Skip to main content
Log in

On hierarchical competition in oligopoly

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we consider a hierarchical oligopoly model, in which firms compete on quantities of an homogeneous product. We provide a proof and an interpretation that under the three necessary and sufficient conditions of linear aggregate demand, constant and identical marginal costs, the strategy of leaders at any stage depends neither on the number of leaders who play after nor on the number of remaining stages. So, all firms behave as Cournotian oligopolists on the residual demand. We show that these three assumptions are not only sufficient but also necessary. Any departure from any of these assumptions rules out this property.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Pal and Sarkar (2001) and Lafay (2010), however, analyze the robustness of the property by investigating the impact of cost differences on the equilibrium strategies.

  2. Our analysis then does not restrict to equilibrium strategies.

  3. The standard Stackelberg duopoly prevails when \(T=2\) and \(n_{1}=n_{2}=1\).

  4. We therefore do not question the way a specific firm could or should become a leader (see Anderson and Engers 1992; Amir and Grilo 1999; Matsumura 1999).

  5. Property 1 still holds in the presence of static conjectural variations (see Julien and Musy 2011).

  6. The case \(\mathcal O _{g}=0\) means that price is constant, that is independent of aggregate output.

  7. The case \(\mathcal O _{f}=0\) is a subcase of Eq. (5) for which \(\alpha _{2}=0\).

  8. This result was pointed out by Anderson and Engers (1992) in footnote 5 on page 129.

  9. This function is derived from the total revenue of a follower \(i\): \( RT(x_{T}^i) = [\bar{a}_{T-1} - b\sum _{k=1}^{n_{T}}x_{T}^k] x_{T}^i\). The symmetric behavior assumed for followers yields: \(x_{T}^i=x_T\) for all \(i\in [1,n_T]\) and \(X_{T}=n_{T} x_T\).

  10. The associated marginal revenue is: \(R_m(X_{T-h})= \tilde{R}_m(X_{T-h})+(1-\gamma _{T-h})c\).

References

  • Amir R, Grilo I (1999) Stackelberg versus Cournot equilibrium. Games Econ Behav 26:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson SP, Engers M (1992) Stackelberg versus Cournot equilibrium. Int J Ind Organ 10:127–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyer M, Moreaux M (1986) Perfect competition as the limit of a hierarchical market game. Econ Lett 22:115–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlton D, Perloff JM (1994) Modern industrial organization. HarperCollins, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Daughety A (1990) Beneficial concentration. Am Econ Rev 80:1231–1237

    Google Scholar 

  • De Quinto J, Watt R (2003) Some simple graphical interpretations of the Herfindahl-Hirshman index. Mimeo

  • Etro F (2008) Stackelberg competition with endogenous entry. Econ J 118:1670–1697

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heywood JS, McGinty M (2008) Leading and merging: convex costs, Stackelberg, and the merger paradox. South Econ J 74:879–893

    Google Scholar 

  • Julien LA, Musy O (2011) A generalized oligopoly model with conjectural variations. Metroeconomica 62:411–433

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafay T (2010) A linear generalization of Stackelberg’s model. Theor Decis 69:317–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T (1999) Quantity-setting oligopoly with endogenous sequencing. Int J Ind Organ 17:289–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pal D, Sarkar J (2001) A Stackelberg oligopoly with nonidentical firms. Bull Econ Res 53:127–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sherali HD (1984) A multiple leader Stackelberg model and analysis. Oper Res 32:390–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stackelberg H (1934) Marktform und Gleichgewicht. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Vives X (1999) Oligopoly pricing. Old ideas and new tools. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Watt R (2002) A generalized oligopoly model. Metroeconomica 53:46–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to C. Bidard for his comments and remarks on a previous version of the paper. Two anonymous referees are acknowledged for their remarks and suggestions. Remaining errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ludovic A. Julien.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proof of Lemma 1

The proof is by backward induction and structured in three steps.

Step 1 property 1 is true for cohort \(t=T-1\) (with \(T>1\)).

The inverse demand function faced by firms is defined by:

$$\begin{aligned} p(X) = a - bX \quad \text{ with} X=\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T} X_\tau , \end{aligned}$$
(H1)

where \(X_\tau = \sum _{i=1}^{n_\tau } x_\tau ^i\ge 0\) is the aggregate production of cohort \(\tau \). For any quantity of output \(X_{T-1}\) produced by cohort \(T-1\), the resulting residual demand faced by followers of cohort \( T\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T}X_\tau \right) = \bar{a}_{T-1} - bX_{T}\quad \text{ with} \bar{a}_{t}\equiv a-b\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{t}X_\tau , \end{aligned}$$
(38)

where \(\bar{a}_{T-1}\) is considered as given by followers. Geometrically (see Fig. 1), followers must select a couple \((X,p)\) on the segment \([D,A]\).

When acting symmetrically, the associated marginal revenue of cohort-\(T\) firms (dashed line on Fig. 1) is defined by:Footnote 9

$$\begin{aligned} R_m(X_T) = \bar{a}_{T-1} - b\frac{1+n_{T}}{n_{T}}X_{T}. \end{aligned}$$
(39)

Considering the following derivatives:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial R_m}{\partial X_T}(X_T)&= \frac{DF}{CF} = -b\frac{1+n_{T}}{ n_{T}}\end{aligned}$$
(40)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p}{\partial X_T}(X_T)&= \frac{DF}{AF} = -b, \end{aligned}$$
(41)

it comes that:

$$\begin{aligned} CF=\frac{n_{T}}{1+n_{T}}AF, \quad \text{ or} \text{ equivalently} AC=\frac{1}{1+n_{T}}AF. \end{aligned}$$
(42)

Finally, applying Thales’ theorem to triangles \(ABC\) and \(ADF\) leads to:

$$\begin{aligned} BC=\frac{1}{1+n_{T}}DF=EF. \end{aligned}$$
(43)

Actually, \(EF\) is the markup of a leader after the entrance of the last cohort, while \(DF\) is the markup of a leader before the entrance of cohort \( T \). Equation (43) can be rewritten as:

$$\begin{aligned} p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T}X_\tau \right) - c = \frac{1}{1+n_{T}}\left[ p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T-1}X_\tau \right) - c\right]. \end{aligned}$$
(44)

Step 2 assume property (1) is true for any cohort \( t=T-h\) (\(1\le h \le T-2\)) then it is true for cohort \(T-h-1\).

If property (1) holds for cohort \(T-h\) then:

$$\begin{aligned} \left[p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T}X_\tau \right)-c\right]x^i_{T-h} = \gamma _{T-h} \left[p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T-h}X_\tau \right)-c\right] x^i_{T-h}, \end{aligned}$$
(45)

with \(\gamma _{T-h}\equiv \prod _{\tau = T-h+1}^{T} \frac{1}{1+n_\tau }\).

Thus, maximizing firm \(i\)’s profit is tantamount to maximize the myopic profit defined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{x^i_{T-h}} \left[p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T-h}X_\tau \right)-c \right]x^i_{T-h}. \end{aligned}$$
(46)

When firms of cohort-\((T-h)\) act symmetrically, the myopic marginal revenue (dashed line) is defined by:Footnote 10

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{R}_m(X_{T-h}) = \bar{a}_{T-h-1} - b \frac{1+n_{T-h}}{n_{T-h}}X_{T-h}. \end{aligned}$$
(47)

In the same way as in step 1, it can be shown that:

$$\begin{aligned} p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T-h}X_\tau \right) - c = \frac{1}{1+n_{T-h}} \left[p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T-h-1}X_\tau \right) - c\right]. \end{aligned}$$
(48)

By assumption, the following property is satisfied:

$$\begin{aligned} p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T}X_\tau \right)-c = \gamma _{T-h} \left[ p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T-h}X_\tau \right)-c\right]. \end{aligned}$$
(49)

We deduce from the two previous equations that:

$$\begin{aligned} p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T}X_\tau \right)-c&= \frac{\gamma _{T-h}}{ 1+n_{T-h}} \left[p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T-h-1}X_\tau \right)-c\right]\end{aligned}$$
(50)
$$\begin{aligned}&= \gamma _{T-h-1} \left[p\left(\sum \limits _{\tau =1}^{T-h-1}X_\tau \right)-c \right] \end{aligned}$$
(51)

Step 3 from steps 1 and 2 we conclude by backward induction that Property 1 is true for any cohort \(t\) (with \(1\le t\le T-1\)).

Appendix B: Proof of Lemma 2

Applying Thales’ theorem to triangles ABC and ADF leads to:

$$\begin{aligned} CF=\frac{n_{t}}{1+n_{t}}AF. \end{aligned}$$
(52)

Actually, \(CF\) is the optimal output produced by cohort \(t\), that is \(X_t\), while \(AF\) is the maximal quantities cohort \(t\) can produce to generate non-negative profit (equal to the difference between the perfect competition equilibrium supply and the output already produced by the previous cohorts). The property above can be rewritten as:

$$\begin{aligned} X_t =\frac{n_t}{1+n_t}(X_t + AC), \quad \text{ or} \text{ equivalently} AC =\frac{X_t}{n_t} = x_t. \end{aligned}$$
(53)

Notice that \(AC\) is also the maximal quantities cohort \(t+1\) can produce to generate non-negative profit. Then, equality (52) applied to cohorts \(t\) and \(t+1\) becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} X_{t+1} =\frac{n_{t+1}}{1+n_{t+1}}AC, \quad \text{ leading} \text{ to} \frac{X_{t+1}}{n_{t+1}} = x_{t+1} = \frac{1}{1+n_{t+1}}x_t. \end{aligned}$$
(54)

By backward induction, it turns out that:

$$\begin{aligned} x_t = \eta _{1,t} x_1,\quad \text{ where} \eta _{1,t}\equiv \prod \limits _{\tau = 2}^{t} \frac{1}{1+n_\tau }. \end{aligned}$$
(55)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Julien, L.A., Musy, O. & Saïdi, A.W. On hierarchical competition in oligopoly. J Econ 107, 217–237 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-012-0286-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-012-0286-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation