Skip to main content
Log in

The impact of individual and collective reputation on wine prices: empirical evidence from the Mosel valley

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Although of considerable practical importance, the separate impact of individual and collective reputation on firm performance (e.g. product prices) has not yet been convincingly demonstrated. We use a sample of some 70 different wineries offering more than 1,300 different Riesling wines from the Mosel valley to isolate the returns to individual reputation (measured by expert ratings in a highly respected wine guide) from the returns to collective reputation (measured by membership in two different professional associations where members are assumed to monitor each other very closely). We find that both effects are statistically significant and economically relevant with the latter being more important in quantitative terms than the former.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Most of these papers refer to or are based on the concept of “implicit promises” as developed by Macaulay (1963).

  2. This is similar to the selection procedure in the US Major Leagues, where owners of incumbent franchises jointly decide on the location of new teams (see e.g. Quirk and Fort 1997, 1999).

  3. Currently there are about 2,700 different (usually rather small) firms producing wine in the Mosel, Saar and Ruwer valleys (Statistische Ämter des Bundes und der Länder 2011: 26). Although most of them are clustered in small villages with at most 1,000 or 2,000 inhabitants, individual producers neither have the technology nor any incentives to monitor other producers. The resulting free-rider problem can only be overcome if a small number of producers jointly invest in an institutional arrangement designed to avoid moral hazard behavior on the one hand and to promote their products on the other hand.

  4. Two years later, von Bruchhausen brought together similar associations that had developed in other German wine-growing regions. The new national organization was the forerunner of today’s “Verband Deutscher Prädikatsweingüter” (Association of German Quality Wine Estates, henceforth VDP).

  5. Eggert et al. (2010) use data from the annual auctions 1994–2008 to analyze the impact of the level and the change in individual producer’s reputation on wine prices.

  6. Anecdotal evidence suggests that being listed in this particular wine guide is considered the “key to success” by most winemakers.

  7. Thus, all the wines in the sample were harvested 2 years prior to the publication of the respective annual edition of the wine guide we use in our econometric analysis. Apart from these 1,303 Riesling wines the estates included in the sample also produced a small number of wines from other grapes (n = 25), indicating that winemakers in the Mosel, Saar and Ruwer valleys are highly specialized. Including these 25 wines in the estimations has no effect on the results (these are, of course, available from the authors upon request).

  8. Table 7 in the “Appendix” demonstrates that the distribution of wine qualities is similar across the three groups of wineries. Minor differences occur only in the middle of the quality distribution (Kabinett, Spätlese and Auslese), but neither at the bottom end (no label, Qualitätswein) nor at the top end (Beerenauslese, Eiswein and Trockenbeerenauslese) of the quality ranking. In each of the four harvest seasons included in the analysis (1992–1995) wines from all over the quality ranking are included in the analysis (a table displaying the distribution of the wines by harvest season and quality is available from the authors upon request).

  9. Estimation of an OLS model with standard errors clustered by winery yields somewhat smaller coefficients for the two membership dummies (see Table 8 in the “Appendix”). At the same time, however, the individual reputation dummies are—with one notable exception (the highest reputation category)—slightly larger in the OLS than in the Hausman-Taylor estimation. As an additional robustness check we also estimated a fixed effects model and then related these to the membership dummies. It appears that the coefficient of BR is negative and significant (−0.103, t = −5.67) while the coefficient of VDP is positive and significant (+0.297, t = 19.18). The full results are, of course, available from the authors upon request.

  10. Estimating the model with dummies for the different reputation categories results in a similar picture (see columns 5–7 of Table 3). As pointed out in Table 2 already, the coefficients exhibit a non-linear pattern, suggesting that there are considerable (additional) returns to “superstar winemakers”. Whether these returns are due to differences in talent (Rosen 1981) or due to differences in publicity (Adler 1985) remains to be tested.

  11. We plan, of course, to expand our data set to include the most recent editions of “Gault Millau”. This allows us to better explore membership effects as we observe not only “late entries” but also (in-) voluntary exits. We can then address the question whether product prices increase/decrease upon change in membership status while controlling for time-varying wine quality and expert evaluations.

References

  • Adler M (1985) Stardom and Talent. Am Econ Rev 75:208–212

    Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof G (1970) The market for lemons: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quart J Econ 84:1007–1040

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen F (1984) Reputation and product quality. Rand J Econ 15:311–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi B (2008) Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, 4th edn. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Benfratello L, Piacenza M, Sacchetto S (2009) Taste or reputation: what drives market prices in the wine industry? Estimation of a Hedonic model for Italian premium wines. Appl Econ 41:2197–2209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger J, Sorensen A, Rasmussen S (2010) Positive effects of negative publicity: when negative reviews increase sales. Mark Sci 29:815–827

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buraimo B, Forrest D, Simmons R (2009) Insights for clubs from modeling match attendance in football. J Operat Res Soc 60:147–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cabral LMB (2005) The Economics of Trust and Reputation: A Primer, mimeo, Stern School of Business. New York University, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardebat J-M, Figuet J-M (2004) What explains Bordeaux wine prices. App Econ Lett 11:293–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chevalier J, Mayzlin D (2006) The effect of word of mouth on sales: online book reviews. J Mark Res 43:345–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Combris P, Lecocq S, Visser M (1997) Estimation of a hedonic price equation for Bordeaux wine: does quality matter? Econ J 1997:390–402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Combris P, Lecocq S, Visser M (2000) Estimation of a Hedonic price equation for Burgundy wine. Appl Econ 32:961–967

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dranove D, Jin G (2010) Quality disclosure and certification: theory and practice. J Econ Lit 48:935–963

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubois P, Nauges C (2010) Identifying the effect of unobserved quality and experts’ reviews in the pricing of experience goods: empirical application on Bordeaux wine. Int J Ind Organ 28:205–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eggert A, Frick B, Hogreve J (2010) Corporate reputation and customers’ value perception: a dynamic analysis. In: Beckmann SC, Ringberg T, Ritter T (eds). The six senses—the essentials of marketing, proceedings of the 39th Annual Conference of the European Marketing Academy, Copenhagen 2010

  • Eliashberg J, Shugan S (1997) Film critics: influencers or predictors? J Mark 61:68–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott C, Simmons R (2009) Determinants of UK box office success: the impact of quality signals. Rev Ind Organ 33:93–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishman A, Rob R (2002) Is bigger better? Investing in reputation, mimeo. Department of Economics, Bar Ilan University, Ramat Gan

    Google Scholar 

  • Friberg R, Grönqvist E (2012) Do Expert Reviews Affect the Demand for Wine? Am Econ J App Econ 4:193–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frick B (2004) Does ownership matter? Empirical evidence from the German wine industry. Kyklos 57:357–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gale D, Rosenthal RW (1994) Price and quality cycles for experience goods. Rand J Econ 25:590–607

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbs M, Tapia M, Warzynski F (2009) Globalization, superstars and reputation: theory and evidence from the wine industry. J Wine Econ 4:49–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2011) Econometric Analysis, 7th ed., Pearson

  • Hadj Ali H, Nauges C (2007) The pricing of experience goods: the example of En Primeur wines. Am J Agric Econ 89:91–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadj Ali H, Lecocq S, Visser M (2008) The impact of Gurus: Parker grades and En Primeur wines. Econ J 118:F158–F173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman JA, Taylor WT (1981) Panel data and unobservable individual effects. Econometrica 49:1377–1398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hilger J, Rafert G, Villas-Boas S (2011) Expert opinion and the demand for experience goods: an experimental approach in the retail wine market. Rev Econ Stat 93:1289–1296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ippolito PM (1990) Bonding and non-bonding signals of product quality. J Bus 63:41–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jin G, Leslie P (2003) The effects of information on product quality: evidence from restaurant hygiene cards. Quart J Econ 118:409–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein B, Leffler KB (1981) The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance. J Polit Econ 89:615–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landon S, Smith CE (1997) The use of quality and reputation indicators by consumers: the case of Bordeaux wine. J Consum Policy 20:289–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landon S, Smith CE (1998) Quality expectations, reputations, and price. South Econ J 64:628–647

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macaulay S (1963) Non-contractual relations in business: a preliminary study. Am Sociol Rev 28:55–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mailath GJ, Samuelson L (2001) Who wants a good reputation? Rev Econ Stud 68:415–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quirk J, Fort RD (1997) Pay Dirt: The Business of Professional Team Sports. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Quirk J, Fort R (1999) Hard Ball: The Abuse of Power in Pro Team Sports. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinstein D, Snyder C (2005) The influence of expert reviews on consumer demand for experience goods: a case study of movie critics. J Indus Econ 53:27–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen S (1981) The economics of superstars. Am Econ Rev 71:845–858

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C (1982) Consumer information, product quality, and seller reputation. Bell J Econ 13:20–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C (1983) Premiums for high quality products as returns to reputations. Quart J Econ 98:659–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistische Ämter des Bundes und der Länder (2011) Agrarstrukturen in Deutschland: Einheit in Vielfalt. Statistisches Landesamt Baden-Württemberg, Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Tadelis S (2002) The market for reputations as an incentive mechanism. J Polit Econ 110:854–882

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole J (1996) A theory of collective reputations (with applications to the persistence of corruption and to firm quality). Rev Econ Stud 63:1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winfree JA, McCluskey JJ (2005) Collective reputation and quality. Am J Agric Econ 87:206–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank two anonymous referees for their constructive comments and suggestions. Moreover, we are grateful to conference participants at the Personnel Economics Workshop in Zurich (2011) and at the annual meeting of the American Association of Wine Economists in Davis, CA (2010) for their helpful suggestions. Finally, we thank Carolin Berges for her assistance in compiling the data set used in this study. Remaining errors and omissions are, of course, our own. This work was partially supported by the German Research Foundation (DFG) within the Collaborative Research Centre ``On-The-Fly Computing’’ (SFB 901).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bernd Frick.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 5, 6, 7 and 8.

Table 5 Composition of the sample (wineries by membership, number of wines and year)
Table 6 Wineries by number of years in sample
Table 7 Wineries by type of wine quality
Table 8 OLS estimation with Robust standard errors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Frick, B., Simmons, R. The impact of individual and collective reputation on wine prices: empirical evidence from the Mosel valley. J Bus Econ 83, 101–119 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11573-013-0652-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11573-013-0652-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation