Skip to main content
Log in

Mechanism design for land acquisition

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Journal of Game Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider the issue of designing Bayesian incentive-compatible, efficient, individually rational and balanced mechanisms for Land Acquisition. This is a problem of great practical importance in developing countries. Several sellers, each with one unit of land, are located at the nodes of a graph. Two sellers are contiguous if they are connected by an edge in the graph. The buyer realizes a positive value only if he can purchase plots that constitute a path of given length. Our main result is that there is a robust set of priors for which successful mechanisms exist when there are at least two distinct feasible sets of contiguous sellers. The analysis also identifies the role of critical sellers who lie on all such feasible sets.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Eminent domain is an important topic in the sub-discipline Law and Economics. See Miceli (2011).

  2. The case of Kelo vs. City of New London, 2005, in the United States (Wikipedia 2014a), or the case of State-led land acquisition in Singur, West Bengal (India) in 2006 (Wikipedia 2014b) highlight these issues.

  3. In expected terms.

  4. Groves (1973) proposed this class of mechanisms that are dominant strategy incentive compatible and ex-post efficient.

  5. See Makowski and Mezzetti (1994) and Schweizer (2006) for other characterizations of possibility.

  6. A similar problem has been extensively studied in the algorithmic branch of mechanism design. Shortest Path Auctions study the problem where a buyer wishes to purchase a set of edges that form a path from a specified source to a sink. This was introduced by Bikhchandani et al. (2002) and followed up in a series of papers.

  7. Apart from the literature on mechanism design, holdouts have been investigated in the framework of bargaining under complete information (Cai 2000, 2003; Menezes and Pitchford 2004; Roy Chowdhury and Sengupta 2012; Xiao 2010). These contributions primarily look at the possibility of holdout in different models of bargaining with one buyer and multiple sellers.

  8. It is sufficient to denote allocation by the n-vector \((x_{1},\ldots , x_{n})\) of seller allocations. However, we find the current notation more convenient.

  9. In the example shown in Fig. 7, this term is \((10+2+3)+ (1+10+3)+(1+2+10)- 2(1+2+3)= 30\).

  10. I am grateful to an Associate Editor of this journal for pointing this out.

  11. The VCG satisfies a stronger incentive compatibility condition, viz., dominant strategy incentive compatibility (DSIC), that requires every agent to be truthful for any report of other agents. It is easy to check that DSIC implies BIC, but not vice-versa.

References

  • Bikhchandani S, de Vries S, Schummer J, Vohra RV (2002) Linear programming and vickrey auctions. Math Internet E-auction Markets 127:75–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai H (2000) Delay in multilateral bargaining under complete information. J Econ Theory 93:260–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai H (2003) Inefficient Markov perfect equilibria in multilateral bargaining. Econ Theory 22(3):583–606

  • Chatterjee K, Samuelson W (1983) Bargaining under incomplete information. Oper Res 31:835–851

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke EH (1971) Multipart pricing of public goods. Public Choice 11:17–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cramton P, Gibbons R, Klemperer P (1987) Dissolving a partnership efficiently. Econometrica 55:615–632

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghatak M, Ghosh P (2011) The land acquisition bill: a critique and a proposal. Econ Polit Wkly 46:65

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghatak M, Mitra S, Mookherjee D, Nath A (2013) Land acquisition and compensation: what really happened in Singur? Econ Polit Wkly 48(21):32–44

  • Grossman Z, Pincus J, Shapiro P (2010) A second-best mechanism for land assembly, Working paper

  • Groves T (1973) Incentives in teams. Econometrica 41:617–631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson MO (2000) Mechanism theory. In: Derigs. U (ed) The encyclopedia of life support systems. EOLSS Publishers, Paris, France

  • Kominers SD, Weyl EG (2011) Concordance among holdouts. In: Proceedings of the 12th ACM conference on electronic commerce, ACM, pp 219–220

  • Kominers SD, Weyl EG (2012) Holdout in the assembly of complements: a problem for market design. Am Econ Rev 102:360–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishna V (2002) Auction theory. Academic Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Krishna V, Perry M (2000) Efficient mechanism design, Working Paper

  • Lehmann D, Oćallaghan L, Shoham Y (2002) Truth revelation in approximately efficient combinatorial auctions. J ACM (JACM) 49:577–602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makowski L, Mezzetti C (1993) The possibility of efficient mechanisms for trading an indivisible object. J Econ Theory 59:451–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makowski L, Mezzetti C (1994) Bayesian and weakly robust first best mechanisms: characterizations. J Econ Theory 64:500–519

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAfee RP (1991) Efficient allocation with continuous quantities. J Econ Theory 53:51–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menezes F, Pitchford R (2004) A model of seller holdout. Econ Theory 24(2):231–253

  • Miceli TJ (2011) The economic theory of eminent domain: private property, public use. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson R, Satterthwaite M (1983) Efficient mechanisms for bilateral trading. J Econ Theory 29:265–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plassmann F, Tideman T (2010) Providing incentives for efficient land assembly, Tech. rep., working paper

  • Roy Chowdhury P, Sengupta K (2012) Transparency, complementarity and holdout. Games Econ Behav 75:598–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences (2007) Scientific bacground on mechanism design theory. http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/2007/advanced-economicsciences2007.pdf

  • Schweizer U (2006) Universal possibility and impossibility results. Games Econ Behav 57:73–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh R (2012) Inefficiency and abuse of compulsory land acquisition: an enquiry into the way forward, CDE Working Paper No. 209

  • Vickrey W (1961) Counterspeculation, auctions and competitive selaed tenders. J Financ 16:8–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wikipedia (2014a) Kelo v. City of New London—Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia

  • Wikipedia (2014b) Singur Tata Nano controversy—Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia

  • Williams SR (1999) A characterization of efficient, Bayesian incentive compatible mechanisms. Econ Theory 14:155–180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xiao J (2010) Bargaining order in a multi-person bargaining game. Available at SSRN 1685463

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Soumendu Sarkar.

Additional information

This paper contains results from my Ph.D. thesis submitted at Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi. I am grateful to my supervisor Prof. Arunava Sen for his guidance. I am also thankful to Professors Avinash Dixit, Vincent Merlin, Debasis Mishra, Rakesh Vohra and two anonymous referees for their useful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Appendices

Appendix

A The VCG mechanism

Here we present the well-known VCG mechanism and mention a related result derived by Williams (1999) and Krishna and Perry (2000) that will be useful for our analysis. We will be closely following the notation of the textbook by Krishna (2002) who also presents these results.

The VCG mechanism is a generalization of the second-price auction scheme conceived by Vickrey (1961). The VCG payment for each agent is interpreted as the externality she imposes on other agents.

Let \(SW(v)=\sum _{j=0}^{n}v_jP_{j}^{*}(v)\) and \(SW_{-j}(v)=\sum _{i\ne j}v_{i}P_{i}^{*}(v)\).

Definition 8

(VCG mechanism) The VCG mechanism is the pair \((P^{*}, t^{V})\) where \(P^{*}\) is an efficient allocation rule and \(t_{j}^{V}\), \(j=0,\ldots , n\), is defined for all profiles v as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} t_{0}^{V}(v)= & {} SW(\underline{v}_{0}, v_{-0})-SW_{-0}(v) \end{aligned}$$
(14)
$$\begin{aligned} t_{i}^{V}(v)= & {} SW(\bar{v}, v_{-i})-SW_{-i}(v) \quad \hbox {for } i=1,\ldots , n. \end{aligned}$$
(15)

It is well-known that the VCG mechanism is efficient, BICFootnote 11, interim individually rational but not budget-balanced.

Example 6

In Example 1 let us suppose that the valuation for both agents lie in [0, 1], so that, \(\underline{v}_{0}=0\) and \(\bar{v}=1\). The efficient rule is to transfer the good to the buyer if \(v_{0}>v_{1}\), and not to transfer if \(v_{0}\le v_{1}\). Then \(SW(v)=v_{0}-v_{1}\) if \(v_{0}>v_{1}\) and 0 otherwise. Using this we get, \(t_{0}^{V}(v)=SW(0,v_{1})-SW_{1}(v_{0},v_{1})\) which is \(v_{1}\) if \(v_{0}>v_{1}\) and 0 otherwise. Similarly, \(t_{1}^{V}(v)=SW(v_{0},1)-SW_{0}(v_{0},v_{1})\) which is \(-v_{0}\) if \(v_{0}>v_{1}\) and 0 otherwise. Thus the sum of payments is \(v_{1}-v_{0}\) if \(v_{0}>v_{1}\) and 0 otherwise. For all profiles where \(v_{0}>v_{1}\), budget balance is violated.

The following Proposition is central to the proof of our main result. See Krishna (2002) for a proof of this result that explicitly constructs a successful mechanism when the given condition is true.

Proposition 1

(WKP) There exists a successful mechanism if and only if the VCG mechanism generates a non-negative expected surplus, i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} E \left( \sum _{j=0}^{n} t_{j}^{V} (v)\right) \ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

The Proposition can be used to prove the Myerson–Satterthwaite impossibility result. To see this, observe that in Example 6, the sum of VCG payments is negative if \(v_{0}>v_{1}\) and 0 otherwise. Therefore, the expectation of this sum is negative. An application of the Proposition yields the result immediately.

B Proof of Theorem 1

Part A. We rely on Proposition 1 and compute the expected value of the sum of VCG payments.

In Part I, we will show that for all v,

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}&\ge \underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)}S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})+(k-1)S_{[1]}(v). \end{aligned}$$

If (2) holds, then the expected sum of payments is non-negative and the result follows by an application of Proposition 1.

The VCG payment of the buyer is given by Lemma 1.

Lemma 1

The VCG payment of the buyer is given by

$$\begin{aligned} t_{0}^{V}(v)&= \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \underline{v}_{0} &{}\quad \hbox {if } v_{0}\ge \underline{v}_{0}>S_{[1]}(v),\\ S_{[1]}(v)&{}\quad \hbox {if } v_{0}> S_{[1]}(v)\ge \underline{v}_{0},\\ 0 &{}\quad \hbox {if } \underline{v}_{0}\le v_{0}\le S_{[1]}(v). \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

Proof

If \(v_{0}\ge \underline{v}_{0}>S_{[1]}(v)\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\underline{v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=\underline{v}_{0}-S_{[1]}(v),\\ \hbox {and } SW_{-0}({v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=-S_{[1]}(v).\\ \hbox {Hence } t_{0}^{V}(v)&=\underline{v}_{0}. \end{aligned}$$

If \(v_{0}> S_{[1]}(v)\ge \underline{v}_{0}\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\underline{v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=0, \\ \hbox {and }SW_{-0}({v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=-S_{[1]}(v). \\ \hbox {Hence } t_{0}^{V}(v)&=S_{[1]}(v). \end{aligned}$$

If \(v_{0}\le S_{[1]}(v)\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\underline{v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=0,\\ \hbox {and }SW_{-0}({v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=0.\\ \hbox {Hence }t_{0}^{V}(v)&=0. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

For the VCG payment of the sellers, we refer to the next two Lemmas.

Lemma 2

The VCG payment of any seller \(i\in \mathcal {P}_{[j]}(v)\backslash \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v), j>1\), is 0.

Proof

Let \(v_{0}> S_{[1]}(v)\). For any seller \(i\in \mathcal {P}_{[j]}(v)\backslash \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v), j>1\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\bar{v},v_{-i})&=v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v),\\ \hbox {and }SW_{-i}(v_{i},v_{-i})&=v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v).\\ \hbox {Hence } t_{i}^{V}(v)&=0. \end{aligned}$$

If \(v_{0}\le S_{[1]}(v)\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\bar{v},v_{-i})&=0, \\ \hbox {and }SW_{-i}(v_{i},v_{-i})&=0. \\ \hbox {Hence } t_{i}^{V}(v)&=0. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Lemma 3

The VCG payment of any seller \(i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\), is given by

$$\begin{aligned} t_{i}^{V}(v)&= \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} -(v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i} ) &{}\quad \hbox {if } S_{[1]}(v)< v_{0}\le S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i}),\\ -(S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}) &{}\quad \hbox {if } S_{[1]}(v) \le S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})< v_{0},\\ 0 &{}\quad \hbox {if } v_{0}\le S_{[1]}(v) \le S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i}).\end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

Proof

If \(S_{[1]}(v)< v_{0}\le S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\bar{v},v_{-i})&=0,\\ \hbox {and }SW_{-i}(v_{i},v_{-i})&=v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i} .\\ \hbox {Hence } t_{i}^{V}(v)&=-(v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}). \end{aligned}$$

If \(S_{[1]}(v) \le S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})< v_{0}\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\bar{v},v_{-i})&=v_{0}-S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i}),\\ \hbox {and }SW_{-i}(v_{i},v_{-i})&=v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}. \\ \hbox {Hence } t_{i}^{V}(v)&=-(S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}). \end{aligned}$$

If \(v_{0}\le S_{[1]}(v) \le S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\bar{v},v_{-i})&=0,\\ \hbox {and }SW_{-i}(v_{i},v_{-i})&=0. \\ \hbox {Hence } t_{i}^{V}(v)&=0. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

When \(q>1\), let \(A(v)=\{h\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}: S_{[1]}(v)< v_{0}\le S_{[1]}(\bar{v}, v_{-i})\}\). As before, A(v) represents the set of trade-pivotal sellers at profile v: they influence the possibility of trade by reporting their highest valuation.

Then we have the following cases for \(\sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)\).

Case I \(v_{0}\ge \underline{v}_{0}>S_{[1]}(v)\) and \(A(v)\ne \emptyset \)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)&=\underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{i\in A(v)} \left( v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}\right) -\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}\right) \\&=\underline{v}_{0}-|A(v)|\left( v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)\right) -\sum _{i\in A(v)}v_{i} \\&\quad -\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)\right) -\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} v_{i}\\&=\underline{v}_{0}-S_{[1]}(v) -|A(v)|\left( v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)\right) -\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)\right) \\&\le 0. \end{aligned}$$

The first equality follows from Lemmas 1, 2 and 3. The second follows by taking the \(v_{i}\) terms out from the parentheses. The next equality sums these \(v_{i}\) terms up to \(S_{[1]}(v)\). The inequality follows because \(\underline{v}_{0}\le v_{0}\) and A(v) is nonempty.

Case II \(v_{0}\ge \underline{v}_{0}>S_{[1]}(v)\) and \(A(v)= \emptyset \)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)= & {} \underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}\right) \\= & {} \underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)\right) -S_{[1]}(v)\\= & {} \underline{v}_{0}+(k-1) S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i}) \end{aligned}$$

The first equality follows from Lemmas 1, 2 and 3. The second follows by taking out the \(v_{i}\) terms out of the parentheses. The third follows by taking out the \(S_{[1]}(v)\) terms out of the parentheses and collecting them together. The sign of the resulting expression can be positive or negative, as examples will show.

Case III \(v_{0}> S_{[1]}(v)\ge \underline{v}_{0}\) and \(A(v)\ne \emptyset \)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)&=S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in A(v)} \left( v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}\right) \\&\quad -\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}\right) \\&=S_{[1]}(v)-|A(v)|\left( v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)\right) -\sum _{i\in A(v)}v_{i} \\&\quad -\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)\right) -\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} v_{i}\\&=-|A(v)|\left( v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)\right) -\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)\right) \\&< 0. \end{aligned}$$

The first equality follows from Lemmas 1, 2 and 3. The second follows by taking out the \(v_{i}\) terms out of the parentheses. The third follows after canceling out the \(S_{[1]}(v)\)’s. The resulting expression is nonpositive since \(v_{0}> S_{[1]}(v)\) and \(S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})\ge S_{[1]}(v)\).

Case IV \(v_{0}> S_{[1]}(v)\ge \underline{v}_{0}\) and \(A(v)= \emptyset \)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)&=S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)\right) -S_{[1]}(v)\\&=-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)\right) \\&\le 0. \end{aligned}$$

The first equality follows from Lemmas 1, 2 and 3. The second follows by taking out the \(v_{i}\) terms out of the parentheses. The third follows after canceling out the \(S_{[1]}(v)\)’s. The resulting expression is nonpositive since \(S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})\ge S_{[1]}(v)\).

Case V \(v_{0}\le S_{[1]}(v)\)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)&=0. \end{aligned}$$

These cases are summarized in Table 1.

Lemma 4

For all v,

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)&\ge \underline{v}_{0}+(k-1) S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i}). \end{aligned}$$

Proof

For \(i\in A(v)\), \(v_{0}\le S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})\). Therefore, in Case I of Table 1,

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)&= \underline{v}_{0}-S_{[1]}(v) -|A(v)|(v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v))-\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} (S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)) \\&\ge \underline{v}_{0}-S_{[1]}(v) -\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} (S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v))\\&= \underline{v}_{0}+(k-1) S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i}). \end{aligned}$$

In Case II, \(\sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)= \underline{v}_{0}+(k-1) S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})\).

In Case III,

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)&= -|A(v)|(v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v))-\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} (S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v))\\&= S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in A(v)} \left( v_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}\right) \\&\quad -\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}\right) \\&\ge S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)+v_{i}\right) \\&\ge \underline{v}_{0}+(k-1) S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i}). \end{aligned}$$

In Case IV,

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)&= -\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} (S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v))\\&=S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})- S_{[1]}(v)\right) -S_{[1]}(v)\\&\ge \underline{v}_{0}+(k-1) S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i}). \end{aligned}$$

In Case V,

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)&= 0 \ge \underline{v}_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)\\&\ge \underline{v}_{0}-S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} \left( S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})-S_{[1]}(v)\right) \\&= \underline{v}_{0}+(k-1) S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i}). \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

If (2) holds, Lemma 4 implies

$$\begin{aligned}&E\left( \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)\right) \ge \underline{v}_{0}+(k-1)E\left( S_{[1]}(v)\right) -E\left( \sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})\right) \ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

Part I now follows by Proposition 1.

For part II, note that the profiles in \(\tilde{V}\) correspond to Case II of Table 1 and all other profiles correspond to the other Cases. If a successful mechanism exists then by Proposition 1,

$$\begin{aligned} 0&\le E\left( \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)\right) \\&= E\left( \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)\Bigg | v\in \tilde{V}\right) \times \Pr \left( v\in \tilde{V}\right) \\&\quad +E\left( \sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)\Bigg |v\notin \tilde{V} \right) \times \Pr \left( v\notin \tilde{V} \right) \end{aligned}$$

The second component of this sum of products is negative since \(\sum _{j=0}^{n}t_{j}^{V}(v)\) takes negative or zero value when \(v\notin \tilde{V}\). Therefore,

$$\begin{aligned} E\left( \sum _{j=0}^{n} t_{j}^{V}(v)\Bigg | v\in \tilde{V}\right)&>0 \end{aligned}$$

Since \(\sum _{j=0}^{n} t_{j}^{V}(v)= \underline{v}_{0}+(k-1) S_{[1]}(v)-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)} S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})\) when \(v\in \tilde{V}\), the claim follows.

By Proposition 1, a successful mechanism exists if and only if the expected sum of VCG payments is non-negative. In Lemma 4, we showed that the sum of VCG payments is bounded below by \(\underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)}S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})+(k-1)S_{[1]}(v)\) at any profile v. Part I of Theorem 1 is a direct consequence of this Lemma. For Part II, note that the set \(\tilde{V}\) corresponds to Case II in Table 1. For all \(v\in \tilde{V}\), \(\underline{v}_{0}>S_{[1]}(v)\), i.e., trade takes place at \((\underline{v}_{0}, v_{-0})\) and therefore, also at v. Furthermore, \(v_{0}>S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})\) for all \(i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)\): trade takes place if any seller i, who is successful at v, changes his valuation to \(\bar{v}\). Therefore, no successful seller at v is trade-pivotal, i.e., the set A(v) is empty. According to Table 1, the sum of VCG payments, \(\underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{i\in \mathcal {P}_{[1]}(v)}S_{[1]}(\bar{v},v_{-i})+(k-1)S_{[1]}(v)\), can be positive only at such profiles. For all other profiles the sum of VCG payments is non-positive. It follows that the conditional expectation in Condition 3 must be positive in order for the expected sum of VCG payments to be non-negative.

Part B. First, we omit all isolated paths of length less than k. Since the VCG mechanism is efficient, trade would have never taken place with sellers on such paths. Consequently, their VCG payments would have been zero in any case. The sellers on the unique feasible path are labelled \(1,\ldots , k\). We will show that the sum of VCG payments \(\sum _{j=0}^{k}t_{j}^{V}\) is nonpositive at all profiles and negative in some interval of profiles. Therefore, its expectation is negative. The result follows by applying Proposition 1.

We have

$$\begin{aligned} SW(v)=\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} v_0 - \sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{k}v_{i} &{}\quad \hbox {if } v_0 > \sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{k}v_{i},\\ 0&{}\quad \hbox {otherwise.} \end{array}\right. \end{aligned}$$

The next lemmas specify the VCG payments for the agents.

Lemma 5

The VCG payment of the buyer is given by

$$\begin{aligned} t_{0}^{V}(v)&= \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \underline{v}_{0} &{}\quad \hbox {if } v_{0}\ge \underline{v}_{0}>\sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{k}v_{i},\\ \sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{k}v_{i} &{}\quad \hbox {if } v_{0}> \sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\ge \underline{v}_{0},\\ 0 &{}\quad \hbox {if } \underline{v}_{0}\le v_{0}\le \sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}. \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

Proof

If \(v_{0}\ge \underline{v}_{0}>\sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\underline{v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=\underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i},\\ \hbox {and } SW_{-0}({v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=-\sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}.\\ \hbox {Hence } t_{0}^{V}(v)&=\underline{v}_{0}. \end{aligned}$$

If \(v_{0}> \sum _{i=1}^{n}v_{i}\ge \underline{v}_{0}\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\underline{v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=0, \\ \hbox {and }SW_{-0}({v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=-\sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}. \\ \hbox {Hence } t_{0}^{V}(v)&=\sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}. \end{aligned}$$

If \(v_{0}\le \sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\underline{v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=0,\\ \hbox {and }SW_{-0}({v}_{0}, v_{-0})&=0.\\ \hbox {Hence }t_{0}^{V}(v)&=0. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Lemma 6

When \(q=1\), the VCG payment of the seller corresponding to \(v_{i}\), \(i=1, \ldots , n\), is given by

$$\begin{aligned} t_{i}^{V}(v)&=\left\{ \begin{array}{ll}-\left( v_{0}-\sum \nolimits _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j} \right) &{}\quad \hbox {if } \sum \nolimits _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j}+\bar{v}\ge v_{0}>\sum \nolimits _{j=1}^{k }v_{j}, \\ -\bar{v} &{}\quad \hbox {if } v_{0}> \sum \nolimits _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j}+\bar{v}\ge \sum \nolimits _{j=1}^{k }v_{j}, \\ 0 &{}\quad \hbox {if } v_{0}\le \sum \nolimits _{j=1}^{k }v_{j} \le \sum \nolimits _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j}+\bar{v}. \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

Proof

If \(\sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j}+\bar{v}\ge v_{0} >\sum _{j=1}^{k }v_{j}\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\bar{v},v_{-i})&=0,\\ \hbox {and }SW_{-i}(v_{i},v_{-i})&=v_{0}-\sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j}. \\ \hbox {Hence } t_{i}^{V}(v)&=-\left( v_{0}-\sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

If \(v_{0}> \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j}+\bar{v}\ge \sum _{j=1}^{k }v_{j}\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\bar{v},v_{-i})&= v_{0}- \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j}-\bar{v},\\ \hbox {and }SW_{-i}(v_{i},v_{-i})&=v_{0}-\sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j}.\\ \hbox {Hence } t_{i}^{V}(v)&=-\bar{v}. \end{aligned}$$

If \(v_{0}\le \sum _{j=1}^{n }v_{j}\le \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1\\ j\ne i \end{array}}^k {v}_{j}+\bar{v}\),

$$\begin{aligned} SW(\bar{v},v_{-i})&= 0, \\ \hbox {and }SW_{-i}(v_{i},v_{-i})&=0.\\ \hbox {Hence } t_{i}^{V}(v)&=0. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

For any profile v, let \(A(v)=\{h\in \{1, \ldots , k\}: \sum _{i=1}^k {v}_{i}<v_{0}\le \sum _{\begin{array}{c} i=1\\ i\ne h \end{array}}^k {v}_i +\bar{v}\}\). In other words, A(v) is the set of sellers who influence the possibility of trade by reporting their highest valuation. Such sellers will be referred to as trade-pivotal.

Different mutually exclusive and exhaustive cases and corresponding sum of payments as obtained from Lemmas 5 and 6 are presented below.

Case I \(v_{0}\ge \underline{v}_{0}>\sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\) and \(A(v)\ne \emptyset \)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{k}t_{j}^{V}(v)= & {} \underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{h\in A(v)} \left( v_{0}-\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i=1\\ i\ne h \end{array}}^k {v}_{i} \right) -\left( k-|A(v)|\right) \bar{v}\\= & {} \underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{h\in A(v)} v_{0}+\sum _{h\in A(v)}\sum _{i=1}^k {v}_{i}-\sum _{h\in A(v)}v_{[h]} -\left( k-|A(v)|\right) \bar{v}\\= & {} \left( \underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{h\in A(v)}v_{[h]}-\left( k-|A(v)|\right) \bar{v}\right) -\sum _{h\in A(v)}\left( v_{0}-\sum _{i=1}^{k} v_{i}\right) \\\le & {} \left( \underline{v}_{0}-\sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i} \right) -\sum _{h\in A(v)}\left( v_{0}-\sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\right) \\\le & {} 0. \end{aligned}$$

Here, \(k-|A(v)|\) is the number of sellers not in A(v) at profile v. The second equality is obtained by expanding \(\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i=1\\ i\ne h \end{array}}^k {v}_{i}\); the third is obtained by re-arranging terms; the first inequality holds since \(v_{i}\le \bar{v}\) for any \(i=1, \ldots , k\) and the second inequality holds since \(v_{0}\ge \underline{v}_{0}\).

Case II \(v_{0}\ge \underline{v}_{0}>\sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\) and \(A(v)= \emptyset \)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{k}t_{j}^{V}(v)= & {} \underline{v}_{0}-k\bar{v}\\< & {} 0. \end{aligned}$$

This holds by virtue of the assumption \(\underline{v}_{0}<k\bar{v}\).

Case III \(v_{0}> \sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\ge \underline{v}_{0}\) and \(A(v)\ne \emptyset \)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{k}t_{j}^{V}(v)= & {} \sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}-\sum _{h\in A(v)}\left( v_{0}-\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i=1\\ i\ne h \end{array}}^k {v}_{i}\right) -\left( k-|A(v)|\right) \bar{v}\\= & {} \sum _{h\in A(v)}v_{h} +\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i=1\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}}^{k} v_{i}-\sum _{h\in A(v)}\left( v_{0}-\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i=1\\ i\ne h \end{array}}^k {v}_{i}\right) -\left( k-|A(v)|\right) \bar{v}\\= & {} -\sum _{h \in A(v)}\left( v_{0}-\sum _{i=1}^{k} {v}_{i}\right) +\sum _{\begin{array}{c} i=1\\ i\notin A(v) \end{array}}^{k}\left( v_{i}-\bar{v}\right) \\< & {} 0. \end{aligned}$$

The second equality is obtained by expanding \(\sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\); the third adds the first and the third term of the left hand side to obtain the first term, and the other two terms constitute the second term. The inequality follows because \(v_{0}> \sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\) and \(v_{i}\le \bar{v}\) for \(i= 1, \ldots , k\).

Case IV \(v_{0}> \sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\ge \underline{v}_{0}\) and \(A(v)= \emptyset \)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{k}t_{j}^{V}(v)= & {} \sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}-k\bar{v}\\= & {} \sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}-k\bar{v}\\< & {} 0. \end{aligned}$$

The inequality follows because \(v_{i}\le \bar{v}\) for \(i= 1, \ldots , k\).

Case V \(v_{0}\le \sum _{i=1}^{k}v_{i}\)

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{j=0}^{k}t_{j}^{V}(v)&=0. \end{aligned}$$

The calculations are summarized in Table 2. Observe that for any profile v, \(\sum _{j=0}^{k}t_{j}^{V}(v)\le 0\) and in Cases II, III and IV, \(\sum _{j=0}^{k}t_{j}^{V}(v)< 0\). Therefore, as required,

$$\begin{aligned} E\left( \sum _{j=0}^{k}t_{j}^{V}(v)\right)&<0. \end{aligned}$$
Table 2 Sum of payments when \(q=1\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sarkar, S. Mechanism design for land acquisition. Int J Game Theory 46, 783–812 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-016-0556-4

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-016-0556-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation