Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Distributional and welfare effects of Germany’s year 2000 tax reform: the context of savings and portfolio choice

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper empirically investigates distributional and welfare effects of Germany’s year 2000 tax reform in the context of the household savings decision and the allocation of wealth to a portfolio of assets. The reform is simulated in an ex ante behavioural microsimulation approach. Behavioural responses resulting from changes in capital income taxation are estimated in an empirical demand model for household savings and asset allocation, which is applied to German survey data. Significant reductions in tax rates result in income gains for most of the households. Gains are found to be greater for households in higher tax brackets, whereby income inequality increases, in particular in East Germany. Moreover, households increase savings and alter the structure of asset demand as a result of shifts in relative asset prices. As a result, utility losses reduce welfare effects for almost all households, in particular for households with greater savings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The reform brought about a total annual tax relief of 32 bn euros, of which about 27 bn euros was related to changes in personal income taxation (Bundesministerium der Finanzen 2004). As a consequence, families, employees, and non-incorporated medium-sized enterprises were meant to benefit most from the reform.

  2. In reflections on the Mirrlees Review, Keuschnigg (2011) stresses the importance of extending existing computational models for meaningful quantification of the gains and costs of reforms to the taxation of capital income.

  3. Domeij and Heathcote (2004) focus on the relevance of household heterogeneity for the welfare implications of cuts to capital income tax rates.

  4. Tuttle and Gauger (2006) find that distributional effects of the former are usually permanent, whereas the latter have rather transitory relevance.

  5. This literature relates to the seminal paper by Feldstein (1976). For a recent analysis, see Poterba and Samwick (2002). For example, Michel and Ahmad (2012) investigate incentives to reallocate assets intertemporally in response to the implementation of a child tax credit in the USA. An analysis for Germany can be found in Lang (1998).

  6. Simultaneously to this reform, the child benefit and child allowance were altered, and a reform of the taxation of old-age pension income was implemented in 2005. These adjustments shall not be considered in this analysis.

  7. This implies that the fiscal budget is unbalanced in the short run through the reform. For the long run, it can be assumed that the fiscal budget is to be balanced, such that the income gains through the reform could be partly (or entirely) drawn back from the households, also see the discussion in Sect. 5. In fact, the major financing elements of the reform were meant to be adjustments of depreciation rules for companies’ assets, which are, however, not considered here (Bundesministerium der Finanzen 2004).

  8. For a consistent treatment of durable consumption, durable goods are treated as investments, following Jalava and Kavonius (2009), and user costs are computed.

  9. In the classical Keynesian framework, savings only depend on current income. The literature motivates the relevance of current income with either liquidity constraints, or myopia, or savings for precautionary motives (e.g. Browning and Lusardi 1996).

  10. Service flows of an asset may involve the return to investment, risk-related attributes, transaction-related characteristics, and other asset-specific services. These are obviously not structural utility parameters, but it shall be assumed that they are invariant to the tax reform.

  11. These two models imply various assumptions on separability of the single decisions. It is assumed that the intertemporal consumption decision and the asset allocation decision are separable from the labour supply decision and that the asset allocation decisions in the two clusters are separable from each other. Separability is tested in Ochmann (2013).

  12. \(p_{ik}\) implies household-specific asset prices. Prices vary over the households by heterogeneity in after-tax rates of return, resulting from heterogeneity in marginal tax rates and in the portfolios.

  13. If income, and thus probably also savings, is concentrated beyond this income threshold (Bach et al. 2009), relevant asset demand responses of the top-income households are missed in this analysis. If these are relevant in size, which the results in Sect. 5.3 suggest, then the true distributional and welfare effects would be greater. The results should thus be interpreted as lower bound results. Note further that while the income distribution is top-coded in the EVS, the distribution of wealth is not. In particular, wealth is observed jointly with income and savings, so that there is no need to estimate or impute the wealth distribution from external data, as it is often the case with microdata on income and consumption.

  14. Note that applying the LWR from six waves between 2002 and 2007 is consistent with an ex ante evaluation of the tax reform that took place between 1998 and 2005, because the LWR data are only used to estimate the interest rate elasticity of compound savings in the first model. This elasticity is used to derive the savings demand effects of the reform. However, the reform is simulated only on the 1998 wave of the EVS data.

  15. Given that microdata are not available for every year, an ex ante analysis appears preferable. For an ex post analysis, additional assumptions on the development of asset demand during the last reform year (2005) and the latest year for which microdata are available (2008) would be needed.

  16. For a survey on behavioural microsimulation models in the context of public redistribution policies, see Bourguignon and Spadaro (2006).

  17. For a study of effects of tax reforms on asset prices and other markets in a general equilibrium framework, see inter alia Hall (1996).

  18. As Hicksian demand functions are first derivatives of the cost function, integration over the interval of a price change yields differences in costs of reaching the same indifference curve at two distinct price vectors (see Deaton and Muellbauer 1980, pp. 184–186).

  19. Alternatively, social utility weights could vary over the households, and inequality aversion could be introduced. This would put a higher weight on households with relatively lower income and a lower weight on households with relatively higher income. The results in Sect. 5 indicate that such weighting would reduce the aggregate welfare effects of the reform, as welfare effects increase by income and they are even slightly negative in the lower income deciles. The results found for the utilitarian welfare function shall be compared to welfare effects for an income-weighted welfare function in future research.

  20. This decrease in the after-tax savings price corresponds to an increase in the rate of the return of about 0.20 % points, e.g. from 5.0 to 5.2 %. The prices computed here for the asset clusters are composite price indices, generated as weighted averages over the prices of the underlying single assets, where the weights are sample-average portfolio shares of asset holdings, which are assumed exogenous to the decision of allocating savings. By a composition effect, the decrease in the price for savings is stronger here than the decrease in the price for housing assets.

  21. First-round distributional effects turn out to be structurally very similar to second-round effects for this reform. Demand responses reduce income gains only marginally on average. On the one hand, households substitute assets that became relatively more expensive through the reform for relatively cheaper assets. On the other hand, a strong income effect dominates the substitution effect for some relatively more expensive assets, or it adds to it in the case of stocks. The compound effect over all assets slightly reduces aggregate capital income for an average household. First-round distributional effects can be found in Ochmann (2010).

  22. If demand responses are neglected, budget effects are positive for 69 % of all households in the population. They are negative for 8 %, and some 23 % are unaffected by immediate budget effects. Households are unaffected by the reform, before behavioural response, if their pre-reform taxable income is below the tax-exempt allowance and no other changes apply. If other changes, related to the broadening of the tax base or to the effect of “bracket creep”, apply in addition households may actually lose from the reform.

  23. Maiterth and Müller (2009) further qualify this result in the context of tax equity, applying a measure for the distribution of the tax burden, and find that increasing income inequality does not necessarily allow the conclusion that the reform increased tax inequity.

  24. Note that this increase in asset prices is related to the average price differential over all single assets. The decrease in the price for savings of 0.20 % is offset by increases in prices for other assets here.

  25. Haan and Steiner (2005) find that labour supply effects let the income gains increase on average by an additional 126 euros in annual net household income, compared to 725 euros without labour supply effects (an additional 0.5 %-points of pre-reform income). Haan (2007) moreover finds that welfare effects are on average 34 % (153 euros in annual equivalent income) lower than income gains (449 euros) if labour supply effects are accounted for.

References

  • Alan S, Atalay K, Crossley T, Jeon S-H (2010) New evidence on taxes and portfolio choice. J Public Econ 94:813–823

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio O, Wakefield M (2010) The effects on consumption and saving of taxing asset returns. In: Adam S, Besley T, Blundell R, Bond S, Chote R, Gammie M, Johnson P, Myles G, Poterba J (eds) Dimensions of tax design: the mirrlees review. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York, pp 675–736

    Google Scholar 

  • Bach S, Corneo G, Steiner V (2009) From the bottom to the top: the entire income distribution in Germany, 1992–2003. Rev Income Wealth 55(2):303–330

  • Banks J, Blundell R, Lewbel A (1996) Tax reform and welfare measurement: do we need demand system estimation? Econ J 106(438):1227–1241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banks J, Blundell R, Lewbel A (1997) Quadratic engel curves and consumer demand. Rev Econ Stat 79(4):527–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim D (2002) Taxation and saving. In: Auerbach AJ, Feldstein M (eds) Handbook of public economics, vol 3, no 18. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1173–1249

  • Beznoska M, Ochmann R (2010) Household savings decision and income uncertainty. DIW discussion papers no. 1046. DIW Berlin, German Institute for Economic Research

  • Beznoska M, Ochmann R (2013) The interest elasticity of household savings. Empir Econ 45:371–399

  • Blundell R (2012) Tax policy reform: the role of empirical evidence. J Eur Econ Assoc 10(1):43–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bönke T, Corneo G (2006) Was hätte man sonst machen können? Alternativszenarien zur rot-grünen Einkommensteuerreform. Diskussionsbeitäge Nr 2006/3, Volkswirtschaftliche Reihe, Freie Universität Berlin

  • Bourguignon F (2011) Status quo in the welfare analysis of tax reforms. Rev Income Wealth 57(4):603–621

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon F, Spadaro A (2006) Microsimulation as a tool for evaluating redistribution policies. J Econ Inequal 4:77–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brenke K (2009) Reallöhne in Deutschland über mehrere Jahre rückläufig. DIW Wochenbericht no. 33, DIW Berlin, German Institute for Economic Research

  • Browning M, Lusardi A (1996) Household saving: micro theories and micro facts. J Econ Lit 34(4):1797–1855

    Google Scholar 

  • Bundesministerium der Finanzen (2004) 1 Jan 2005: Die letzte Stufe der Steuerreform 2000 wird wirksam. Monatsbericht des BMF, December 2004:45–59

  • Conesa J, Kitao S, Krueger D (2009) Taxing capital? Not a bad idea after all! Am Econ Rev 99(1):25–48

  • Corneo G (2005) Verteilungsarithmetik der rot-grünen Einkommensteuerreform. J Appl Soc Sci Stud 125(2):299–314

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton AS, Muellbauer J (1980) Economics and consumer behavior. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Domeij D, Heathcote J (2004) On the distributional effects of reducing capital taxes. Int Econ Rev 45(2):523–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebert U, Moyes P (2003) Equivalence scales reconsidered. Econometrica 71(1):319–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein M (1976) Personal taxation and portfolio composition: an econometric analysis. Econometrica 44(4):631–650

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haan P (2007) The effects of personal income taxation on labor supply, employment and welfare: empirical evidence for Germany. Dissertation, Free University of Berlin. http://www.diss.fu-berlin.de/2007/216/

  • Haan P, Steiner V (2005) Distributional and fiscal effects of the german tax reform 2000—a behavioral microsimulation analysis. J Appl Soc Sci Stud 125(1):39–49

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall R (1996) The effects of tax reform on prices and asset values. Tax Policy Econ 10:71–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman J, Poterba J (1987) Household behavior and the tax reform act of 1986. J Econ Perspect 1(1):101–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jalava J, Kavonius IK (2009) Measuring the stock of consumer durables and its implications for euro area savings ratios. Rev Income Wealth 55(1):43–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson D, Parker J, Souleles N (2006) Household expenditure and the income tax rebates of 2001. Am Econ Rev 96(5):1589–1610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen M (2002) The German tax reform of 2000. Int Tax Public Finance 9:603–621

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keuschnigg C (2011) The design of capital income taxation: reflections on the mirrlees review. Fisc Stud 32(3):437–452

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang O (1998) Steueranreize und Geldanlage im Lebenszyklus—Empirische Analysen zu Spar- und Portfolioentscheidungen deutscher Privathaushalte. ZEW-Wirtschaftsanalysen Band 32, Nomos, Baden-Baden

  • Maiterth R, Müller H (2009) Beurteilung der Verteilungswirkungen der “rot-grünen” Einkommensteuerpolitik—Eine Frage des Maßstabs. J Appl Soc Sci Stud 129(3):375–390

    Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell A, Whinston M, Green J (1995) Microeconomic theory. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Merz J, Zwick M (2002) Verteilungswirkungen der Steuerreform 2000/2005 im Vergleich zum “Karlsruher Entwurf”. Wirtschaft und Statistik 8:729–740

    Google Scholar 

  • Michel N, Ahmad N (2012) Consumer response to child tax credit. Empir Econ 43:1199–1214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myck M, Ochmann R, Qari S (2011) Dynamics in transitory and permanent variation of wages in Germany. Econ Lett 113:143–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ochmann R (2010) Distributional and welfare effects of Germany’s year 2000 tax reform. DIW discussion papers no. 1083, DIW Berlin, German Institute for Economic Research

  • Ochmann R (2013) Asset demand in the financial aids portfolio model—evidence from a major tax reform. Appl Financ Econ 23(8):649–670

  • Poterba J (2002) Taxation, risk-taking, and household portfolio behavior. In: Auerbach AJ, Feldstein M (eds) Handbook of public economics, vol 3, no 17. Elsevier, Amsterdm, pp 1109–1171

  • Poterba JM, Samwick AA (2002) Taxation and household portfolio composition: US evidence from the 1980s and 1990s. J Public Econ 87:5–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saez E (2003) The effect of marginal tax rates on income: a panel study of ‘bracket creep’. J Public Econ 87:1231–1258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor J, Clements K (1983) A simple portfolio allocation model of financial wealth. Eur Econ Rev 23:241–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tuttle MH, Gauger J (2006) Wealth and the distribution of income: permanent and transitory effects. Rev Income Wealth 52(4):493–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagenhals G (2000) Incentive and redistribution effects of the German tax reform 2000. FinanzArchiv: Public Finance Anal 57(3):316–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This paper greatly benefited from valuable discussions with Martin Browning, André Decoster, Peter Haan, Carsten Schröder, Viktor Steiner, Arthur van Soest, and audiences at the 2011 annual congress of the European Economic Association, the 2011 annual congress of the Verein für Socialpolitik, and in economic policy seminars at DIW Berlin and Free University of Berlin, as well as useful comments from two anonymous referees. Financial support from the Fritz Thyssen Stiftung through project ‘Taxation and Asset Allocation of Private Households—Empirical Analyses and Simulations of Policy Reforms for Germany’ is gratefully acknowledged. Data provision by the Federal Statistical Office, as well as the Research Data Centre (FDZ) of the Statistical Offices of the Länder, is also acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard Ochmann.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Reform

See Fig. 2.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Personal income tax rates and allowances over the time frame of the reform. Notes Tax rates exclude solidarity surcharge of 5.5 %. Source: Own illustration. Figures from Bundesministerium der Finanzen (2004)

Appendix 2: Methodology

1.1 Budget and price elasticities

In the linearized QUAIDS, the budget elasticity for asset j in levels follows from Eq. (2):

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{ij} \equiv \frac{\partial A_{ij}}{\partial A_{il}} \frac{A_{il}}{A_{ij}} = 1 +\left( \beta _{1j} + 2\beta _{2j}\ln \left( A_{il}/P^{*}\right) \right) /s_{ij} \end{aligned}$$
(3)

The uncompensated price elasticity for the levels of asset j, w.r.t. price of good k, is:

$$\begin{aligned} \varepsilon ^{\,u}_{ijk} \equiv \frac{\partial A_{ij}}{\partial p_{jk}} \frac{p_{jk}}{A_{ij}} = - \delta _{jk} + \gamma _{jk} / s_{ij} - \left( \beta _{1j} + 2\beta _{2j}\ln \left( A_{il}/P^{*}\right) \right) \, \bar{s}_{k} / s_{ij} \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \(\bar{s}_{k}\) is the average share of asset k and \(\delta _{jk}\) is the Kronecker delta, i.e. \(\delta _{jk}=1\) if \(j=k\) and \(\delta _{jk}=0\) if \(j \ne k\). By the Slutsky equation, the compensated price elasticity follows as:

$$\begin{aligned} \varepsilon ^{\,c}_{ijk} \equiv \varepsilon ^{\,u}_{ijk} + s_{ik} \eta _{ij} = - \delta _{jk} + \gamma _{jk}/s_{ij} + s_{ik} + \left( \beta _{1j} + 2\beta _{2j}\ln \left( A_{il}/P^{*}\right) \right) \, \left( s_{ik} - \bar{s}_{k}\right) /s_{ij} \end{aligned}$$
(5)

For the sake of interpretation, compensated (after-tax) rate-of-return elasticities, rather than price elasticities, will be presented. They follow from the price elasticities as:

$$\begin{aligned} \varepsilon ^{\,(r)\,c}_{ijk} =-\varepsilon ^{\,c}_{ijk} \, \frac{\widetilde{r}^\mathrm{net}_{j}}{1+\widetilde{r}^\mathrm{net}_{j}} \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(\widetilde{r}^{\mathrm{net}}_{j} = r^{\mathrm{gro}}_{j}(1-t_{ij})-\pi _{i}\) is the after-tax real rate of return to asset \(j, r^{\mathrm{gro}}_{j}\) the respective pre-tax return, \(\pi _{i}\) is the inflation rate relevant for household i, and \(t_{ij}\) the marginal tax rate on income from asset j, which is simulated in the income taxation module. The uncompensated rate-of-return elasticity follows accordingly from Eq. (4).

1.2 Indices of inequality

The general entropy index, GE(\(-\)1), is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} I_{\mathrm{GE}} = \frac{1}{2n} \sum _{i=1}^{n} \left( \frac{\bar{x}}{x_i}-1\right) \end{aligned}$$
(7)

The Gini coefficient is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} I_{\mathrm{Gini}} = \sum _{i=1}^{n} \frac{x_i}{n\bar{x}} \frac{(2i-n-1)}{n} \end{aligned}$$
(8)

The Theil index, GE(1), is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} I_{\mathrm{Theil}}= \frac{1}{n} \sum _{i=1}^{n} \mathrm{log}\left( \frac{x_i}{\bar{x}}\right) \, \frac{x_i}{\bar{x}} \end{aligned}$$
(9)

1.3 Approximating the compensating variation

Following the welfare-concept definition, the compensating variation is defined as (see Deaton and Muellbauer 1980, pp. 184–190):

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{CV}_{i} = c\left( u^{1}_{i},p^{1}_{i}\right) - c\left( u^{0}_{i},p^{1}_{i}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where \(c(u^{1}_{i},p^{1}_{i})\) is the cost function for expenditures of household i to gain the post-reform utility level at post-reform prices, and \(c(u^{0}_{i},p^{1}_{i})\) is the respective cost function to gain the pre-reform utility level at post-reform prices. If this difference is strictly greater than zero, the household is better off after the reform in money-metric welfare terms.

As differences in utility are not observed, the CV needs to be approximated with the help of estimates for the compensated price elasticities in Eq. (5). A second-order Taylor expansion of \(c(u^{0},p^{1})\) around (\(u^{0},p^{0}\)) yields (see Deaton and Muellbauer 1980, p.174, or an application in Banks et al. 1996):

$$\begin{aligned} c(u^{0},p^{1})\approx & {} c(u^{0},p^{0}) + \sum _{j}\frac{\partial c(u^{0},p^{0})}{\partial p^{0}_{j}}(p^{1}_{j}-p^{0}_{j})\nonumber \\&+\,\frac{1}{2} \, \sum _{j} \sum _{k}{\frac{\partial ^2 c(u^{0},p^{0})}{\partial p^{0}_{j} \partial p^{0}_{k}}(p^{1}_{j}-p^{0}_{j})(p^{1}_{k}-p^{0}_{k})} \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Applying the fact that the first derivative of the cost function equals Hicksian demand (Mas-Colell et al. 1995, pp. 67–75):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial c\left( u^{0},p^{0}\right) }{\partial p^{0}_{j}}=h_{j}(u^{0},p^{0})=q^{0}_{j} \end{aligned}$$
(12)

it follows from Eq. (11) that

$$\begin{aligned} c\left( u^{0},p^{1}\right)\approx & {} c\left( u^{0},p^{0}\right) + \sum _{j}q^{0}_{j}(p^{1}_{j}-p^{0}_{j})\nonumber \\&+\,\frac{1}{2} \, \sum _{j} \sum _{k}{\frac{\partial h_{j}\left( u^{0},p^{0}\right) }{\partial p^{0}_{k}}\left( p^{1}_{j}-p^{0}_{j}\right) \left( p^{1}_{k}-p^{0}_{k}\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(13)

where \(h_{j}(u^{0},p^{0})\) denotes pre-reform Hicksian demand for asset j.

Rewriting the definition of the CV for a compound income and price change in Eq. (10) and applying the fact that \(c(u^{1},p^{1})=y^{1}\), yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{CV} = y^{1} -y^{0} -c\left( u^{0},p^{1}\right) + c\left( u^{0},p^{0}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(14)

Plugging Eq. (13) into Eq. (14) and rearranging, it follows that:

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\mathrm{CV}} \approx y^{1}- y^{0}- \sum _{j}{p^{0}_{j}q^{0}_{j} \left( \frac{p^{1}_{j}-p^{0}_{j}}{p^{0}_{j}}\right) \left( 1 + \frac{1}{2} \sum _{k}{\widehat{\varepsilon }^{\,c}_{jk} \, \frac{p^{1}_{k}-p^{0}_{k}}{p^{0}_{k}}} \right) } \end{aligned}$$
(15)

where \(\widehat{\varepsilon }^{\,c}_{jk}\) is an estimate for the compensated price elasticity of asset j w.r.t. price of asset k. Note that these are average elasticities over all households. Their application in the welfare measure implies the assumption of equal social utility weights for all households (see Banks et al. 1996). In simulations with log-linear utility, this approximation performed accurately in case the differentials in pre- and post-reform prices are of similar size and the same sign for all assets. In case, the variation in the differentials is not too large, the approximation error appeared to be acceptable. For further simulations on the approximation error, also see Banks et al. (1996).

Equation (15) contains only variables that are observed or that have been estimated, while all utility terms have been replaced. In case demand is completely inelastic for all assets, there are no distortionary effects, i.e.  \(\widehat{\varepsilon }^{\,c}_{jk} = 0 \, \forall \, j,k = 1,\ldots ,J\), and the CV reduces to the income changes added to the changes in expenditures for constant demand resulting from the price shifts: \(\widetilde{\mathrm{CV}} \approx y^{1} - y^{0} - \sum \nolimits _{j}{p^{0}_{j}q^{0}_{j} \left( \frac{p^{1}_{j} - p^{0}_{j}}{p^{0}_{j}}\right) }\). This is denoted in the literature as first-order approximation to the welfare measure (Banks et al. 1996). Generally, there is a trade-off regarding accuracy between such a first-order approximation and a second-order approximation of the form in Eq. (11). The latter is, on the one hand, found to produce lower approximation error in specific empirical applications (Banks et al. 1996). On the other hand, it gives rise to potential imprecision, or even bias, from the estimation of substitution elasticities in demand, which is not needed for first-order approximations. In Sect. 6, implications for further research are directed to the investigation into which approximation is the most appropriate for the application at hand.

Appendix 3: Results

See Tables 4 and 5.

Table 4 Compensated rate-of-return elasticities on unconditional asset demand levels (from the unconstrained estimation on the pooled 1998 and 2003 data)
Table 5 OLS regression of welfare effects on savings ratio

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ochmann, R. Distributional and welfare effects of Germany’s year 2000 tax reform: the context of savings and portfolio choice. Empir Econ 51, 93–123 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-1003-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-1003-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation