Skip to main content
Log in

Socially optimal contribution rate and cap in a proportional (DC) pension system

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Portuguese Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In our model, the government operates a mandatory proportional (DC) pension system to substitute for the low life-cycle savings of the lower-paid myopic workers, while maintaining the incentives of the higher-paid far-sighted ones in contributing to the system. The introduction of an appropriate cap on pension contribution (or its base)—excluding the earnings above the cap from the contribution base—raises the optimal contribution rate, helping more the lower-paid myopic workers and reserving enough room for the saving of higher-paid far-sighted ones. The social welfare is almost independent of the cap in a relatively wide interval but the maximal welfare is higher than the capless welfare by 0.3–4.5 %.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Recently, the US Social Security contribution rate is as low as 12.4 %, while in Italy it is as high as 34 %. There are a number of causes of this difference, e.g. the higher systemic dependency in Italy and the stronger redistribution in the US, see Disney (2004). Taking the average gross wage as unity, the cap is as low as 1.3 in Sweden and as high as 2.5 in the US, cf. also Table 1 in Valdés-Prieto and Schwarzhupt (2011). Lovell (2009) gives a useful dataset and analysis of the long and sometimes turbulent history of the US Social Security.

  2. The lowered contribution rate for the self employed can be explained along this line, too, but in fact, it stems from the difficulties of auditing rather than paternalistic differentiation.

  3. In Hungary, the former contribution rate is 10 % of the gross wage, while the latter is 24%. Until 2013, the uncapped contributions alone provided 6 % of the total pension contributions and gave 10 % of the de facto personal income tax. From 2013, there is no cap at all, decreasing the social welfare with respect to the maximum. At the same time, the weak progressivity of the system becomes stronger.

  4. In the US, the progressivity of the Social Security disappears above the cap. In Great Britain of post-WWII the cap was set at the minimum wage, transforming the flat benefit system into a flat contribution one, see also Example 1 below.

  5. One can also argue that their flexible labor supply is replaced by more efficient private saving in the present paper.

  6. Studying lifetime income redistribution, Tenhunen and Tuomala (2010) connected the incomes and discount factors and compared the welfarist and the paternalistic social optima.

  7. It would be interesting to see how our partial equilibrium result change in their general equilibrium model; for example, if the introduction of the cap raises savings, then the endogenous interest rate diminishes, weakening the advantage of the cap.

  8. The use of various control characters may seem superfluously complicated but in fact this practice helps to understand the notations. For example, writing \(\bar w\) rather than an unrelated parameter, e.g. 𝜃 reminds the reader that it is related to wage w.

  9. In a median voter model with a progressive pension system, Borck (2007) analytically investigated the important problem when the life expectancy grows with income but at the cost of distorting (3).

  10. Using a Rawlsian social welfare function would defy the purpose of the study, rendering the socially optimal cap indeterminate and the corresponding contribution rate myopic (cf. (10) below)

  11. Note that for zero contribution rate, the value of the cap is as irrelevant as for zero cap, the value of the contribution rate. Therefore \(V[\varepsilon ,\tau ,0]=V[\varepsilon ,0,\bar {w}]=V[\varepsilon ,0,0]\).

  12. If we took into account that the socially optimal discount factor is less than one (e.g. labor disutility, reduced family size in old-age, etc., as postulated by Cremer et al. (2008)), then we could reduce the contribution rate further, even to 1/4.

  13. We shall divide the interval [w m ,w Q ] into n = 100 subintervals such a way that the division points w i form a geometrical sequence. At integration, the representative points are the geometrical means of the subsequent points: w i + 1 = q w i and \(z_{i}=\sqrt {w_{i} w_{i+1}}\). The mass of the remaining infinite part is 1−F(w Q )=0.0001 with w Q =50 and the earning w K =100 represents the average highest wage.

References

  • Barr N, Diamond P (2008) Reforming pensions: principles and policy choices. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G, Mulligan CB (1997) On the Optimal Determination of Time Preferences. Q J Econ 112:729–758

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borck R (2007) On the choice of public pensions when income and life expectancy are correlated. J. Public Economic Theory 9:711–725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer H, De Donder Ph, Maldonaldo D, Pestieau P (2008) Designing a linear pension scheme with forced savings and wage heterogeneity. Int Tax Public Finance 15:547–562

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer H, Pestieau P (2011) Myopia, redistribution and pensions. Eur Econ Rev 55:165–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA, Orszag P (2004) Saving social security: a balanced approach, Washington. Brookings Institution, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA, Saez E (2011) The case for a progressive tax: from basic research to policy prescriptions. J Econ Perspect 23(4):165–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Disney R (2004) Are contributions to public pension programmes a tax on employment?. Econ Policy 39:267–311

    Google Scholar 

  • Docquire F (2002) On the optimality of mandatory pensions in an economy with life-cyclers and Myopes. J Econ Behav Organ 47:121–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr H, Kallweit M, Kindermann F (2013) Should pensions be progressive?. Eur Econ Rev 63:94–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein MS (1985) The optimal level of social benefits. Q J Econ 100:302–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein MS (1987) Should social security means be tested?. Journal of Political Economy 95:468–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein M (2005) Structural reform of social security. J Econ Perspect 19(1):33–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Findley TS, Caliendo FN (2009) Short horizons, time inconsistency, and the optimal social security. Int J Public Finance 16:487–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson D (1997) Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Q J Econ 112:443–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lovell M C (2009) Social securitys five OASI inflation indexing problems, Economics: The Open Access, Open Assessed E-Journal, 140

  • Pestieau P, Ponthiere G (2014) Policy implications for changing longevity. CESifo Econ Stud 60:178–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1975) Optimum social security in a life-cycle growth model. Int Econ Rev 16:539–544

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonovits A (2009) Underreported earning and age-specific income redistribution in post-socialist economies, IE-HAS Discussion Papers 27

  • Simonovits A (2011) When are voluntary pensions indifferent?. Econ Lett 111:153–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonovits A (2012) Optimal cap on pension contributions, IE–CERS–HAS Discussion Papers 8. Budapest

  • Tenhunen S, Tuomala M (2010) On optimal lifetime redistribution policy. J Public Econ Theory 12:171–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Valdés-Prieto S, Schwarzhupt U (2011) Optimal compulsion when behavioural biases vary and the state errs, CESifo Working Paper 3316

  • World Bank (1994) Averting old-age crisis, Washington. World Bank, DC

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to András Simonovits.

Additional information

An earlier version of the present paper was published as a discussion paper, Simonovits (2012). I am indebted to N. Barr, Zs. Cseres-Gergely, G. Kézdi, J. Köllő, G. Kőrösi, M. C. Lovell, Th. Matheson (my discussant at the IIPF Congress in Dresden held in 2012), J. Pál and G. Varga for friendly comments. H. Fehr deserves a special acknowledgment for his steady contribution to developing this paper. I express my gratitude to anonymous referees, especially of the POJE’s; who greatly helped to improve the paper. This research has received generous financial support from OTKA K 81483.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Simonovits, A. Socially optimal contribution rate and cap in a proportional (DC) pension system. Port Econ J 14, 45–63 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10258-015-0107-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10258-015-0107-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation