Skip to main content
Log in

Malthus to modernity: wealth, status, and fertility in England, 1500–1879

  • ORIGINAL PAPER
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A key challenge to theories of long-run economic growth has been linking the onset of modern growth with the move to modern fertility limitation. A notable puzzle for these theories is that modern growth in England began around 1780, 100 years before there was seemingly any movement to limit fertility. Here we show that the aggregate data on fertility in England before 1880 conceals significant declines in the fertility of the middle and upper classes earlier. These declines coincide with the Industrial Revolution and are of the character predicted by some recent theories of long-run growth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Taking the Demographic Transition as the date overall marital fertility fell by 10 %. See Strulik and Vollmer 2014 for a recent empirical survey of global fertility trends.

  2. Theories which fail this challenge include, Becker et al. (1990), Hansen and Prescott (2002), and Lucas (2002). Galor and Weil (2000) and Galor and Moav (2002) achieve concordance with much of the fertility pattern but, as we will see below, still face challenges.

  3. Hollingsworth (1957) showed that from 1350 to 1729, the net fertility of the richest of English ducal families was generally below the average for England. Wrigley et al. (1997, p. 427) concluded that fertility differentials by occupation were “trivial” before 1837.

  4. This parish record analysis finds more muted effects than here, but this is because occupations are imperfect measures of wealth, wealth itself being the crucial explanator of fertility before 1760 as shown in Table 11.

  5. Assuming that 60 % of male deaths in 1861 were of men aged 21 or above.

  6. Wrigley and Schofield (, p. 510) stress the “remarkable homogeneity of the patterns” observed in the data for individual English parishes. For the years after 1837, Wilson and Woods (1991, p. 414) state, “In Victorian England and Wales demographic variations were local rather than regional.”

  7. Omission of children, at least in a sex-biased sense, appears to be inconsequential from 1580 on (see Table A1).

  8. Such measures include age-specific fertility rates, total fertility rates, and child to woman ratios.

  9. See Table A3. In about half of these cases, we only get the date of first marriage or the date of the first child born, but we can use this information to estimate a birth date for the testator from the fact that the average age at first marriage was 28, and the average age at first birth is 29.1.

  10. A concern with these marriage cohorts is that, for reasons of record availability, we have unbalanced death cohorts. For married or widowed men outside London, for example, we have 1,243 observations for the 1630s and 157 for the 1640s. This will lead to the marriage cohorts having an unbalanced age structure. Some will have too many older men and some too many younger men. To correct this, we calculate the net fertility by marriage cohort, reweighting by the inverse of the sizes of the probate cohorts who contributed observations to each marriage cohort.

  11. The will sample fails to identify some widowers, since if they have no surviving children or grandchildren and fail to mention their deceased wife or her relatives in the will, they will be classified as single. However, the number of such omissions should be constant over time.

  12. Using death duty registers, Green et al. (2009, p. 323) uncover a similar age-wealth profile for men dying in the late nineteenth century as for our men first marrying 1780-1879.

  13. The R 2 value of the relationship between wealth and fertility is several times higher than that between age and fertility.

  14. These dates correspond to a marriage cohort split on 1780. For men dying in 1860–1914, the sample over weights married men since, initially, we were concerned to sample only those whose age could be obtained from the censuses of 1841 and later. For this reason, we have to report Fig. 9 by death cohort.

  15. In this exercise, we counted as survivors only children still living at the time of the will, not those dead but with surviving children of their own.

  16. We can compare these rates to survival rates estimated from parish burial records. Before 1800, these suggest that 69 % of those born were alive at age 15, but the average child at the time of the will was older than 15, so these rates are similar (Wrigley et al. 1997, p. 262).

  17. This would be along the lines of “Demographic Transition theory.” Parents will rationally adjust their fertility (with a lag) to the mortality environment (Thompson 1929; Landry 1934; Notestein 1945).

  18. Clark and Cummins (2009) give further evidence against this possibility through an examination of the fertility patterns of men in different mortality environments in preindustrial England. The countryside was so much safer than London that if reduced mortality risks were leading to declining fertility, it should already have happened in the most rural locations even before 1780.

  19. The conclusions to the European Fertility Project (Coale and Watkins 1986) suggested that the fertility transition across Europe was not an economic “adaptation” but a result of “ideational change”—more closely associated with cultural and linguistic variables than the economy (see also Knodel and van de Walle 1986 and the literature review in Cummins 2009). Recent work which incorporates “social norms” into a couple’s fertility decision-making process includes that of Manski and Mayshar (2003), Munshi and Myaux (2006), and Bhattacharya and Chakraborty (2012).

  20. Boberg-Fazlic et al. (2011), however, find greater occupational differences in fertility before 1600 in the 26 Cambridge Group reconstitutions parishes, suggesting that this greater wealth effect before 1600 is likely correct.

  21. There are sufficient extant wills that it will be possible to check conclusively whether fertility among the rich was even higher before 1600.

References

  • Allen M (1989) Wills of the archdeaconry of Suffolk, 1620-24 Woodbridge. Suffolk: Boydell Press for the Suffolk Records Society, 31

  • Allen M (1995) Wills of the archdeaconry of Suffolk, 1625-26 Woodbridge. Suffolk Boydell Press for the Suffolk Records Society, 37

  • Allen M, Evans N (1986a) Wills from the archdeaconry of Suffolk, 1629-36. New England Historic Genealogical Society, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen M, Evans N (1986b) Wills from the archdeaconry of Suffolk, 1637-40. New England Historic Genealogical Society, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker G, Murphy K, Tamura R (1990) Human capital, fertility and economic growth. J Pol Econ 98:S12—37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya J, Chakraborty S (2012) Fertility choice under child mortality and social norms. Econ Lett 115(3):338–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boberg-Fazlic N, Sharp P, Weisdorf J (2011) Survival of the richest? Testing the Clark hypothesis using English pre-industrial data from family reconstitution records. Euro Rev Econ Hist 15(3):365–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2005) The condition of the working class in England, 1209-2004. J Pol Econ 113(6):1307–1340

  • Clark G (2007) A farewell to Alms: a brief economic history of the world. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2010a) The macroeconomic aggregates for England, 1209-2008. Res Econ Hist 27:51–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2010b) The consumer revolution: turning point in human history, or statistical artifact? Working paper, UC-Davis

  • Clark G (2011) Average earnings and retail prices, UK, 1209-2010. Working paper, UC Davis

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Cummins N (2009) Urbanization, mortality and fertility in Malthusian England. Am Econ Rev 99(2):242–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Cummins N (2012a) What is the true rate of social mobility? Surnames and social mobility in England, 1800–2011. Working paper

  • Clark G, Cummins N (2012b) The Beckerian family and the English Demographic Revolution of 1800. Working paper

  • Clark G, Hamilton G (2006) Survival of the richest. The Malthusian mechanism in pre-industrial England. J Econ Hist 66(3):707–736

    Google Scholar 

  • Coale A, Treadway R (1986) A summary of the changing distribution of overall fertility, marital fertility, and the proportion married in the provinces of Europe. In: Coale A, Watkins S (eds). Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 1–30

  • Coale A, Watkins S (1986) The decline of fertility in Europe: the revised proceedings of a conference on the Princeton European Population Project. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummins N (2009) Why did fertility decline? An analysis of the individual level economic correlates of the nineteenth century fertility transition in England and France, PHD Thesis. London School of Economics

  • Cummins N (2013) Marital fertility and wealth during the fertility transition: rural France, 1750–1850. Econ Hist Rev 66(2):449–476

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doepke M (2005) Child mortality and fertility decline: does the Barro-Becker model fit the factsJ Popul Econ 18:337–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emmison F (1978) Elizabeth life: wills of Essex gentry and merchants, proved in the Prerogative Court of Canterbury Chelmsford, Essex: Essex Record Society Publication, 71

  • Emmison F (1990) Essex wills, 1558–1603, vol 2–11. Essex Record Office, Chelmsford

    Google Scholar 

  • Essex Record Office, Chelmsford: Archdeaconry and Consistory Court Wills, 1500–1857

  • Evans N (1987) The wills of the archdeaconry of Sudbury, 1630-35. Suffolk Records Society, vol 29 Woodbridge. The Boydell Press, Suffolk

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans N (1993) The wills of the archdeaconry of Sudbury, 1636-38 Suffolk Records Society, vol 35 Woodbridge. The Boydell Press, Suffolk

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor O (2011) Unified growth theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Weil D (2000) Population, technology and growth: from Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. Am Econ Rev 90:806–828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Moav O (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quart J Econ 117:1133–1192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green D, Owens A, Maltby J, Rutterford J (2009) Lives in the balance? Gender, age and assets in late nineteenth-century England and Wales. Contin Chang 24(2):307–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Great Britain Historical GIS (2009) English administrative counties, 1910 and English urban/rural areas 1910. http://borders.edina.ac.uk/ukborders/action/restricted/textgeosearch

  • Hansen G, Prescott E (2002) Malthus to Solow. Am Econ Rev 92(4):1205–1217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hazan M, Berdugo B (2002) Child labor, fertility and economic growth. Econ J 112(482):810–828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hollingsworth T (1957) A demographic study of the British ducal families. Pop Stud 11(1):4–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horrell S, Humphries J (1995) The exploitation of little children: child labor and the family economy in the industrial revolution. Explor Econ Hist 32(4):485–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes A (1986) Reproductive success and occupational class in eighteenth century Lancashire, England. Soc Bio 33:109–115

    Google Scholar 

  • Kimura M, Yasui D (2013) Public policy and the income-fertility relationship in economic development. Working paper. Kyoto University, Institute of Economic Research

    Google Scholar 

  • Knodel J, van de Walle E (1986) Lessons from the past: policy implications of historical fertility studies. In: Coale A J, Watkins S C (eds) The decline of fertility in Europe: the revised proceedings of a conference on the Princeton European Population Project. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 390–419

    Google Scholar 

  • Landers J (1993) Death and the Metropolis: studies in the demographic history of London, 1670–1830. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Landry A (1934) La Revolution Demographique. Sirey, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • London Metropolitan Archive: Archdeaconry and Consistory Court Wills, 1600–1857

  • Lucas R (2002) The Industrial Revolution: past and future. In: Lectures on economic growth. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Manski C, Mayshar J (2003) Private incentives and social interactions: fertility puzzles in Israel. J Euro Econ Assoc 1(1):181–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munshi K, Myaux J (2006) Social norms and the fertility transition. J Dev Econ 80(1):1–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Notestein F (1945) Population; the long view. In: Schultz TW (ed) Food for the world. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 36–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Owens A, Green D, Bailey C, Kay A (2006) A measure of worth: probate valuations, personal wealth and indebtedness in England, 1810–40. Hist Res 79(205):383–403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Probate Department of the Principal Registry Family Division: all wills 1858–1914

  • Public Record Office, Kew: Prerogative Court of Canterbury Wills, 1500–1857

  • Rubenstein W (1977) Wealth, elites and the class structure of modern Britain. Past Present 76:99–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott S, Duncan C (2000) Interacting effects of nutrition and social class differentials on fertility and infant mortality in a pre-industrial population. Popul Stud 54(1):71–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strulik H, Vollmer S (2014) The fertility transition around the world. J Popul Econ. doi:10.1007/s00148-013-0496-2

  • Suffolk Record Office: Archdeaconry Court Wills, 1500–1857

  • Teitelbaum M (1984) The British fertility decline: demographic transition in the crucible of the industrial revolution. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson W (1929) Population. Am J Soc 34(6):959–975

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Transcripts of wills of testators from Earls Colne, Essex, 1490–1857. http://linux02.lib.cam.ac.uk/earlscolne/probate/index.htm

  • Webb C (1996) Surrey will abstracts, vol 1-41. West Surrey Family History Society

  • Wilson C, Woods R (1991) Fertility in England: a long-term perspective. Popul Stud 45(3):399–415

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley E, Schofield R (1981) The population history of England 1541–1871. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley E, Davies R, Oeppen J, Schofield R (1997) English population history from family reconstitution, 1580–1837. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gregory Clark.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Junsen Zhang

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 122 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Clark, G., Cummins, N. Malthus to modernity: wealth, status, and fertility in England, 1500–1879. J Popul Econ 28, 3–29 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-014-0509-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-014-0509-9

Keywords

Navigation