Skip to main content
Log in

An empirical analysis of the multimarket contact theory in pharmaceutical markets

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The European Journal of Health Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Multimarket contact theory predicts that firms will optimally reduce prices in markets where collusive prices are sustainable and allocate the slack of the corresponding incentive compatibility to increase prices in markets where collusion is not sustainable. Binding price caps in collusive markets will have different effects over the multimarket contact mechanism depending on the severity of the cap. Setting a price cap close to the unregulated case will increase the size of the redistribution of market power whereas stronger regulation will even reduce prices in unregulated markets. Therefore, price regulations aiming at capping prices in a specific market will also affect markets that are not subject to specific mandatory price regulations. We find evidence of the theory predictions using information for nine OECD countries for pharmaceutical markets. Unregulated US markets are shown to respond to the redistribution effect; Canadian markets, known to be subject to soft price regulations, with respect to the former, are shown to be consistent with a stronger redistribution effect. EU markets and Japan are either consistent with the effect of a medium regulation or strong regulation. In this last case multimarket contact cannot explain prices, and these are expected to be lower compared to the unregulated benchmark.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Other theoretical works on the multimarket contact structure of industries are Spagnolo [19] and Matsushima [14]. In practice, as such a strategy implies firms pricing above competitive prices in some markets and reducing prices in others, the average multimarket effect over prices can be ambiguous.

  2. This functional form is taken from an unpublished paper by Gimeno and Woo [12].

  3. This approach was also present in Jans and Rosembaum [13]; however, they did not intend to test for the market power redistribution hypothesis. Nevertheless, the latter found that prices are expected to be higher because of contacts across markets whenever the concentration is higher in a market.

  4. The data set gathers information from the 4th quarter of each year, apart from 2003, for which the information is provided for the 2nd quarter.

  5. We are indebted to Guillem López (UPF) and Vicente Ortún (UPF) and Félix Lobo (UC3M) for helpful advice on this regard.

  6. The ATC classification is supported and maintained by the World Health Organization Collaborating Center for Drug Statistics Methodology with a base at the Norwegian Institute of Public Health.

  7. Note that whenever a firm is a monopolist in a product market, the variable takes the value of zero.

  8. In any case, it would be a never-ending exercise to identify marginal costs of production for a large set of products like the one we consider in our sample.

  9. See Berndt et al. [2, 3], Cockburn and Anis [6], and Suslow [21].

  10. Tables 12 and 13 in the “Appendix” show IV-GMM estimations for Eqs. (9) and (10), respectively, where lags of the multimarket contact variables are used as instruments. The estimated marginal effects for the multimarket contact specification do not change significantly with respect to our baseline estimation strategy shown above. Furthermore, for the great majority of countries the instruments pass the Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions. We take this result as indicative that lagging the multimarket contact variables provides consistent estimates of the marginal effects of interest.

  11. The complete set of results is available from the author upon request.

References

  1. Baltagi, B.: Econometric Analysis of Panel Data. Wiley, London (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  2. Berndt, E., Cockburn, I., Griliches Z.: Pharmaceutical innovations and market dynamics: tracking effects on price indexes for antidepressant drugs. Brookings Pap. Econ. Act., 133–188 (1996)

  3. Berndt, E., Pindyck, R., Azoulay, P.: Network Effects and Diffusion in Pharmaceutical Markets: Antiulcer Drugs. NBER Working Paper Series, No. 7024 (1999)

  4. Bernheim, D., Whinston, M.: Multimarket contact and collusive behavior. Rand J. Econ. 21, 1–26 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Busse, M.: Multimarket contact and price coordination in the cellular telephone industry. J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 9, 287–320 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Cockburn, I.M., Anis, A.H.: Hedonic Analysis of Arthritis Drugs. NBER Working Papers 6574, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc (1998)

  7. Danzon, P., Chao, L.: Does regulation drive out competition in pharmaceutical markets? J. Law Econ. 43, 311–357 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Edwards, C.: Conglomerate bigness as a source of power. In: The National Bureau of Economic Research Conference Report, Business Concentration and Price Policy, pp. 331–359. Princeton University Press, Princeton (1955)

  9. Evans, W., Kessides, I.: Living by the “golden rule”: multimarket contact in the U.S. airline industry. Q. J. Econ. 109, 341–366 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Fernández, N., Marín, P.: Market power and multimarket contact. Some evidence from the spanish hotel industry. J. Ind. Econ. 46, 301–315 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Fu, W.: Multimarket contact of U.S. newspaper chains: circulation competition and market coordination. Inf. Econ. Policy 15, 501–519 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Gimeno, J., Woo, C.Y.: Multimarket contact as a mechanism of Transfer of Power Across Structurally Different Markets. Working Paper/Texas AM University (1994)

  13. Jans, I., Rosembaum, D.: Multimarket contact and pricing: evidence from the U.S. cement industry. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 15, 391–412 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Matsushima, H.: Multimarket conctact, imperfect monitoring and implicit collusion. J. Econ. Theory 98, 158–178 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Parker, P., Roller, L.: Collusive conduct in duopolies: multimarket contact and cross-ownership in the mobile telephone industry. Rand J. Econ. 28, 304–322 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Phillips, O., Mason, C.: Marker regulation and market rivalry. Rand J. Econ. 27(3), 596–617 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Pilloff, S.J.: Multimarket contact in banking. Rev. Ind. Organ. 14, 163–182 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Puig-Junoy, J.: Price regulation systems in the pharmacetical market. In: Puig-Junoy, J. (eds.) The Public Financing of Pharmaceuticals. Edgard Elward Publishing, Cheltenham, UK (2005)

  19. Spagnolo, G.: On interdependent games: multimarket contact, concavity and collusion. J. Econ. Theory 89, 127–139 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Stern, S.: Market Definition and the Returns to Innovation: Substitution Patterns in Pharmaceutical Markets. MIMEO, MIT Sloan School, Cambridge, Boston (1996)

  21. Suslow, V.Y.: Measuring quality change in pharmaceutical markets: hedonic price indexes for anti-ulcer drugs. In: Helms, R. (eds.) Competitive Strategies in the Pharmaceutical Industry, NBER Chapters, pp. 48–72. American Enterprise Institute, Washington (1996)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Early research for this paper was supported by an unrestricted educational grant from the Merck Company Foundation, the philanthropic arm of Merck & Co., Inc., Whitehouse Station, NJ. Partial funding was also obtained from the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology under projects ECO2008-06395-C05-01 and ECO2011-30323-C03-02. We thank MSD and IMS for providing the data and conference participants at IDEI/U.Toulouse, AES/A Corunha and Swiss IO Day conferences and seminar audiences at UPF and UC3M. The helpful suggestions of Antonio Cabrales, Félix Lobo, Guillem López, Vicente Ortún, Jaume Puig, Fran Ruiz-Aliseda and Joel Shapiro are gratefully acknowledged. We are specially grateful to Patricia Danzon for her kind suggestions on critical issues in the data analysis.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sergi Jiménez-Martín.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 14, and 15.

Table 9 Mean and SD (in parentheses) for variables in sample by country
Table 10 Pricing regressions for molecule markets: average multimarket effect
Table 11 Pricing regressions for molecule markets: multimarket contact redistribution effect
Table 12 Pricing regressions for average multimarket effect: IV regressions with lagged multimarket variables as instruments
Table 13 Pricing regressions for multimarket redistribution effect: IV regressions with lagged multimarket variables as instruments
Table 14 Pricing regressions for molecule markets: ATC-1 fixed effects
Table 15 Pricing regressions for molecule markets: IV regressions with lagged controls as instruments

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Coronado, J., Jiménez-Martín, S. & Marín, P.L. An empirical analysis of the multimarket contact theory in pharmaceutical markets. Eur J Health Econ 15, 623–643 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-013-0501-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-013-0501-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation