Skip to main content
Log in

Sorting out single-crossing preferences on networks

  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We extend the single-crossing property to tree networks to facilitate its application in network games. It is equivalent to intermediate preferences and order restriction (also extended to networks). Moreover, to facilitate broader applications in real world cases and simulations, we develop algorithms that answer the following two questions. Given a preference profile, can we construct a tree graph that supports single-crossing? Given a set of alternatives, can we generate single-crossing preference profiles with associated tree graphs?

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Let \(>\) be a linear order on the set \(N\) of individuals. Preference profile \(\succeq \) satisfies single-crossing on linear order \(>\), if there is a linear order \(>_{X}\) on \(X\) such that for any pair \( x,y\in X\) with \(x>_{X}y\) and for all \(i, j\in N\) with \(i>j\), we have \(x\succeq _{i}y\) implies \(x\succeq _{j}y\) and \(x\succ _{i}y\) implies \(x\succ _{j}y\) . Preference profile \(\succeq \) is intermediate on linear order \(>\), if for any pair \(x, y\in X\) for all \(i, j, k\in N\) with \(i<j<k\), (i) [\(x\succ _{i}y\) and \(x\succ _{k}y\)] implies \(x\succ _{j}y\), and (ii) [\(x\succeq _{i}y \) and \(x\succeq _{k}y\)] implies \(x\succeq _{j}y\). Preference profile \(\succeq \) satisfies order restriction on linear order \(>\), if for any pair \(x,y\in X\), either \(\left\{ i\mid x\succ _{i}y\right\} >\left\{ i\mid x\sim _{i}y\right\} >\left\{ i\mid y\succ _{i}x\right\} \), or \(\left\{ i\mid x\succ _{i}y\right\} <\left\{ i\mid x\sim _{i}y\right\} <\left\{ i\mid y\succ _{i}x\right\} \).

  2. Saporiti and Tohmé (2006) use a version of single-crossing where the alternatives are real numbers, hence have a preexisting order over individuals.

  3. After the following modification on top-monotonicity, Theorem 1 of Barberà and Moreno (2011) generalizes to tree graphs immediately: Preference profile \(\succeq \) is top—monotonic on \(G\), if for any \(i,j\in G\), there is a linear order \(>_{X}\) on \(X\), such that (i) \(t_{i}\left( A\right) \) is a finite union of closed intervals for all \(i\in p\left( ij\right) \), and (ii) For all \(S\in A\left( \succeq \right) \), for all \(m,n\in p\left( ij\right) \), all \(x\in t_{m}\left( S\right) \), all \(y\in t_{n}\left( S\right) \), and any \(z\in S\), we have \(\left[ x>_{X}y>_{X}z\ \text {or}\ z>_{X}y>_{X}x\right] \) implies (a) \(y\succeq _{m}z\ \)if \(z\in t_{m}\left( S\right) \cup t_{n}\left( S\right) \), and (b) \(y\succ _{m}z\) if \( z\not \in t_{m}\left( S\right) \cup t_{n}\left( S\right) \).

  4. Donder (2013) examines single-crossing satisfied separately inside each among many voter groups. His space of alternatives is, however, a common real interval, thus implies a common order. On the other hand, the order of alternatives in our model is not predetermined and can differ for each chosen path of individuals.

  5. Demange (1994) uses this property as the definition of intermediate preferences.

References

  • Barberà S, Moreno B (2011) Top monotonicity: a common root for single peakedness, single-crossing and the median voter result. Games Econ Behav 73:345–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demange G (1994) Intermediate preferences and stable coalition structures. J Math Econ 23:45–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Donder P (2013) Majority voting and the single-crossing property when voters belong to separate groups. Econ Lett 118:523–525

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellickson B (1979) Competitive equilibrium with local public goods. J Econ Theory 21:46–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epple D, Filimon R, Romer T (1984) Equilibrium among local jurisdictions: toward an integrated treatment of voting and residential choice. J Public Econ 24:281–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epple D, Romer T (1992) Mobility and redistribution. J Political Econ 99:828–857

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epple D, Romano R, Sieg H (2006) Admission, tuition, and financial aid policies in the market for higher education. Econometrica 74:885–928

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gans JS, Smart M (1996) Majority voting with single-crossing preferences. J Public Econ 59:219–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grandmont J-M (1978) Intermediate preferences and the majority rule. Econometrica 46:317–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg J, Weber S (1986) Strong tiebout equilibrium under restricted preference domain. J Econ Theory 38:101–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson MO, Watts A (2002) On the formation of interaction networks in social coordination games. Games Econ Behav 41:265–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson MO, Wolinsky A (1996) A strategic model of social and economic networks. J Econ Theory 71:44–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konishi H, Le Breton M, Weber S (1997) Pure strategy nash equilibrium in a group formation game with externalities. Games Econ Behav 21:161–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konishi H, Le Breton M, Weber S (1998) Equilibrium in a finite local public goods economy. J Econ Theory 79:224–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kung F-C (2006) An algorithm for stable and equitable coalition structures with public goods. J Public Econ Theory 8:345–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kung F-C (2010) Coalition formation with local public goods and group-size effect. Int J Game Theory 39:573–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Le Breton M, Owen G, Weber S (1992) Strongly balanced cooperative games. Int J Game Theory 20:419–427

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quah JK-H, Strulovici B (2012) Aggregating the single-crossing property. Econometrica 80:2333–2348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts K (1977) Voting over income tax schedules. J Public Econ 8:329–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein P (1990) Order restricted preferences and the majority rule. Soc Choice Welf 7:331–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saporiti A, Tohmé F (2006) Single-crossing, strategic voting and the median choice rule. Soc Choice Welf 26:363–383

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saporiti A (2009) Strategy-proofness and single-crossing. Theor Econ 4:127–163

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Fan-Chin Kung.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kung, FC. Sorting out single-crossing preferences on networks. Soc Choice Welf 44, 663–672 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-014-0852-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-014-0852-5

Keywords

Navigation