: Revisiting evidence from U.S. multinationals. (Working papers 11–12, New York University, Leonard N. Stern School of Business, Department of Economics).

  • Riker, D., & Brainard, S. (1997). U.S. multinationals and competition from low wage countries. (NBER working papers 5959, National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.)

  • Scott, J. (1990). Corporate control and corporate rule: Britain in an international perspective. British Journal of Sociology, 41, 351–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slaughter, M. J. (2000). Production transfer within multinational enterprises and American wages. Journal of International Economics, 50(2), 449–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smarzynska-Javorcik, B., & Spatareanu, M. (2008). To share or not to share: Does local participation matter for spillovers from foreign direct investment? Journal of Development Economics, 85(1–2), 194–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spitz-Oener, A. (2006). Technical change, job tasks and rising educational demands: Looking outside the wage structure. Journal of Labor Economics, 24(2), 235–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiegert, K. W., Ardalan, A., & Marsh, T. L. (2006). Foreign-market entry strategies in the European Union. Journal of Food Distribution Research, 37(03), 44–55.

  • Stock, J. H., & Yogo, M. (2002). Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. (NBER technical working papers 0284, National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.)

  • Strauss-Kahn, V. (2004). The role of globalization in the within-industry shift away from unskilled workers in France. In Challenges to globalization: Analyzing the economics, NBER Chapters (pp. 209–234). National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.

  • Topiol, A., & Héricher, C. (2013). Les groupes français à l’étranger. (Technical Report 1439, Institute for Statistics and Economic Studies (INSEE)).

  • UNCTAD, Geneva. (2013). Global value chains: Investment and trade for development. (World investment report, United Nations Press, New York and Geneva).

  • Vermeulen, E. P. (2013). Beneficial ownership and control: A comparative study-disclosure, information and enforcement. (Technical Report 7, OECD Publishing).

  • Yeats, A. (1998). Just how big is global production sharing?. (Policy research working paper series 1871, The World Bank).

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Catherine Laffineur.

Appendices

Appendix 1: The composition of tasks within occupations

We classified the 41 main work activities into five major categories as in ALM (2003). They distinguish between: (i) non-routine analytical tasks are usually performed in technical or managerial occupations. They require cognitive capacity in which responsiveness, creativity, decision making and problem solving are important. (ii) The second major task category includes non-routine interactive tasks. These tasks require physical interaction and adaptability to certain types of situations. (iii) The third category identifies cognitive routine tasks that are usually carried out by administrative or clerical occupations, such as secretaries and accounting officers who perform repetitive tasks using an identified procedure. (iv) Manual routine tasks are performed by production operators such as handlers, machine operators, workers in packaging and transportation. These tasks can be seen as unskilled manual tasks. (v) Finally, the last category lists manual tasks that require specific knowledge and are considered as skilled manual tasks. These tasks are mostly performed by technicians or foremen (Table 11).

Table 11 Occupational tasks

The following table gives examples of different types of tasks performed in four main occupations in the metal industry. Here we see that engineers have a higher score in making decision, whereas mechanics have the lower score. In contrast, skilled assemblers have a higher score in the task of handling and moving objects compared to engineers (Table 12).

Table 12 Examples in the metal industry

Table 13 provides descriptive statistics, showing the mean intensity of each score for the seven major occupations.

Table 13 Tasks’ intensity within occupations

It shows that skilled production workers (composed of skilled blue-collar workers, engineers, technicians and foremen) have an important index of non-routine manual, interactive and analytical tasks. Managers and engineers are the two occupations having the highest score of routine cognitive tasks, whereas skilled and unskilled blue-collar workers perform routine manual tasks more intensively.

Mapping the SOC classification of ONET to the French PCS-ESE The ONET databases provides information on 900 occupations classified according to a classification close to the American SOC classification. In order to build a task index compatible with the French classification of occupations (PCS-ESE), we need to build a mapping table from PCS-ESE to SOC 2010. We have built it thanks to the EurOccupations database.Footnote 47 The EurOccupations project aimed at building a publicly available database containing the most common occupations in multi-country data-collection. The database includes a source list of 1594 distinct occupational titles within the ISCO-08 classification and provides a mapping table between the EurOccupation classification and the ISCO-08 classification, as well as a French translation of these occupations. We then match the 412 PCS-ESE occupational classification for which there is at least a perfect pair with occupations described in the EurOccupation database. Finally, a mapping table from the ISCO-08 to the SOC-2010 classification is used to link the PCS-ESE occupational classification with the SOC-2010. By creating this mapping table, we can use the ONET index to analyze the task content of French occupations.

Appendix 2: Robustness tests

The following section gives results of Eq. 3 by using different measures of offshoring. We define three other measures of FDI.

The first proxy is constructed by using the percentage of votes at general meeting. The aim is to take into account the possibility that a firm uses its blocking minority power.Footnote 48 The underlying idea for using blocking minority as a weighted measure is to assuming increasing control over the foreign subsidiary when the firm has the possibility to veto certain decisions at extraordinary general meetings of shareholders. The investing firm could thus have incentives to actively manage employment inside the subsidiary and to transfer its intangible assets.

The measure is built as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \rho _{jt} = \sum \limits _k {subsidiary_{kjt} } \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} subsidiary_{kjt} = 1,&\quad when\, Voting_{kjt} \ge 34\,\% \\ subsidiary_{kjt} = Voting_{kjt},&\quad when\, Voting_{kjt} < 34\,\% \\ \end{array} \right. \)

Here, we assume that when a firm owns more than 34 % of the voting stock, then the firm has a blocking minority and can intervene in important decisions concerning its subsidiary. Therefore the firm owns the subsidiary entirely, and the number of FDI projects is equal to 1. If the firm does not hold a blocking minority, then we do not consider that the firm holds the entire subsidiary, but only holds the subsidiary weighted by the voting stock.

The \(\rho \) measure controls for the blocking minority, but has the disadvantage of overriding the existing hierarchy when votes are held.

We also control our results by using a second proxy of a firm’s FDI size, by weighting the firm’s number of subsidiaries by firm \(j\)’s average outward investment stock.Footnote 49 The third measure is constructed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _{jt} = \sum \limits _k {Value_{kjt} } \end{aligned}$$
(7)

where \(Value_{kjt}\) is the balance sheet value of firm \(j\)’s subsidiary \(k\) at time \(t\). However, information on the gross value of investment purchased in each subsidiary is not available prior to 2004. As it is a stock value, the average over a 4-year period gives a good proxy of a firm’s mean size of foreign investments. We first measure the number of foreign subsidiaries controlled by each firm \(j\) over the period \(t \in \left[ {2002,2007} \right] \). We weight this number by the firm \(j\)’s mean outward investment stock amount over the period 2004–2007.

However, the measure \(\varphi \) does not account for all multinational companies, since information on subsidiaries’ stock amounts are not referenced for each subsidiary in the LIFI survey.

Finally, we use the number of subsidiaries abroad without weights (we call this \(\delta \)).

The measure \(\kappa \) is preferred for different reasons. First, it allows the effect of a change in the share of voting stock held in a foreign subsidiary to be captured, even if the firm does not change its number of foreign subsidiaries. Several studies have highlighted the impact of control over wages and employment (see Bircan 2011 for a review). Second, it allows control for multiple authority sources in a group. Indeed, if two French subsidiaries inside a domestic group control the same subsidiary abroad, it allows firm holdings with a clear majority to be distinguished.

Tables 14 and 15 report results with the different measures of FDI on the share of executives and blue-collar workers respectively. Columns (1) and (7) report the results with the measure of offshoring \(\kappa \). Columns (2) and (8) report the results with the measure of offshoring \(\rho \). Columns (3) and (9) report the results with the measure \(\varphi \). Columns (4) and (10) report the result with the measure of offshoring \(\delta \). Columns (5) and (11) report the results with the measure of offshoring \(\kappa \), and include the variables on the wages paid by type of work \(i\) relative to the composite wage of work type not in \(i\). Whatever the proxy retained, the preceding conclusions are not altered.

Table 14 Robustness test with different measures of offshoring (executives)
Table 15 Robustness test with different measures of offshoring (blue-collar workers)

Columns (6) and (12) report the results with the measure of offshoring \(\kappa \), by including the variable of parent company nationality. We add a dummy that takes the value of 1 if a firm is controlled by a foreign parent company, and 0 otherwise. The coefficient associated with this dummy is identified for firms that changed nationality in the sample period. The inclusion of the firm’s nationality does not alter the conclusions. FDI to low-income countries is significantly associated with a higher share of executives employees, and is associated with a lower share of blue-collar workers.Footnote 50

Finally, we report the results when controlling for the FDI strategy at the group level (see Table 16). The results are consistent with those obtained by taking into account the relocation strategy at the firm level. A group’s number of subsidiaries in low-income countries raises the share of executives inside domestic firms. Relocation in high-income countries does not show any significant impact on either types of jobs and tasks. However, contrary to results at the firm level, when the group raises its FDI in high-income countries, blue-collar workers are negatively affected. The reason is certainly due to an overall effect on the rationalization of production processes by eliminating unnecessary domestic capacity at the group level. Indeed, when the group increases FDI to low-income countries it may decide to reduce the employment of blue-collar workers in dedicated subsidiaries, even those that are not directly engaged in outward FDI.

Table 16 International strategies at the group level

Appendix 3: Description of variables

We report a detailed description of groups of occupations, set out in Sects. 5.1, 5.2, 5.3 and 5.4. We also refer to their French classification (PCS-ESE 2003), available at http://www.insee.fr/ (Table 17).

Table 17 Description of the groups of occupations

Appendix 4: Regression on groups of occupations

See Table 18.

Table 18 Changes in the share of occupations by production groups

Appendix 5: Sector decomposition

Table 19 presents the average wage bill share for seven broad occupations per sector. The consumer goods industries are relatively more intensive in administrative workers (managers and employees), while the capital and intermediate goods industries are more intensive in skilled production workers (engineers, skilled blue-collars and technicians). The share of unskilled blue-collar workers and foremen are relatively similar in the three sectors.

Table 19 Decomposition of the wage-bill share by sector

The following tables present the results of the fixed effect model by dividing the sample into three main industry categories. Firms belonging to consumer goods industries are reported in Table 20. Firms belonging to intermediate goods industries are reported in Table 22. Finally, firms belonging to capital goods industries are reported in Table 21. 20.82 % of our sample are in the consumer goods industries, 23.69 % are in capital goods industries and 50.99 % are in the intermediate goods industries.

Table 20 Fixed effect model for the consumer goods industries
Table 21 Fixed effect model for capital goods industries
Table 22 Fixed effect model for intermediate goods industries

Table 20 shows no clear effect of offshoring on employment. Whereas Table 21 shows a positive effect of offshoring to low-income countries on the share of executives, and the share of workers performing intensively cognitive and analytical tasks.

Interestingly, Table 21 shows that the negative bias towards manual workers when offshoring occurs in high-wage countries and is mainly driven by firms in capital goods industries, as described in Sect. 5.2. We also observe a positive association between offshoring in high-income countries and the share of workers performing interactive tasks. This is similar to results obtained in Becker et al. (2013).

Table 22 shows a clear substitution between blue-collar workers and a complementarity between skilled executives and offshored employment in low-income countries. Similar results were obtained for Sweden by Hansson (2005).

Appendix 6: First-stage estimates

Results of the first-stage estimates show that there is a positive correlation between our \(\kappa \) measure, reflecting the number of subsidiaries, in high-income countries and the average GDP per capita in the destination country. Conversely, there is a positive correlation between GDP per capita in low-wage countries and the number of subsidiaries in low-wage countries. Overall, we observe that increasing GDP per capita raises the incentive for firms to invest, whatever the type of country (low-income or high-income).

Interestingly, we observe a positive correlation between FDI to high-income countries and the GDP per capita in low-income countries. FDI to low-income countries and more particularly in emerging economies combines strategies of market access and saving labor costs (which are often called mixed investment strategies). On the one hand, production costs are lower than in developed countries, which increasingly drive efficiency-seeking investments. On the other hand, growing demand and strong market potential increase incentives to invest in emerging economies. Mixed investment strategies represent the major share of investment, since roughly 80 % of FDI to low-income countries is directed towards only ten emerging countries with strong growth potential. Large firms in European countries and French CAC 40 companies, in particular, have created more jobs and business in emerging countries than in high-income European countries in recent years. This is because a part of the global demand and growth have shifted to emerging markets (UNCTAD 2013). Therefore, increasing low-income countries’ GDP per capita would raise consumer demand without increasing production costs as much as in developed countries. A firm could gain in efficiency and profitability as a result of increasing low-income countries’ GDP, and would allow it to raise FDI in high-income countries.

In contrast, we observe a negative and significant correlation between high-income countries’ GDP per capita and FDI to low-income countries. These results show that, other things being equal, increasing market potential in high-income countries reduces the incentive for firms to invest in low-income countries. This corroborates the result that market access is a powerful force of attraction for companies (Fontagne and Mayer 2005).

Results for infrastructure variables are intuitive and are in line with the existing, vast literature. They show that the quality of infrastructure is an important source of comparative advantage. Increases in the level of infrastructure in low-income countries raise the incentive for firms to invest in these countries. The same conclusion holds for offshoring to high-income countries.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Laffineur, C., Mouhoud, E.M. The jobs at risk from globalization: the French case. Rev World Econ 151, 477–531 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-015-0221-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-015-0221-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation