Skip to main content
Log in

Private versus public consumption within groups: testing the nature of goods from aggregate data

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the testability implications of public versus private consumption in collective models of group consumption. The distinguishing feature of our approach is that we start from a revealed preference characterization of collectively rational behavior. Remarkably, we find that assumptions regarding the public or private nature of specific goods do have testability implications, even if one only observes the aggregate group consumption. In fact, these testability implications apply as soon as the analysis includes three goods and four observations. This stands in sharp contrast with existing results that start from a differential characterization of collectively rational behavior.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The term differential refers to the fact that the characterization is obtained by integrating and/or differentiating the functional specifications of the fundamentals (e.g., the individual preferences of the group members) of the model.

  2. See also Samuelson (1938), Houthakker (1950), Diewert (1973) and Fostel et al. (2004) for seminal contributions on the revealed preference approach to analyzing consumption behavior.

  3. See for example Hurwicz (1971) and Pollak (1990) for discussions on the difference between the global revealed preference approach and the local differential approach.

  4. Other possible applications could combine our results with those of Gersbach and Haller (2005), who focus on the impact of externalities on intra-household allocations, and with those of Ekeland and Galichon (2012), who focus on the duality between the housing market and revealed preference theory.

  5. The results below can be generalized toward the setting of \(M\) members, with \(M\ge 2\). However, we believe that the core arguments underlying our results are better articulated for this simple case.

  6. As in the differential approach, we say that a function is well behaved if it is concave, differentiable and monotonically increasing.

  7. For ease of exposition, the scalar product \(\mathbf p ^{\prime }_{t}\mathbf q _{t}\) is written as \(\mathbf p _{t}\mathbf q _{t}\).

  8. Given that \(\mathfrak q ^{1}_{t}+\mathfrak q ^{2}_{t}=\mathbf 0 \), the specification of \(\mathfrak p ^1_t\) and \(\mathfrak p ^2_t\) is irrelevant for verifying GARP. In other words, only the willingness to pay for the public goods (i.e., \(\mathfrak p ^h_t\) and \(\mathbf p _t-\mathfrak p ^h_t\)) is important. A similar remark holds for Proposition 3.

  9. If \(T=2\), one can easily verify that \(\mathfrak p _{1}^{h}=\mathbf p _{1}\) and \(\mathfrak p _{2}^{h}=\mathbf 0 \) is a solution for the GARP conditions in Proposition 2 (and thus a fortiori also for the GARP conditions in Proposition 1). Next, if \(N=2\), one can verify that member 1 paying for the first good (i.e., \((\mathfrak p _{t}^{h})_{1}=(\mathbf p _{1})_{1})\) for all observations \(t\) and, similarly, member 2 paying for the second good (i.e., \((\mathfrak p _{t}^{h})_{2}=0\)) for all observations \(t\) obtains again a solution for the GARP conditions in Proposition 2.

  10. A similar qualification applies to the use of zeroes in Example 2.

  11. Our sample contains four types of dyads, namely, two male friends (12 in total), two female friends (14 in total), a male friend, and a female friend who do not have a romantic relationship together (13 in total), and a male and a female who are in a romantic relationship together (12 in total).

  12. Although, by definition, a private good with externalities and a public good is not the same, they are very related. As in the case of the public good, the private good with externalities enters simultaneously in both utility functions. This implies that both members have a willingness to pay for the consumption of this good, which is in our approach captured by the personalized prices. As such, if the private good with externalities is exclusively consumed by one member, we can reinterpret a public-CR as a collective rationalization with private consumption with externalities.

  13. See Cherchye et al. (2011) for a detailed discussion of this point.

  14. See Cherchye et al. (2007, 2008) for discussions on the difficulties associated with testing the general collective consumption model.

  15. We have used the integer programming methodology introduced by Cherchye et al. (2011) to test the conditions in Propositions 2 and 3 (while accounting for assignable quantities if applicable). See also our discussion in the concluding section, on the practical implementation of the revealed preference conditions under consideration.

References

  • Afriat, S.: The construction of utility functions from expenditure data. Int. Econ. Rev. 8, 67–77 (1967)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M., Chiappori, P.-A.: Efficient intra-household allocations: a general characterization and empirical tests. Econometrica 66, 1241–1278 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M., Chiappori, P.-A., Lewbel, A.: Estimating consumption economies of scale, adult equivalence scales, and household bargaining power. Boston College Working Paper WP588, Department of Economics, Boston College, version 2006 (2006)

  • Bruyneel, S., Cherchye, L., De Rock, B.: Collective consumption models with restricted bargaining weights: an empirical assessment based on experimental data. Rev. Econ. Househ. doi:10.1007/s11150-011-9125-6 (2012)

  • Cherchye, L., De Rock, B., Sabbe, J., Vermeulen, F.: Nonparametric tests of collectively rational consumption behavior: an integer programming procedure. J. Econom. 147, 258–265 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherchye, L., De Rock, B., Vermeulen, F.: The collective model of household consumption: a nonparametric characterization. Econometrica 75, 553–574 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherchye, L., De Rock, B., Vermeulen, F.: An Afriat theorem for the collective model of household consumption. J. Econ. Theory 145, 1142–1163 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherchye, L., De Rock, B., Vermeulen, F.: The revealed preference approach to collective consumption behavior: nonparametric testing and sharing rule recovery. Rev. Econ. Stud. 78, 176–198 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A.: Rational Household Labor Supply. Econometrica 56, 63–89 (1988)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A.: Collective Labor Supply and Welfare. J. Polit. Econ. 100, 437–467 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A., Ekeland, I.: The micro economics of group behavior: general characterization. J. Econ. Theory 130, 1–26 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A., Ekeland, I.: The micro economics of efficient group behavior: identification. Econometrica 77, 763–799 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert, W.E.: Afriat and revealed preference theory. Rev. Econ. Stud. 40, 419–426 (1973)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekeland, I., Galichon, A.: The housing problem and revealed preference theory: duality and an application. Econ Theory. doi:10.1007/s00199-012-0719-x (2012)

  • Fostel, A., Scarf, E., Todd, M.J.: Two new proofs of Afriat’s theorem. Econ. Theor. 24, 211–219 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach, H., Haller, H.: When inefficiency begets efficiency. Econ. Theory 25, 105–121 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harbaugh, W.T., Krause, K., Berry, T.: GARP for kids: on the development of rational choice behavior. Am. Econ. Rev. 91, 1539–1545 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houthakker, H.S.: Revealed preference and the utility function. Economica 17, 159–174 (1950)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurwicz, L.: On the problem of integrability of demand functions. In: Chipman, J., Hurwicz, L., Richter, M., Sonnenschein, H. (eds.) Preferences, Utility, and Demand. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York (1971)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollak, R.: Distinguished fellow: Houthakker’s contributions to economics. J. Econ. Perspect. 4, 141–156 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A.: A note on the pure theory of consumer behavior. Economica 5, 61–71 (1938)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sippel, R.: An experiment on the pure theory of consumer behaviour. Econ. J. 107, 1431–1444 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H.: Nonparametric approach to demand analysis. Econometrica 50, 954–973 (1982)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bram De Rock.

Additional information

We are grateful to the editor and the anonymous referee for the time invested in our manuscript. We also want to thank Georg Kirchsteiger, Paola Conconi and participants of the Dauphine Workshop “Recent Advances in Revealed Preference Theory: testable restrictions in markets and games” in Paris, the ECORE Summer School “Market Failure and Market Design” in Louvain-La-Neuve and the EEA-ESEM conference in Malaga for useful comments. Laurens Cherchye gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Research Fund K.U. Leuven through the grant STRT1/08/004. Bram De Rock gratefully acknowledges the European Research Council (ERC) for his Starting Grant.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Example 1

There exists a general-CR of S. Consider the following personalized quantities and prices:

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{1}&= (\mathbf q _{1}, \mathbf 0 , \mathbf 0 ), \widehat{ \mathbf q }_{2}=\left(\frac{1}{2} \mathbf q _{2}, \frac{1}{2}\mathbf q _{2}, \mathbf 0 \right), \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{3}=\left(\mathbf 0 , \mathbf q _{3}, \mathbf 0 \right); \\ \mathfrak p _{t}^{1}&= \mathbf p _{1}, \mathfrak p _{t}^{2}=\mathbf 0 \quad \text{ for}\; t=1,2,3. \end{aligned}$$

Then one can easily verify that the GARP conditions in Proposition 1 are satisfied for both members. This implies that there exists a general-CR of \(S\).

There exists an egoistic-CR of S. By Proposition 3 we can conclude that the above construction also shows that there exists an egoistic-CR of \(S\).

There does not exist a public-CR of S. Let us prove this ad absurdum and assume that we have a construction of feasible prices that satisfy condition (ii) in Proposition 2.

Observe that for the given set of observations we have for any \(t,s \in \{1,2,3\}\), with \(t\not = s\), that \(\mathbf p _{t}\mathbf q _{t} > \mathbf p _{t} \mathbf q _{s}\). Therefore, we must have for our solution of feasible prices that either \(\mathfrak p ^{h}_{t}\mathbf q _{t} > \mathfrak p ^{h}_{t} \mathbf q _{s}\) or \((\mathbf p _{t}-\mathfrak p ^{h}_{t})\mathbf q _{t} > ( \mathbf p _{t}-\mathfrak p ^{h}_{t})\mathbf q _{s}\). As a result, the GARP conditions in Proposition 2 require that if \(\mathfrak p ^{h}_{t}\mathbf q _{t} \ge \mathfrak p ^{h}_{t}\mathbf q _{s}\), we must have that \(\mathfrak p ^{h}_{s}\mathbf q _{s} \le \mathfrak p ^{h}_{s} \mathbf q _{t}\) and thus \((\mathbf p _{s}-\mathfrak p _{s}^{h})\mathbf q _{s} > (\mathbf p _{s}-\mathfrak p _{s}^{h})\mathbf q _{t}\). Or, alternatively, if \(\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{t} R^{1}_{0} \widehat{\mathbf{q }} _{s}\), then we must have \(\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{s} R^{2}_{0} \widehat{ \mathbf q }_{t}\). Given that this holds for any \(t,s \in \{1,2,3\}\), with \( t\not = s\), we may therefore conclude that, without losing generality, the solution of feasible prices leads to (i) \(\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{1} R^{1}_{0} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2}\) and \(\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2} R^{1}_{0} \widehat{ \mathbf q }_{3}\) for member 1 and (ii) \(\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{3} R^{2}_{0} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2}\) and \(\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2} R^{2}_{0} \widehat{ \mathbf q }_{1}\) for member 2.

Assume that \(\mathfrak p ^{h}_{2}=(\pi _{1},\pi _{2},\pi _{3})^{\prime }\). The GARP condition for member 1 in Proposition 2 requires that

$$\begin{aligned} \mathfrak p ^{h}_{2}\mathbf q _{2}\le \mathfrak p ^{h}_{2} \mathbf q _{1}\;\Leftrightarrow\;2\pi _{1}+5\pi _{2}+2\pi _{3} \le 5\pi _{1}+2\pi _{2}+2\pi _{3}\\\;\Leftrightarrow\;0\le \pi _{1}-\pi _{2}. \end{aligned}$$

The GARP condition for member 2 in Proposition 2 requires that

$$\begin{aligned} (\mathbf p _{2}-\mathfrak p _{2}^{h})\mathbf q _{2}\le (\mathbf p _{2}- \mathfrak p _{2}^{h})\mathbf q _{3}\;\Leftrightarrow\;2(1-\pi _{1})+5(4-\pi _{2})+2(1-\pi _{3}) \\&\le 2(1-\pi _{1})+2(4-\pi _{2})+5(1-\pi _{3}) \\\;\Leftrightarrow\;3\le \pi _{2}-\pi _{3}. \end{aligned}$$

Together this implies that \(3\le \pi _{2}\le \pi _{1}\), which gives us the wanted contradiction since by construction \(\pi _{1}\le 1\). We thus conclude that there cannot exists a public-CR of the data set in Example 1.

1.2 Example 2

There exists a general-CR of S. Consider the following personalized quantities and prices:

$$\begin{aligned}&\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{1}=( \mathbf 0 , \mathbf 0 , \mathbf q _{1}),\quad \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2}=(\mathbf 0 , \mathbf 0 , \mathbf q _{2}),\quad \widehat{ \mathbf q }_{3}=(\mathbf 0 , \mathbf 0 , \mathbf q _{3}),\quad \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{4}=(\mathbf 0 , \mathbf 0 , \mathbf q _{4}); \\&\mathfrak p ^{h}_{1}=(6, 2 , 2, 2)^{\prime }, \mathfrak p ^{h}_{2}=(4,3.5,0,0)^{\prime },\quad \mathfrak p ^{h}_{3}=(4,4,3.5,0)^{\prime },\quad \mathfrak p ^{h}_{4}=(2,2,2,1)^{\prime }. \end{aligned}$$

Then one can easily verify that the GARP conditions in Proposition 1 are satisfied for both members. This implies that there exists a general-CR of \(S\).

There exists a public-CR of S. By Proposition 2 we can conclude that the above construction also shows that there exists a public-CR of \(S\).

There does not exist an egoistic-CR of S. Let us prove this ad absurdum and assume that we have a construction of feasible prices that satisfy condition (ii) in Proposition 3.

Again we observe that for the given set of observations, we have for any \(t,s \in \{1,2,3,4\}\), with \(t\not = s\), that \(\mathbf p _{t}\mathbf q _{t} > \mathbf p _{t} \mathbf q _{s}\). Therefore, without losing generality, we can as before assume that the solution of feasible prices leads to (i) \(\widehat{ \mathbf q }_{1} R^{1}_{0} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2}, \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2} R^{1}_{0} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{3}\) and \(\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{3} R^{1}_{0} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{4}\) for member 1; and (ii) \(\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{4} R^{2}_{0} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{3}, \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{3} R^{1}_{0} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2}\) and \(\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2} R^{2}_{0} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{1}\) for member 2.

Assume that \(\mathfrak q ^{1}_{2}=(0,\alpha ,0, 0)\) and \(\mathfrak q ^{1}_{3}=(0, 0, \beta , 0)\). The GARP conditions for the two members in Proposition 3 require that the following holds:

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\mathbf{p }}^{1}_{2}\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2} \le \widehat{\mathbf{p }}^{1}_{2}\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{1}\;\Leftrightarrow\;7\alpha \le 4; \\ \widehat{\mathbf{p }}^{1}_{3}\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{3} \le \widehat{\mathbf{p }}^{1}_{3} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2}\;\Leftrightarrow\;7\beta \le 4\alpha \le 4; \\ \widehat{\mathbf{p }}^{2}_{2}\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{2} \le \widehat{\mathbf{p }}^{2}_{2}\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{3}\;\Leftrightarrow\;7(1-\alpha )\le 4(1-\beta )\le 4; \\ \widehat{\mathbf{p }}^{2}_{3}\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{3} \le \widehat{\mathbf{p }}^{2}_{3}\widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{4}\;\Leftrightarrow\;7(1-\beta )\le 4. \end{aligned}$$

This implies that \(\frac{3}{7}\le \alpha \le \frac{4}{7}\), \(\frac{3}{7} \le \beta \le \frac{4}{7}\) and \(\frac{7\beta }{4} \le \alpha \) and thus also that \(\alpha \ge \frac{3}{4}\). As such, we obtain the wanted contradiction, and we conclude that there cannot exist an egoistic-CR of the data set in Example 2.

1.3 Proof of Proposition 4

Example 1 of Cherchye et al. (2007) shows that there cannot exist a general-CR of \(S\) if we observe that \(\mathbf p _{1}\mathbf q _{1}\ge \mathbf p _{1}(\mathbf q _{2}+\mathbf q _{3})\), \(\mathbf p _{2}\mathbf q _{2}\ge \mathbf p _{2}(\mathbf q _{1}+\mathbf q _{3})\) and \(\mathbf p _{3} \mathbf q _{3}\ge \mathbf p _{3}(\mathbf q _{1}+\mathbf q _{2})\) holds simultaneously. Without losing generality, we assume that \(\mathbf p _{2} \mathbf q _{2}< \mathbf p _{2}(\mathbf q _{1}+\mathbf q _{3})\).

Consider the following personalized quantities and prices for an \(\alpha \in [0,1]\):

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{1}&= (\mathbf q _{1}, \mathbf 0 , \mathbf 0 ), \widehat{ \mathbf q }_{2}=(\alpha \mathbf q _{2}, (1-\alpha )\mathbf q _{2}, \mathbf 0 ), \widehat{\mathbf{q }}_{3}=(\mathbf 0 , \mathbf q _{3}, \mathbf 0 ); \\ \mathfrak p _{t}^{1}&= \mathbf p _{1}, \mathfrak p _{t}^{2}=\mathbf 0 \quad \text{ for} \; t=1,2,3. \end{aligned}$$

These feasible prices and quantities are consistent with the collective model with only private goods (i.e., \(\mathfrak q _{t}^{h}=\mathbf 0 \)) and egoistic preferences (i.e., \(\mathfrak p _{t}^{1}=\mathbf p _{t}\) and \( \mathfrak p _{t}^{2}=\mathbf 0 \)).

Given that \(\mathbf p _{2}\mathbf q _{2}< \mathbf p _{2}(\mathbf q _{1}+ \mathbf q _{3})\), there must exist an \(\alpha \in [0,1]\) such that \(\alpha \mathbf p _{2}\mathbf q _{2}< \mathbf p _{2}\mathbf q _{1}\) and \((1-\alpha ) \mathbf p _{2}\mathbf q _{2}< \mathbf p _{2}\mathbf q _{3}\). One can then easily verify that for such an \(\alpha \) the GARP conditions in Proposition 3 are satisfied for both members. This implies that there exists an egoistic-CR of \(S\).\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cherchye, L., De Rock, B. & Platino, V. Private versus public consumption within groups: testing the nature of goods from aggregate data. Econ Theory 54, 485–500 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-012-0729-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-012-0729-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation