Skip to main content
Log in

Sequential all-pay auctions with head starts

  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study a sequential all-pay auction with two contestants who are privately informed about a parameter (ability) that affects their cost of effort. We characterize the unique perfect Bayesian equilibrium of this sequential all-pay auction and analyze if giving a head start, i.e., an exogenously determined mechanism that increases the winning probability of the first mover for any level of effort she exerts, improves the contestants’ performance. In particular, we analyze the difference between a multiplicative head start and an additive head start with respect to the effect on the contestants’ performance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, Dixit (1987) studied a sequential Tullock contest and examined whether the ability to commit to an effort choice before other contestants choose their effort while assuming that they can then observe this choice is advantageous or not. Linster (1993) analyzed two-player sequential Tullock contests and showed that if the stronger player is the first (second) mover in the sequential contest the players’ total effort is larger (smaller) than in the simultaneous contest.

  2. In a similar vein, Hamilton and Slutsky (1990) Deneckere and Kovenock (1992) and Mailath (1993) studied sequential oligopoly games and showed that sequential choices of quantities in a Cournot competition can be the equilibrium outcome of non-cooperative play.

  3. For all-pay auctions under complete information see Hillman and Samet (1987), Hillman and Riley (1989), Leininger (1991), Baye et al. (1993, 1996), Che and Gale (1998, 2000) and Siegel (2009). For all-pay auctions under incomplete information see Hillman and Riley (1989), Amann and Leininger (1996), Krishna and Morgan (1997), Gavious et al. (2003), Moldovanu and Sela (2001, 2006) and Moldovanu et al. (2012).

  4. It is worth noting that this feature of our model can explain why players sometimes choose to stay out of a contest.

  5. In sport contest, for example, the designer wishes to maximize the players’ expected total effort, while in R&D contests she wishes to maximize the expected highest effort.

  6. See Tsoulouhas et al. (2007) for asymmetric rules in labor tournaments, and Epstein et al. (2011) for asymmetric rules in public procurement and lobbying contests.

  7. Siegel (2010) also studied simultaneous all-pay auctions with head starts in which players do not choose weakly-dominated strategies. He provided an algorithm that constructs a unique equilibrium in these contests.

  8. See Konrad (2002) for another application of headstarts in contests.

  9. See Meirowitz (2008) for a more detailed discussion about head starts in political contests (campaigns).

  10. Schotter and Weigelt (1992) similarly to Lazear and Rosen (1981), Nalebuff and Stiglitz (1983) and Rosen (1986), studied simultaneous tournaments where players are identical, and the observed output is a stochastic function of an unobservable effort. In addition, they assumed that the output of a player must exceed that of his opponent by some fixed amount in order to win the contest. They showed that this additive head start in their model decreases the players’ total performance.

  11. An equivalent interpretation is that \(a_{i}\) is player’s \(i\) valuation for the prize and his cost is equal to his bid.

  12. Note that the S.O.C. is satsisfied if \(f_{2}^{\prime }(b_{1})<0\) for all \( b_{1}\in [b_{1}(0),b_{1}(1)]\). This condition does not imply that \( F_{2}\) should be concave on all the interval \([0,1].\)

  13. In the simultaneous contest with \(F_{1}\left( x\right) =F_{2}\left( x\right) =\sqrt{x}\) the symmetric equilibrium bid function is \(b\left( a\right) = \frac{1}{3}a^{\frac{3}{2}}\) and then \(HE=\frac{2}{15}=0.1333, TE=\frac{1}{6 }=0.1667\) and \(Eff=1\)

  14. Note that if Condition 1 holds then the density function \(f_{2}\left( x\right) \) is convex. This follows by taking the derivative w.r.t. \(a\) of both sides of the equality \(f_{2}\left( b_{1}\left( a\right) \right) =\frac{1}{a}\). Then we get \(-a^{2}f_{2}^{\prime }\left( b_{1}\left( a\right) \right) b_{1}^{\prime }\left( a\right) =1\). And by taking the derivative w.r.t. \(a\) of both sides of this equality and rearranging we get the following equality \(b_{1}^{\prime \prime }\left( a\right) =-\frac{2b_{1}^{\prime }\left( a\right) }{a}-\frac{f_{2}^{\prime \prime }\left( b_{1}\left( a\right) \right) }{f_{2}^{\prime }\left( b_{1}\left( a\right) \right) }\left( b_{1}^{\prime }\left( a\right) \right) ^{2}\). Since by our assumptions \(f_{2}^{\prime }\left( b_{1}\left( a\right) \right) <0\) and \(b_{1}^{\prime }\left( a\right) >0,\) we conclude that \( b_{1}^{\prime \prime }\left( a\right) >0\Rightarrow f_{2}^{\prime \prime }\left( b_{1}\left( a\right) \right) >0.\)

  15. Strict concavity does not imply that \(G^{\prime \prime }\left( x\right) <0\) on the entire interval. Here we assume that both \(G\left( x\right) \) is strictly concave and \(G^{\prime \prime }\left( x\right) <0\) on the entire interval \(\left[ 0,1\right] \).

  16. Recall that \(\widehat{a}=\frac{1}{tf_{2}\left( 0\right) }\) and therefore \( F_{2}\left( f_{2}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{t\widehat{a}}\right) \right) =0\)

References

  • Amann E, Leininger W (1996) Asymmetric all-pay auctions with incomplete information: the two-player case. Games Econ Behav 14:1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baik KH, Shogren JF (1992) Strategic behavior in contests: comment. Am Econ Rev 82(1):359–362

    Google Scholar 

  • Baye MR, Kovenock D, de Vries C (1993) Rigging the lobbying process: an application of the all-pay auction. Am Econ Rev 83:289–294

    Google Scholar 

  • Baye M, Kovenock D, de Vries C (1996) The all-pay auction with complete information. Econ Theory 8:291–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Che YK, Gale I (1998) Caps on political lobbying. Am Econ Rev 88(3):643–651

    Google Scholar 

  • Che YK, Gale I (2000) Difference-form contests and the robustness of all-pay auctions. Games Econ Behav 30:22–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corns A, Schotter A (1999) Can affirmative action be cost effective? an experimental examination of price-preference auctions. Am Econ Rev 89:291–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deneckere RJ, Kovenock D (1992) Price leadership. Rev Econ Stud 59(1):143–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK (1987) Strategic behavior in contests. Am Econ Rev 77(5):891–898

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein G, Mealem Y, Nitzan S (2011) Political culture and discrimination in contests. J Public Econ 1–2:88–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franke J, Kanzow C, Leininger W, Schwartz A (2013) Effort maximization in asymmetric contest games with heterogeneous contestants. Econ Theory 52(2):586–630

    Google Scholar 

  • Fu Q (2006) Endogenous timing of contest with asymmetric information. Public Choice 129:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gavious A, Moldovanu B, Sela A (2003) Bid costs and endogenous bid caps. Rand J Econ 33(4):709–722

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton JH, Slutsky SM (1990) Endogenous timing in duopoly games: Stackelberg or Cournot equilibria. Games Econ Behav 2(1):29–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman A, Riley J (1989) Politically contestable rents and transfers. Econ Polit 1:17–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman A, Samet D (1987) Dissipation of contestable rents by a small number of contenders. Public Choice 54:63–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirkegaard R (2012) Favoritism in contests: head starts and handicaps. Games and Economic Behavior 76(1):226–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konrad K (2002) Investment in the absence of property rights: the role of incumbency advantages. Eur Econ Rev 46(8):563–575

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konrad K, Leininger W (2007) The generalized Stackelberg equilibrium of the all-pay auction with complete information. Rev Econ Des 11(2):165–174

    Google Scholar 

  • Krishna V, Morgan J (1997) An analysis of the war of attrition and the all-pay auction. J Econ Theory 72(2):343–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear E, Rosen S (1981) Rank order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. J Polit Econ 89:841–864

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leininger W (1991) Patent competition, rent dissipation and the persistence of monopoly. J Econ Theory 53(1):146–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leininger W (1993) More efficient rent-seeking—a Munchhausen solution. Public Choice 75:43–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linster BG (1993) Stackelberg rent-seeking. Public Choice 77(2):307–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mailath GJ (1993) Endogenous sequencing of firm decisions. J Econ Theory 59(1):169–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meirowitz A (2008) Electoral contests, incumbency advantages, and campaign finance. J Polit 70(03):681–699

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moldovanu B, Sela A (2001) The optimal allocation of prizes in contests. Am Econ Rev 91(3):542–558

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moldovanu B, Sela A (2006) Contest architecture. J Econ Theory 126(1):70–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moldovanu B, Sela A, Shi X (2012) Carrots and sticks: prizes and punishments in contests. Econ Inq 50(2):453–462

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgan J (2003) Sequential contests. Public Choice 116:1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nalebuff B, Stiglitz J (1983) Prizes and incentives: towards a general theory of compensation and competition. Bell J Econ 14:21–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen S (1986) Prizes and incentives in elimination tournaments. Am Econ Rev 76:701–715

    Google Scholar 

  • Schotter A, Weigelt K (1992) Asymmetric tournaments, equal opportunity laws, and affirmative action: some experimental results. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(2):511–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel R (2009) All-pay contests. Econometrica 77(1):71–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel R (2010) Head starts in all-pay contests. Working paper

  • Tsoulouhas T, Knoeber CR, Agrawal A (2007) Contests to become CEO: incentives, selection and handicaps. Econ Theory 30:195–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aner Sela.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

The expected highest effort in the two-player model without a head start is equal to contestant 1’s expected effort, while the expected highest effort in the two-player model with a head start is larger than or equal to contestant 1’s expected effort. Thus, in order to prove that a head start increases the expected highest effort it is sufficient to show that a head start increases contestant 1’s expected effort. However, what we actually show is even stronger. We show that the effort of every type of contestant 1 who made a positive effort when there was no head start increases when there is a head start. Therefore we show that

$$\begin{aligned} \beta _{1}(a_{1})\ge b_{1}(a_{1})\text { for all }0\le a_{1}\le 1\text { and }1\le t\le \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( 1\right) } \end{aligned}$$

Note that if Condition 1 holds then since \( b_{1}\left( a_{1}\right) \) is increasing in \(a_{1}\) and \(\tilde{a}\ge 0\) then for all \(t>1,\)

$$\begin{aligned} \beta _{1}\left( a_{1}\right) =\frac{1}{t}f_{2}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{ta_{1}} \right) >f_{2}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) =b_{1}\left( a_{1}\right) \end{aligned}$$

Moreover the lowest type of contestant 1 who is active in the two-player model with a head start is lower than the lowest active type of contestant 1 in the two-player model without any head start. Formally, \(\widehat{a}=\frac{ 1}{tf_{2}\left( 0\right) }\le \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( 0\right) }=\widetilde{a}\) for any \(t\ge 1.\) Thus, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \beta _{1}\left( a_{1}\right)&= \frac{1}{t}f_{2}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{ta_{1}} \right) >f_{2}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) =b_{1}\left( a_{1}\right) \quad \text { for all }\quad \widetilde{a}\le a_{1}\le 1 \\ \beta _{1}\left( a_{1}\right)&= \frac{1}{t}f_{2}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{ta_{1}} \right) >b_{1}\left( a_{1}\right) =0\quad \text { for all }\widehat{a}\le a_{1}\le \widetilde{a} \\ \beta _{1}\left( a_{1}\right)&= b_{1}(a_{1})=0\quad \text { for all }\quad 0\le a_{1}\le \text { }\widehat{a} \end{aligned}$$

such that the expected effort of contestant 1 with a head start \(t\) is higher than her expected effort without any head start. \(Q.E.D.\)

1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

The expected effort of contestant 2 given an effort \(\beta _{1}\left( a_{1},t\right) >0\) of contestant 1 is

$$\begin{aligned} E_{2}(t,a_{1})=\left( 1-F_{2}\left( t\beta _{1}\left( a_{1},t\right) \right) \right) t\beta _{1}\left( a_{1},t\right) \end{aligned}$$

The expected effort of contestant 2 is then

$$\begin{aligned} TE_{2}(t)=\int \limits _{0}^{1}E_{2}(t,a_{1})f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1}=\int \limits _{\widehat{a} }^{1}E_{2}(t,a_{1})f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1}>0 \end{aligned}$$

The function \(t\beta _{1}\left( a_{1},t\right) =f_{2}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{ a_{1}t}\right) \) is increasing in \(a_{1}\) as well as in \(t\). By Condition 3, we know that \(f_{2}^{-1}\left( 1\right) <x^{*}\). Therefore we obtain that, for \(t>1\) close enough to \(1\) and for all \(a_{1}\le 1,\)

$$\begin{aligned} t\beta _{1}\left( a_{1},t\right) \le t\beta _{1}\left( a_{1}=1,t\right) =f_{2}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{t}\right) <x^{*} \end{aligned}$$

Thus, by Condition 2 we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dE_{2}(t,a_{1})}{dt}>0 \end{aligned}$$

So far we have shown that given a type \(\widehat{a}\le a_{1}\le 1\) of contestant 1 that exerts a positive effort, the expected effort of contestant 2 increases in \(t\) as long as \(t\) is sufficiently close to \(1\). By Condition 1, the interval of types of contestant 1 who exert a positive effort increases in \(t\), i.e., \(\frac{d\widehat{a}}{dt }=\frac{d}{dt}\left( \frac{1}{tf_{2}\left( 0\right) }\right) \le 0\) and therefore, if \(t\) is sufficiently close to \(1\) we established that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d}{dt}TE_{2}(t)=\frac{d}{dt} \int \limits _{0}^{1}E_{2}(t,a_{1})f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1}=\frac{d}{dt}\int \limits _{\widehat{a} }^{1}E_{2}(t,a_{1})f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1}>0 \end{aligned}$$

\(Q.E.D.\)

1.3 Proof of Proposition 5

The expected highest effort for \(0<t\le f_{2}^{-1}\left( 1\right) \) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} HE(t)&= \int \limits _{0}^{\overline{a}}\left( \int \limits _{t}^{1}tf_{2}\left( a_{2}\right) da_{2}\right) f_{1}\left( a_{1}\right) da_{1} \\&+\int \limits _{\overline{a}}^{1}\left( \int \limits _{0}^{\gamma _{1}\left( a_{1}\right) +t}\gamma _{1}\left( a_{1}\right) f_{2}(a_{2})da_{2} \right. \\&\left. +\int \limits _{\gamma _{1}\left( a_{1}\right) +t}^{1}\left( \gamma _{1}\left( a_{1}\right) +t\right) f_{2}(a_{2})da_{2}\right) f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1} \\&= t\left( 1-F_{2}\left( t\right) \right) F_{1}\left( \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) \\&+\int \limits _{\overline{a}}^{1}\left( \left( f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}} \right) -t\right) F_{2}\left( f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) \right) \right. \\&\left. +f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) \left( 1-F_{2}\left( f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) \right) \right) \right) f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1} \\&= t\left( 1-F_{2}\left( t\right) \right) F_{1}\left( \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) \\&+\int \limits _{\frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) }}^{1}\left( f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) -tF_{2}\left( f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) \right) \right) f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1} \end{aligned}$$

Therefore

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dHE\left( t\right) }{dt}&= \left( 1-F_{2}\left( t\right) -tf_{2}\left( t\right) \right) F_{1}\left( \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) } \right) -t\left( 1-F_{2}\left( t\right) \right) \frac{f_{2}^{\prime }\left( t\right) }{\left( f_{2}\left( t\right) \right) ^{2}} \\&+t\frac{f_{2}^{\prime }\left( t\right) }{\left( f_{2}\left( t\right) \right) ^{2}}\left( 1-F_{2}\left( t\right) \right) f_{1}\left( \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) } \right) \\&-\int \limits _{\frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) }}^{1}F_{2}\left( f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) \right) f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1} \\&= \left( 1-F_{2}\left( t\right) -tf_{2}\left( t\right) \right) F_{1}\left( \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) -\int \limits _{\frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) } }^{1}F_{2}\left( f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) \right) f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1} \end{aligned}$$

Now, since \(f_{2}\left( t\right) \rightarrow \infty \) and \(tf_{2}\left( t\right) \rightarrow 0\) when \(t\rightarrow 0\) we have

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow 0}\frac{dHE\left( t\right) }{dt}=-\int \limits _{0}^{1}F_{2}\left( f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) \right) f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1}<0 \end{aligned}$$

Moreover, since the expected total effort for \(0<t\le f_{2}^{-1}\left( 1\right) \) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} TE(t)&= t\left( 1-F_{2}\left( t\right) \right) F_{1}\left( \frac{1}{ f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) -t\left( 1-F_{1}\left( \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) \right) \\&+\int \limits _{\overline{a}}^{1}\left( \left[ 2-F_{2}\left( f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) \right) \right] f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}} \right) \right) f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1} \\&= t\left( \left( 2-F_{2}\left( t\right) \right) F_{1}\left( \frac{1}{ f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) -1\right) \\&+\int \limits _{\overline{a}}^{1}\left( \left[ 2-F_{2}\left( f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) \right) \right] f_{2}{}^{-1}\left( \frac{1}{a_{1}}\right) \right) f_{1}(a_{1})da_{1} \end{aligned}$$

we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dTE}{dt}&= \left( 2-F_{2}\left( t\right) \right) F_{1}\left( \frac{1}{ f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) -1\\&+t\left( -f_{2}\left( t\right) F_{1}\left( \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) -\left( 2-F_{2}\left( t\right) \right) f_{1}\left( \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) \frac{ f_{2}^{\prime }\left( t\right) }{\left( f_{2}\left( t\right) \right) ^{2}} \right) \\&+\frac{f_{2}^{\prime }\left( t\right) }{\left( f_{2}\left( t\right) \right) ^{2}}\left( 2-F_{2}(t)\right) tf_{1}\left( \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) \\&= \left( 2-F_{2}\left( t\right) -tf_{2}\left( t\right) \right) F_{1}\left( \frac{1}{f_{2}\left( t\right) }\right) -1 \end{aligned}$$

And since \(f_{2}\left( t\right) \rightarrow \infty \) and \(tf_{2}\left( t\right) \rightarrow 0\) when \(t\rightarrow 0\) we obtain that

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{t\rightarrow 0}\frac{dTE}{dt}=-1 \end{aligned}$$

\(Q.E.D.\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Segev, E., Sela, A. Sequential all-pay auctions with head starts. Soc Choice Welf 43, 893–923 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-014-0816-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-014-0816-9

Navigation