Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Sustainability and consumption

  • Published:
Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider the implications of the three pillars of sustainability (environment, economy and social justice) on consumption in a wealthy country. Building a theoretical model that includes consumers, business, government, the environment, and economic and political relations between nations, we explore how sustainability should affect the consumption behavior of consumers, charitable aid to poorer countries, and responsible environmental practices by businesses. Our model enables us to provide normative implications for consumers, society and business. Importantly, we assume that all stakeholders will optimize their self-interest, and that altruism will only partly explain behavior consistent with sustainability. Among the more non-obvious findings are that (1) the poorer the poor countries are, the less the rich countries should consume, (2) the more sensitive the global political climate is to economic inequity between the rich and poor nations, the less the rich countries should consume, and (3) if aid to poor countries is effective enough, then the more materialistic the society is, the more charitable aid it should give. We also confirm a number of more intuitive findings, such as that business should use more green technology as the taxes on pollution and/or efficiency of green technology increase, and the more resource-intensive consumption is, the less consumers should consume. Taken as a whole, the findings imply that societal consumption patterns should be sensitive to aspects of environmental impact and social justice, even if altruistic motivations are absent.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A “standard budget” is a list of goods and services that a family of a specified size and composition would need to live at a designated level of well-being, together with the estimated monthly or annual costs of those goods and services (Fisher 2007).

  2. Material possessions and acquisition are conceptualized as the marketing domains of life.

  3. In the case of positive externalities, Pigovian subsidies are used to encourage the supply of the goods or services.

  4. Our decreasing returns formulations in Eqs. (1) and (2) are based on prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky 1979).

  5. We assume decreasing returns here because pollution savings are certain to get tougher to achieve as pollution is decreased (the low hanging fruit has been picked).

  6. Many factors other than perceived consumption inequality also are important causes of conflict and wars, but we omit them from this formulation for reasons of parsimony and focus.

References

  • Aasness, J., & Larsen, E. R. (2003). Distributional effects of environmental taxes on transportation. Journal of Consumer Policy, 26(3), 279–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arthy, S. (2009). Momentum for success at climate summit. Sky News, Sky.com, US News Editor, Port of Spain, Trinidad, UK, 28 November.

  • Barkin, J. S. (1998). The evolution of the constitution of sovereignty and the emergence of human rights norms. Millenium, 27(Summer), 229–252.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, C., Cafaro, P., & Newholm, T. (2005). Philosophy and ethical consumption. In R. Harrison, T. Newholm, & D. Shaw (Eds.), The ethical consumer (pp. 11–24). London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barratt-Brown, M. (1993). Fair trade: Reform and realities in the international trading system. London: Zed Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (1972). On taxation and the control of externalities. American Economic Review, 62(3), 307–322.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belk, R. W. (1985). Materialism: Trait aspects of living in the material world. Journal of Consumer Research, 12(3), 265–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berenger, V., & Verdier-Chouchane, A. (2007). Multidimensional measures of well-being: Standard of living and quality of life across countries. World Development, 35(7), 1259–1276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, C. (2001). Sustainability is good business. OECD Observer, September, p.35. http://www.oecdobserver.org/news/printpage.php/aid/546/Sustainability_is_good_business.html.

  • Carrier, J. G. (2007). Ethical consumption. Anthropology Today, 23, 1–2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., Etile, F., Postel-Vinay, F., Senik, C., & Van der Straeten, K. (2005). Heterogeneity in reported well-being: Evidence from twelve European countries. The Economic Journal, 115(502), C118–C132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, B., & Winn, M. I. (2007). Market imperfections, opportunity and sustainable entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing, 22(1), 29–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corporate Responsibility Officer (2009). 100 best corporate citizens 2009—full story. http://www.thecro.com/100best09.

  • Day, G. S. (1994). The capabilities of market-driven organizations. Journal of Marketing, 58(4), 37–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Day, R. L. (1978). Beyond social indicators: Quality of life at the individual level. In F. D. Reynolds & H. C. Barksdale (Eds.), Marketing and the quality of life (pp. 11–18). Chicago: American Marketing Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dierksmeier, C., & Pirson, M. (2009). Oikonomia versus chrematistike: Learning from Aristotle about the future orientation of business management. Journal of Business Ethics, 88, 417–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunn, E. W., Aknin, L. B., & Norton, M. I. (2008). Spending money on others promotes happiness. Science, 319, 21–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (2000). The worldwide standard of living since 1800. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(1), 7–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engardio, P, Capell, K., Kerry, J., & Hall, K. (2007). Beyond the green corporation. Business Week, 29 January, 50–64.

  • Feldman, L. P. (1971). Societal adaptation: A new challenge for marketing. Journal of Marketing, 35, 54–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, G. M. (2007). An overview of recent work on standard budgets in the United States and other Anglophone countries. Online paper, January. http://www.aspe.hhs.gov/poverty/papers/std-budgets/.

  • Flatters, P., & Willmott, M. (2009). Understanding the post-recession consumer. Harvard Business Review, 106–112 (July-August).

  • Fox, B. (2009). Climate debate heats up Caribbean summit. Associated Press, Saturday, November 27. http://www.google.com/hostednews/ap/article/ALeqM5hMngtnyb69v5U96jDSem6I5cT0vwD9C7PM1G0.

  • Hawken, P., Lovins, A., & Lovins, L. H. (1999). Natural capitalism: Creating the next industrial revolution. Snowmass, CO: Rocky Mountain Institute.

  • Hetrick, W. (1989). The ideology of consumerism: A critique. In R. Bagozzi & J. P. Peter (Eds.), Proceedings of the American Marketing Association Winter Conference (pp. 287–296). Orlando: American Marketing Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horn, R. V. (1976). Assessment of living levels—the social indicator approach. Paper delivered to the 47th Congress of the Australian and New Zealand Association for the Advancement of Science (ANZAAS), Hobart.

  • Huseman, R. C., Hatfield, J. D., & Miles, E. W. (1987). A new perspective on equity theory: The equity sensitivity construct. Academy of Management Review, 12(2), 222–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, T. (2000). The employment and productivity effects of environmental taxation: Additional dividends or added distractions? Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, 43(3), 389–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsen, R. (1991). Economic efficiency and the quality of life. Journal of Business Ethics, 10(3), 201–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, R. L. (2009). Organizational motivations for going green or profitability versus sustainability. The Business Review, 13(1), 22–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilbourne, W., McDonagh, P., & Prothero, A. (1997). Sustainable consumption and the quality of life: A macromarketing challenge to the dominant social paradigm. Journal of Macromarketing, 17(1), 4–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilbourne, W. E. (2004). Sustainable communication and the dominant social paradigm: Can they be integrated? Marketing Theory, 4(3), 187–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R. (2005). Happiness and public policy: A challenge to the profession. Working paper, March.

  • Leelakulthanit, O., Day, R., & Walters, R. (1991). Investigating the relationship between marketing and overall satisfaction with life in a developing country. Journal Macromarketing, 11(1), 3–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, T. L. (2003). Environmental aid: Driven by recipient need or donor interests? Social Science Quarterly, 84(1), 144–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowe, I. (1998). Producing a better world: Theory, education, and consulting. The American Behavioral Scientist, 42(3), 531–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martinsons, M. G., Leung, A. K. Y., & Loh, C. (1996). Technology transfer for sustainable development environmentalism and entrepreneurship in Hong Kong. International Journal of Social Economics, 23(9), 69–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald, S., Oates, C., Thyne, M., Alevizou, P., & McMorland, L.-A. (2009). Comparing sustainable consumption patterns across product sectors. International Journal of Consumer Studies, 33, 137–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menon, A., & Menon, A. (1997). Enviropreneurial marketing strategy: The emergence of corporate environmentalism as market strategy. Journal of Marketing, 61(1), 51–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menon, A., Menon, A., Chowdhury, J., & Jankovich, J. (1999). Evolving paradigm for environmental sensitivity in marketing programs: a synthesis of theory and practice. Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice, 7(2), 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muncy, J. A., & Eastman, J. K. (1998). Materialism and consumer ethics: An exploratory study. Journal of Business Ethics, 17(2), 137–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norcia, V. D., & Tigner, J. (2000). Mixed motives and ethical decisions in business. Journal of Business Ethics, 25(1), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Opotow, S., & Weiss, L. (2000). Denial and the process of moral exclusion in environmental conflict. Journal of Social Issues, 56(3), 475–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Riordan, T. (2009). On the politics of sustainability a long way ahead. Environment, 51(2), 40–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ottman, J. A., Stafford, E. R., & Hartman, C. L. (2006). Avoiding green marketing myopia. Environment, 48(5), 22–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paim, L. (1995). Definitions and measurements of well-being: A review of literature. Journal of Economic and Social Measurement, 21, 297–309.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paramio, J. L., & Zofío, J. L. (2008). Labor market duality and leisure industries in Spain: Quality of life versus standard of living. The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 67(4), 683.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peattie, K., & Collins, A. (2009). Guest editorial: Perspectives on sustainable consumption. International Journal of Consumer Studies, 33, 107–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pepper, M., Jackson, T., & Uzzell, D. (2009). An examination of the values that motivate socially conscious and frugal consumer behaviors. International Journal of Consumer Studies, 33, 126–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasche, A., Baur, D., Huijstee, M., Ladek, S., Naidu, J., Perla, C., et al. (2008). Corporate as political actors—a report on the first Swiss master class in corporate social responsibility. Journal of Business Ethics, 80, 151–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rees, W. E. (2001). Economics and sustainability: Conflict or convergence? An ecological economics perspective. StatsCan Economic Conference, Ottawa, Ontario, June.

  • Richins, M. L., & Dawson, S. (1992). A consumer values orientation for materialism and its measurement: Scale development and validation. Journal of Consumer Research, 19(3), 303–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selim, S. (2008). Life satisfaction and happiness in Turkey. Social Indicator Research, 88, 541–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1987). The standard of living: Lecture I, concepts and critiques. In A. Sen, & G. Hawthorn (Eds.), The standard of living (pp. 1–19). Cambridge University Press.

  • Sirgy, M. J. (1998). Materialism and quality of life. Social Indicators Research, 43(3), 227–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stafford, E. R., & Hartman, C. L. (1998). Toward an understanding of the antecedents of environmentalist-business cooperative relations. American Marketing Association Conference Proceedings, 9, 56–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern, P. C., Dietz, T., Kaloff, L., & Guagnano, G. A. (1995). Values, beliefs, and pro-environmental action: attitude formation toward emergent attitude objects. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 25(18), 1611–1636.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strong, C. (1997). The problems of translating fair trade principles into consumer purchase behavior. Marketing Intelligence & Planning, 15(1), 32–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thogersen, J., & Crompton, T. (2009). Simple and painless? The limitations of spillover in environmental campaigning. Journal of Consumer Policy, 32(2), 141–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trentmann, F. (2007). Citizenship and consumption. Journal of Consumer Culture, 7(2), 147–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations (1987). Report of the World Commission on Environment and Development. General Assembly 42/187, 11th December 1987. http://www.un-documents.net/a42r187.htm.

  • United Nations Human Development Reports (2009). Overcoming barriers: Human mobility and development. http://hdr.undp.org/en/reports/global/hdr2010/.

  • Vanderschraaf, P. (1999). Hume’s game-theoretic business ethics. Business Ethics Quarterly, 9(1), 47–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varul, M. Z. (2008). Consuming the campesino: Fair trade marketing between recognition and romantic commodification. Cultural Studies, 22, 654–679.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Roland T. Rust.

Additional information

Ming-Hui Huang and Roland T. Rust contributed equally to the paper.

Appendix

Appendix

Consumption level

We find the level of consumption, C*, that maximizes happiness, H. This is obtained as follows:

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\partial {\text{H}}/\partial {\text{C}} = {{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}}\left( {\partial {\text{S}}/\partial {\text{C}}} \right) = {{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}}\left[ {1 - 2{{\text{a}}_{\text{S}}}{\text{C}} - \left( {\partial {\text{P}}/\partial {\text{C}}} \right) - \left( {\partial {\text{W}}/\partial {\text{C}}} \right)} \right] = } \hfill \\ { = {{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}}\left[ {1 - 2{{\text{a}}_{\text{S}}}{\text{C}} - {{\text{a}}_{\text{P}}} - 2{{\text{a}}_{\text{W}}}\left( {{\text{C}} - {{\text{C}}_{\text{p}}}} \right)} \right] = 0\,{\text{when}}} \hfill \\ {{\text{C}} * = \left( {1 - {{\text{a}}_{\text{P}}} + 2{{\text{a}}_{\text{W}}}{{\text{C}}_{\text{p}}}} \right){/}\left( {2\left( {{{\text{a}}_{\text{S}}} + {{\text{a}}_{\text{W}}}} \right)} \right)} \hfill \\ {{\partial^2}{\text{H}}/\partial {{\text{C}}^2} = - 2{{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}}\left( {{{\text{a}}_{\text{S}}} + {{\text{a}}_{\text{W}}}} \right) < 0,\,{\text{ensuring}}\,{\text{the}}\,{\text{C}} * \,{\text{provides}}\,{\text{a}}\,{\text{maximum}}.} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
(A1)

Sensitivity to consumption inequity

To determine the sign of

$$ \partial {\text{C}} * /\partial {{\text{a}}_{\text{W}}} = \left( {2{{\text{C}}_{\text{p}}}{{\text{a}}_{\text{S}}} + {{\text{a}}_{\text{P}}} - 1} \right){/}\left( {2{{\left( {{{\text{a}}_{\text{S}}} + {{\text{a}}_{\text{W}}}} \right)}^2}} \right) $$
(A2)

we first note that C > Cp which means that

$$ \left( {1 - {{\text{a}}_{\text{P}}} + 2{{\text{a}}_{\text{W}}}{{\text{C}}_{\text{p}}}} \right){/}\left( {2\left( {{{\text{a}}_{\text{S}}} + {{\text{a}}_{\text{W}}}} \right)} \right) > {{\text{C}}_{\text{p}}} $$
(A3)

from which we obtain \( 0 > 2{{\text{C}}_{\text{p}}}{{\text{a}}_{\text{S}}} + {{\text{a}}_{\text{P}}} - 1 \), from which (7) follows.

Environmental sacrifice

The level of environmental sacrifice, X*, that maximizes happiness is obtained as:

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\partial {\text{H}}/\partial {\text{X}} = {{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}}\left( {\partial {\text{S}}/\partial {\text{X}}} \right) + {{\text{b}}_{\text{H}}} - 2{{\text{c}}_{\text{H}}}{\text{X}} = - {{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}} + {{\text{b}}_{\text{H}}} - 2{{\text{c}}_{\text{H}}}{\text{X}} = 0\,{\text{when}}} \hfill \\ {{\text{X}} * = \left( { - {{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}} + {{\text{b}}_{\text{H}}}} \right)/2{{\text{c}}_{\text{H}}}} \hfill \\ {{\partial^2}{\text{H}}/\partial {{\text{X}}^2} = - 2{{\text{c}}_{\text{H}}} < 0,\,{\text{ensuring}}\,{\text{that}}\,{\text{X}} * {\text{provides}}\,{\text{a}}\,{\text{maximum}}.} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
(A4)

Charitable aid to poorer countries

The level of charitable aid to poor countries that maximizes happiness is:

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\partial {\text{H}}/\partial {\text{A}} = {{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}}\left( {\partial {\text{S}}/\partial {\text{A}}} \right) + {{\text{d}}_{\text{H}}} - 2{{\text{e}}_{\text{H}}}{\text{A}} = {{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}}\left( { - \left( {\partial {\text{W}}/\partial {\text{A}}} \right) - 1} \right) + {{\text{d}}_{\text{H}}} - 2{{\text{e}}_{\text{H}}}{\text{A}} = } \hfill \\ { = {{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}}\left( {{{\text{b}}_{\text{W}}} - 2{{\text{C}}_{\text{W}}} - 1} \right) + {{\text{d}}_{\text{H}}} - 2{{\text{e}}_{\text{H}}}{\text{A}} = 0\,{\text{when}}} \hfill \\ {A * = \left\{ {{{\text{a}}_{\text{H}}}\left( {{{\text{b}}_{\text{W}}} - 2{{\text{c}}_{\text{W}}} - 1} \right) + {{\text{d}}_{\text{H}}}} \right\}/2{{\text{e}}_{\text{H}}}} \hfill \\ {{\partial^2}{\text{H}}/\partial {{\text{A}}^2} = - 2{{\text{e}}_{\text{H}}} < 0,\,{\text{which}}\,{\text{means}}\,{\text{we}}\,{\text{have}}\,{\text{a}}\,{\text{maximum}}.} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
(A5)

Adoption of green technology

The level of green technology that maximizes profits can be found as:

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\partial \Pi /\partial {\text{G}} = - {\text{t}}\left( {\partial {\text{P}}/\partial {\text{G}}} \right) - 1 = {\text{t}}{{\text{b}}_{\text{P}}} - 2{\text{t}}{{\text{c}}_{\text{P}}}{\text{G}} - 1 = 0\,{\text{when}}} \hfill \\ {{\text{G}} * = \left( {{\text{t}}{{\text{b}}_{\text{P}}} - 1} \right){/}\left( {2{\text{t}}{{\text{c}}_{\text{P}}}} \right)} \hfill \\ {{\partial^2}\Pi /\partial {{\text{G}}^2} = - 2{\text{t}}{{\text{c}}_{\text{p}}} < 0,\,{\text{ensuring}}\,{\text{a}}\,{\text{maximum}}.} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
(A6)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Huang, MH., Rust, R.T. Sustainability and consumption. J. of the Acad. Mark. Sci. 39, 40–54 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-010-0193-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-010-0193-6

Keywords

Navigation