Skip to main content
Log in

Theories of swidden agriculture, and the political economy of ignorance

  • Published:
Agroforestry Systems Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Swidden agriculture is today the focus of a great deal of debate in the context of agroforestry development in humid, tropical countries. This paper argues that much of this debate deals not with the empirical facts of swidden agriculture, however, but rather with widely-accepted myths, and that this explains the widespread failures of developmental schemes involving swidden agriculturalists. The paper examines three of these myths in some detail.

One myth is that swidden agriculturalists own their land communally (or not at all), work it communally, and consume its yields communally. The truth is that their land (including land under secondary forest fallow) is typically owned by individual households, it is worked by individual household labor forces and/or by reciprocal but not communal work groups, and its yields are owned and consumed privately and individually by each household. A second myth is that swidden cultivation of forested land is destructive and wasteful, and in the worst cases results in barren, useless grassland successions. The truth is that swidden cultivation is a productive use of the forests, indeed more productive than commercial logging in terms of the size of the population supported, and forest-grassland successions are typically a function not of rapaciousness but of increasing population/land pressure and agricultural intensification — the grasses, including Imperata cylindrica, having value both as a fallow period soil-rebuilder and as cattle fodder. A third myth is that swidden agriculturalists have a totally subsistence economy, completely cut off from the rest of the world. The truth is that swidden agriculturalists, in addition to planting their subsistence food crops, typically plant market-oriented cash crops as well, and as a result they are actually more integrated into the world economy than many of the practitioners of more intensive forms of agriculture.

In the conclusion to the paper, in a brief attempt to explain the genesis of these several myths, it is noted that they have generally facilitated the extension of external administration and exploitation into the territories of the swidden agriculturalists, and hence can perhaps best be explained as a reflection of the political economy of the greater societies in which they dwell.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Ace Partadiredja (1982) Farm organization, technology and employment. In [44] pp 179–215.

  2. Biotrop (1980) Proceedings of Biotrop workshop on alang-alang. Bogor: Biotrop (Special Publication No. 5).

    Google Scholar 

  3. Boeke JH (1953) Economics and economic policy of dual societies. H.D. Tjeenk Willink, Haarlem.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Boserup E (1966) The conditions of agricultural growth: the economics of agrarian change under population pressure. Aldine, Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Burbridge P et al (1981) Land allocation for transmigration. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies XVII,1: 108–113.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Burkill IH (1935) A dictionary of the economic products of the Malay Peninsula. 2 vols. Crown Agent for the Colonies, London.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Burnham P (1980) Changing agricultural and pastoral ecologies in the West African savanna region. In [31] pp 147–170.

  8. Collier WL (1981) Agricultural evolution in Java. In Hansen GE ed. Agricultural and rural development in Indonesia, pp 147–173. Westview Press, Boulder/U.S.A.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Condominas G (1957/1977) We have eaten the forest: the story of a Montagnard village in the central highlands of Vietnam. Hill and Wang, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Condominas G (1980) Agricultural ecology in the Southeast Asian savanna region: the Mnong Gar of Vietnam and their social space. In [31] pp 209–252.

  11. Conklin HC (1954) An ethnoecological approach to shifting agriculture. Transactions of the New York Academy of Sciences II, 17.2: 133–142.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Conklin HC (1957) Hanunoo Agriculture: a report on an integral system of shifting cultivation in the Philippines. Rome: FAO (Forestry Development Papers no. 12).

    Google Scholar 

  13. Daroesman R (1981) Vegetative elimination of alang-alang. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies XVII, 1: 83–107.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Dobby EHG (1973) Southeast Asia. University of London Press, London.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Dove MR (1980) Development of tribal land rights in Borneo: The role of ecological factors. Borneo Research Bulletin 12,1:3–19.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Dove MR (1981) Symbiotic relationships between human populations and Imperata cylindrica: the question of ecosystem succession and preservation in South Kalimantan. In: Nordin M et al (eds) Conservation inputs from life sciences, pp 187–200. Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia, Bangi/Malaysia.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Dove MR (1982) The myth of the communal longhouse in rural development: the Kantu' of Kalimantan. In:MacAndrews C and Chin LS (eds) Too rapid rural development. Ohio University Press, Athens/U.S.A.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Dove MR (1983) Forest preference in swidden agriculture. Tropical Ecology 24, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Dove MR (forthcoming) Intensive versus extensive systems of agriculture in inner and outer Indonesia: cultural perception versus economic reality. Hainsworth G (ed) Proceedings of CCSEAS-ISEAS Joint International Conference on Village-Level Modernization, 21–24 June, 1982, Singapore.

  20. Dumond DE (1961) Swidden agriculture and the rise of Maya civilization. Southwestern Journal of Anthropology 17:301–316.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Eussen JHH (1980) Biological and ecological aspects of alang-alang. In [2] pp 15–22.

  22. Freeman JD (1955) Iban agriculture: a report on the shifting cultivation of dry rice by the Iban of Sarawak. H.M.S.O., London. (Colonial Research Study no. 18).

    Google Scholar 

  23. Furtado JI (1979) The status and future of the tropical moist forest in Southeast Asia. In: MacAndrews C and Chin LS (eds) Developing economies and the environment: the Southeast Asian experience, pp 73–120. McGraw-Hill, Singapore.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Furtado JI (1980) Tropical ecology and development: proceedings of the Vth international symposium of tropical ecology, 16–21 April, Kuala Lumpur. 2 vols. The International Society of Tropical Ecology, Kuala Lumpur.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Geddes WR (1954) The Land Dayaks of Sarawak. H.M.S.O., London. (Colonial Research Study no. 14).

    Google Scholar 

  26. Geddes WR (1970) Opium and the Miao: a study in ecological adjustment. Oceania 4,1:1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Geertz (1963) Agricultural involution: the process of ecological change in Indonesia. University of California Press, Berkeley.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Grandstaff T (1978) The development of swidden agriculture (shifting cultivation). Development and Change 9:547–579.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Grijpstra BC (1976) Common efforts in the development of rural Sarawak, Malaysia. Van Gorkum, Assen.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Hainsworth GB (1982) Beyond dualism? Village-level modernization and the process of integration into national economies in Southeast Asia. In Hainsworth GB ed. Village-Level Modernization: The Political Economy of Rice and Water, pp 1–33. UBC Press, Vancouver.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Harris DR (1980) Human ecology in savanna environments. Academic Press, London.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Hartmans EH (1981) Land development and management in tropical Africa. International Institute of Tropical Agriculture, Ibadan/Nigeria.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Holmes JHG et al (1980) The use of Imperata cylindrica (L.) Beauv. by grazing cattle in Papua-New Guinea. In [2] pp 179–192.

  34. Hudson AB (1974) Swidden systems and potential directions for agricultural development: a case from Kalimantan. In: Conference on Indonesian Agriculture, Madison, pp 101–105.

  35. Ivens GW (1980) Imperata cylindrica (L.) Beauv in West African agriculture. In [2] pp 149–156.

  36. Izikowitz KG (195) Lamet: hill peasants in French Indochina. Etnografiska Museet, Göteborg (Etnografiska Studier 17).

  37. Kunstadter P (1978) Subsistence agricultural economies of Lua' and Karen Hill Farmers, Mae Sariang District, Northwestern Thailand. In [40] pp 74–133.

  38. Kunstadter P (1980) The impact of economic development on Southeast Asian tropical forests. In [24] pp 65–72.

  39. Kunstadter P and Chapman EC (1978) Problems of shifting cultivation and economic development in Northern Thailand. In [40] pp 3–23.

  40. Kunstadter P et al (eds) (1978) Farmers in the forest: economic development and marginal agriculture in Northern Thailand. East-West Center, Honolulu.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Mears LA (1981) The new rice economy of Indonesia. Gadjah Mada University Press, Yogyakarta.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Merrill ED (1954) Plant life of the Pacific World. Macmillan, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Miles D (1972) Land, labour and kin groups among Southeast Asian shifting cultivators. Mankind 8:185–197.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Mubyarto (ed) (1982) Growth and equity in Indonesian agricultural development. Yayasan Agro Ekonomika, Jakarta.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Ngampongsai C (1980) Sambar's plant foods in Khao-Yai National Park, Thailand. In [24] pp 295–301.

  46. Nye PH and Greenland DJ (1960) The soil under shifting cultivation. Commonwealth Agricultural Bureaux, Farnham Royal/England (Technical Communication no. 51).

    Google Scholar 

  47. Padoch C (1980) The environmental and demographic effects of alternative cash-producing activities among shifting cultivators in Sarawak. In [24] pp 475–481.

  48. Pelzer KJ (1978) Swidden cultivation in southeast Asia: historical, ecological, and economic perspectives. In [40] pp 271–286.

  49. Penny DH (1964) The transition from subsistence to commercial family farming in North Sumatra (Ph.D. thesis, Cornell University) University Microfilms, Ann Arbor/USA.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Proceedings seminar agroforestry dan pengendalian perladangan, Jakarta 19–21 November (1981). The Directorate of Reforestation and Rehabilitation, and The General Directorate of Forestry, Jakarta.

  51. Ratanakhon S (1978) Legal aspects of land occupation and development. In [40] pp 45–53.

  52. Richards PW (1952) The tropical rain forest. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge/England.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Sanchez PA (1976) Properties and management of soils in the tropics. Wiley, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Sanchez PA (1981) Soils of the humid tropics. Studies in Third World Societies 14: 347–410.

    Google Scholar 

  55. Seavoy RE (1975) The origin of tropical grasslands in Kalimantan, Indonesia. Journal of Tropical Geography 40:48–52.

    Google Scholar 

  56. Seavoy RE (1980) Population pressure and land use change. Singapore Journal of Tropical Geography 1:61–67.

    Google Scholar 

  57. Sherman G (1980a) What ‘green desert’? The ecology of Batak grassland farming. Indonesia 29:113–148.

    Google Scholar 

  58. Sherman G (1980b) The culture-bound notion of ‘soil fertility’: On interpreting non-western criteria of selecting land for cultivation. Studies in Third World Societies 14:487–511.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Smitinand T et al (1978) The environment of Northern Thailand. In [40] pp 24–40.

  60. Soewardi B and Sastradipradja D (1980) Alang-alang (Imperata cylindrica [L.] Beauv.) and animal husbandry. In [2] pp 157–178.

  61. Spencer JE (1966) Shifting cultivation in Southeastern Asia. University of California Press, Berkeley.

    Google Scholar 

  62. Suryatna ES and McIntosh JL (1980) Food crops production and control of Imperata cylindrica (L.) Beauv. on small farms. In [2] pp 135–148.

  63. Syarifuddin Baharsyah and Soetatwo Hadiwigeno (1982) The development of commercial crop farming. In [44] pp 144–178.

  64. Thomas KD (1965) Shifting cultivation and production of small holder rubber in a South Sumatran village. Malayan Economic Review 10:100–115.

    Google Scholar 

  65. UNESCO (1978) Tropical Forest Ecosystems. UNESCO, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  66. Vayda AP (1981) Research in East Kalimantan on interactions between people and forests: a preliminary report. Borneo Research Bulletin 13,1:3–15.

    Google Scholar 

  67. Van Vollenhoven C (1909) Miskenningen van het adatsrecht. Leiden.

  68. de Vries E (1950) Problems of agriculture in Indonesia. Pacific Affairs 23,2:130–143.

    Google Scholar 

  69. Weatherly WP (1980) USAID assisted development projects and wildlife and genetic resources. In [24] pp 261–265.

  70. Whitmore TC (1975) Tropical forests of the Far East. Clarendon Press, Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  71. Wong J ed. (1979) Group farming in Asia: experiences and potentials. Singapore University Press, Singapore.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

This paper was written during the tenure of a research fellowship from the Rockefeller Foundation. The fieldwork upon which its conclusions are based was funded by the National Science Foundation (U.S.A., grant no. GS-42605), CRIS (Stanford University), FAO/UNFPD, and also the Rockefeller Foundation.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Dove, M.R. Theories of swidden agriculture, and the political economy of ignorance. Agroforest Syst 1, 85–99 (1983). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00596351

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00596351

Keywords

Navigation