Skip to main content
Log in

Predicting the Trend of Well-Being in Germany: How Much Do Comparisons, Adaptation and Sociability Matter?

  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using longitudinal data from the German Socio-Economic Panel, we estimate the variation of subjective well-being experienced by Germans over the last two decades testing the role of some of the major correlates of people’s well-being. Our results suggest that the variation of Germans’ well-being between 1996 and 2007 is well predicted by changes over time of income, demographics and social capital. The increase in social capital predicts the largest positive change in subjective well-being. Income growth, also predicts a substantial change in subjective well-being, but it is compensated for about three fourths by the joint negative predictions due to income comparison and income adaptation. Finally, we find that aging of the population predicts the largest negative change in subjective well-being. This result appears to hinge on the large loss of satisfaction experienced by individuals in old age.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Dolan et al. (2008) for a recent survey on the determinants of subjective well-being.

  2. Corazzini et al. (2011) show that also the perception of poverty is reference-based, with people in higher income countries giving more relevance to reference income.

  3. See Bartolini and Bonatti (2008), Antoci et al. (2012), and Bilancini and D’Alessandro (2011) recent theoretical investigations on the role of social capital.

  4. The data were extracted using the add-on package PanelWhiz v2.0 (Nov 2007) for Stata. PanelWhiz was written by Dr. John P. Haisken-DeNew (john@panelwhiz.eu). The PanelWhiz generated .do files to retrieve the SOEP data used here are available upon request to the authors. Any data or computational errors in this paper are our own. Please refer to Haisken-DeNew and Hahn (2010) for a detailed description of PanelWhiz.

  5. For more details on the SOEP see Frick et al. (2007) and Wagner et al. (2007).

  6. http://www.diw.de.

  7. As pointed out in Dolan et al. (2008), health is likely to be an important correlate of SWB. However, we cannot control for it in our regressions because the SOEP does not contain data on objective health. The SOEP does provide data on subjective health, but this variable has been shown to be a poor proxy of objective health (e.g., Kahneman and Riis 2005; Deaton 2008).

  8. For more details about the tunnel effect see Hirschman (1973) or, more recently, Senik (2004) and Caporale et al. (2009).

  9. In order to explore different non-linear relationships between age and SWB, we run further regressions where we include not only age and age squared, but also higher order variables. We found confirmation that in the very old age the relationship is strongly negative and concave.

  10. See, e.g., Clark and Oswald (2006), Blanchflower and Oswald (2008) and references therein for a full list of contributions supporting the U-shape hypothesis in economics. See instead Mroczek and Spiro (2005) for a recent contribution in the psychological literature which also supports the U-shape hypothesis. Interestingly enough, Mroczek and Spiro (2005) find that the age of minimum SWB is greater than the one typically found by economists of about 20 years (in the 60s instead of the 40s).

  11. See also Easterlin (2006) and Van Landeghem (2009) on this issue.

  12. In this respect, Becchetti et al. (2008) do not provide any indication since they do not allow for a non-linear relationship between age and SWB.

References

  • Antoci, A., Sabatini, F., & Sodini, M. (2012). The Solaria syndrome: Social capital in a growing hyper-technological economy. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81(3), 802–814.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartolini, S., Bilancini, E. & Pugno, M. (2011). Did the decline in social connections depress Americans’ happiness? Social Indicators Research. doi:10.1007/s11205-011-9971-x.

  • Bartolini, S., & Bonatti, L. (2008). Endogenous growth, decline in social capital and expansion of market activities. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 67, 917–926.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becchetti, L., Pelloni, A., & Rossetti, F. (2008). Relational goods, sociability and happiness. Kyklos 61(3):343–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becchetti, L., Ricca, E. G., & Pelloni, A. (2009). The 60s turnaround as a test on the causal relationship between sociability and happiness. SOEP papers on multidisciplinary panel data research 209, DIW Berlin, The German Socio-Economic Panel (SOEP).

  • Bilancini, E., & D’Alessandro, S. (2011). Long-run welfare under externalities in consumption, leisure, and production: A case for happy degrowth vs. unhappy growth. Ecological Economics. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.10.023.

  • Blanchflower, D. (2009). International evidence on well-being. In: A. Krueger (Ed.), Measuring the subjective well-being of nations: National accounts of time use and well-being. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. & Oswald, A. (2004). Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. Journal of Public Economics, 88(7–8), 1359–1386.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. & Oswald, A. (2008). Is well-being U-shaped over the life cycle? Social Science & Medicine, 66(8), 1733–1749.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruni, L., & Stanca L. (2008). Watching alone: Relational goods, television and happiness. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 65, 506–528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caporale, G., Georgellis, Y., Tsitsianis, N., & Yin, Y. (2009). Income and happiness across europe: Do reference values matter? Journal of Economic Psychology 30(1):42–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charles, S., Reynolds, C., & Gatz, M. (2001). Age-related differences and change in positive and negative affect over 23 years. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 80, 136–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., Frijters, P. & Shields, M. (2008). Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the Easterlin paradox and other puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(1), 99–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A. & Oswald, A. (2006). The curved relationship between subjective well-being and age. PSE working paper n.29.

  • Corazzini, L., Esposito, L. & Majorano, F. (2011). Exploring the absolutist vs relativist perception of poverty using a cross-country questionnaire survey. Journal of Economic Psychology 32(2), 273–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costa, D. & Kahn, M. (2003). Understanding the American decline in social capital: 1952–1998. Kyklos 56, 17–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Ambrosio, C., & Frick, J. (2011). Individual well-being in a dynamic perspective. Economica 78, 723–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A. (2008). Income, health and well-being around the World: Evidence from the Gallup World Poll. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 22(2), 53–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella, R., Haisken-De New, J., & MacCulloch, R. (2010). Happiness adaptation to income and to status in an individual panel. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 76(3):834–852

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella, R. & MacCulloch, R. (2008). Gross national happiness as an answer to the Easterlin paradox? Journal of Development Economics 86, 22–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella, R. & MacCulloch R. (2010). Happiness adaptation to income ‘basic needs’. In: Diener, E., Helliwell, J. & Kahneman, D. (Eds) International Differences in Well-Being. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diener, E., Sandvik, E., Seidlitz, L. & Diener, M. (1993). The relationship between income and subjective well-being: Relative or absolute? Social Indicators Research 28, 195–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolan, P., Peasgood, T. & White, M. (2008). Do we really know what makes us happy? A review of the economic literature on the factors associated with subjective well-being. Journal of Economic Psychology 29(1), 94–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duesenberry, J.S. (1949). Income, savings and the theory of consumer behaviour. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf, S. (2002). On the empirics of social capital. The Economic Journal 112(483), F459–F479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf, S. N. (2001). A framework for the study of individual behaviour and social interactions. Social Methodology, 31, 47–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, E. A. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence. In P. A. David (Eds.), Nations and households in economic growth (pp. 89–125). California: Stanford University Press.

  • Easterlin, E.A. (1995). Will rising the incomes of all increase the happiness of all? Journal of Economic Behaviour & Organization, 27, 35–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. (2006). Life cycle happiness and its sources: Intersections of psychology, economics, and demography. Journal of Economic Psychology 27(4), 463–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A., & Angelescu, L. (2011). Modern economic growth: Cross sectional and time series evidence. In K. C. Land, A. C. Michalos, & M. J. Sirgy (Eds.), Handbook of social indicators and quality of life research. New York and London: Springer.

  • Falk, A. & Knell M. (2004). choosing the joneses: Endogenous goals and reference standards. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 106(3), 417–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. (2005). Income and well-being: An empirical analysis of the comparison income effect. Journal of Public Economics, 89(5–6), 997–1019.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. & Frijters P. (2004). How important is methodology for the estimates of the determinant of happiness? The Economic Journal, 114(497), 641–659.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S., & Loewenstein, G. (1999). hedonic adaptation. In D. Kanheman and E. Diener (Eds.) The foundations of hedonic psychology. New York: Russel Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. & Stutzer, A. (2000). Happiness, Economy and Institutions. Economic Journal, 110, 918–938.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2002). Happiness and economics. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frick, J., Jenkins, S., Lillard, D., Lipps, O. & Wooden M. (2007). The cross-national equivalent file (cnef) and its member country household panel studies. Schmollers Jahrbuch 127(4), 627–654.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerstorf, D., Ram, N., Goebel, J., Schupp, J., Lindenberger, U., & Wagner G. (2010). Where people live and die makes a difference: Individual and geographic disparities in well-being progression at the end of life. Psychology and Aging 25(3), 661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerstorf, D., Ram, N., Mayraz, G., Hidajat, M., Lindenberger, U., Wagner, G. & J. Schupp (2010). Late-life decline in well-being across adulthood in Germany, the United Kingdom, and the United States: Something is seriously wrong at the end of life. Psychology and aging 25(2), 477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gui, M. & Sugden R. (2005). Economics and social interaction. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Haisken-DeNew, J. & Hahn, M. (2010). Panelwhiz: Efficient data extraction of complex panel data sets–an example using the German soep. Schmollers Jahrbuch 130(4), 643–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell, J. (2001) Social capital, the economy and well-being. In Andrew Sharpe, E. D., France St-Hilaire, R., & Keith Banting D. (Eds.), The review of economic performance and social progress 2001: The longest decade: Canada in the 1990s, Volume 1 of The Review of Economic Performance and Social Progress. Centre for the Study of Living Standards & The Institute for Research on Public Policy.

  • Helliwell, J. (2006). Well-being, social capital and public policy: What’s new? Economic Journal 116, C34–C45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell, J. & Putnam R. (2004) The social context of well-being. Philosophical Transactions 359(1449):1435–1446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. (1973). The changing tolerance for income inequality in the course of economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(4), 544–566.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Riis, J. (2005). Living, and thinking about it: Two perspectives on life. In F. Huppert, N. Baylis, & B. Keverne (Eds.), The science of well-being (pp. 285–304). USA: Oxford University Press.

  • Kapteyn, A. & T. Wansbeek (1985). The individual welfare function: A review. Journal of Economic Psychology, 6, 333–363.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ladd, E. (1996). The data just don’t show erosion of America’s social capital. Public Perspective 7, 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R. (2005). Happiness: Lessons from a new science. London: The Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R., & Nickell, S. (2009). Does relative income matter? Are the critics right? In: Kahneman D., Diener E., Helliwell J. (Eds) International differences in well-being. Oxford: Oxford University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Lim, C., & Putnam, R. (2010). Religion, social networks, and life satisfaction. American Sociological Review 75(6), 914–933.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luttmer, E. F. (2005). Neighbors as negatives: Relative earnings and well-being. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 936–1002.

    Google Scholar 

  • McBride, M. (2001). Relative-income effects on subjective well-being in the cross-section. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 45(3), 251–278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mroczek, D., Spiro, A. (2005). Change in life satisfaction during adulthood: Findings from the veterans affairs normative aging study. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 88, 189–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2001). The evidence on social capital. In The well-being of nations: The role of human and social capital (pp. 39–63). Paris: OECD.

  • Paxton, P. (1999). Is social capital declining in the United States? A multiple indicator assessment. American Journal of Sociology 105, 88–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R.D. (2000). Bowling alone: The collapse and revival of american community. New York: Simon & Schuster

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, R., Jackson, E. (2001) Is trust in others declining in America? An age period cohort analysis. Social Science Research 30, 117–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sabatini, F. (2009). Social capital as social networks: a new framework for measurement and an empirical analysis of its determinants and consequences. Journal of Socio-economics 38(3), 429–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salvatore, N., & Teresa Muñoz Sastre, M. (2001). Appraisal of life: “area” versus “dimension” conceptualizations. Social Indicators Research, 53(3), 229–255.

  • Senik, C. (2004). When information dominates comparison: Learning from russian subjective panel data. Journal of Public Economics, 88(9–10), 2099–2133.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stutzer, A. (2004). The role of income aspirations in individual happiness. Journal of Economic Behaviour & Organization, 54, 89–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uhlaner, C. (1989). âĂIJrelational goods and participation: Incorporating sociability into a theory of rational action. Public Choice 62(3), 253–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Landeghem, B. (2009). The course of subjective well-being over the life cycle. Schmollers Jahrbuch 129(2), 261–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Praag, B., Frijters, P., & Ferrer-i Carbonell, A. (2003) The anatomy of subjective well-being. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 51(1), 29–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. (1899). The theory of the leisure class. New York:Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vendrik, M., & Hirata, J. (2007). Experienced versus decision utility of income: Relative or absolute happiness. In: Bruni, L., Porta, P. (Eds.) Handbook on the economics of happiness, (pp. S185–S208). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vendrik, M., & Woltjer, G.B. (2007). Happiness and loss aversion: Is utility concave or convex in relative income? The Journal of Public Economics 91, 1423–1448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, G., Frick, J., & Schupp, J. (2007). The german socio-economic panel study (soep)—evolution, scope and enhancements. Schmollers Jahrbuch 127(1), 139–169.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Francesco Sarracino is supported by an AFR grant (contract PDR-09-075) by the National Research Fund, Luxembourg cofunded under the Marie Curie Actions of the European Commission (FP7-COFUND).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ennio Bilancini.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Definition of Variables

Satisfaction with life a scale of 11 degrees ranging from 10, if respondent declares to be “completely satisfied”, to 0, if respondent declares to be “completely dissatisfied” (SOEP source variable: p1110107)

Married 1 if respondent reports to be currently married, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110407)

Separated 1 if respondent reports to be currently separated, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110407)

Divorced 1 if respondent reports to be currently divorced, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110407)

Widowed 1 if respondent reports to be currently widowed, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110407)

Female 1 if subject is female, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d11102ll)

Age number of years since born, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110107)

Age squared age to the power of 2, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110107)

Household size number of reported household members, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110607)

1 child 1 if in the household there is one child, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110707)

2 children 1 if in the household there is two children, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110707)

3 or more children 1 if in the household there is three or more children, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110707)

Years of education number of years the respondent declared to have attended school, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: d1110907)

Living with parents at 16 1 if respondent declares to be living with own parents at 16 years old, 0 otherwise (SOEP source vari-able: xh61)

Absolute income natural logarithm of Adjusted Monthly Household Net Income (Euro 2000) as provided in the SOEP, 0 otherwise (variable name: ahinc07)

Reference income natural logarithm of average Adjusted Monthly Household Net Income (Euro 2000) for a reference group as provided in the SOEP, 0 otherwise (variable name: ahinc07)

Past income Lag3 3 years temporal lag of the natural logarithm of Adjusted Monthly Household Net Income (Euro 2000) as provided in the SOEP, 0 otherwise (variable name: ahinc07)

Monthly at church 1 if respondent reports to attend at least once a month church or religious institutions, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: xp0309)

Monthly at culture events 1 if respondent reports to attend at least once a month cultural events, 0 otherwise (SOEP source vari-able: xp0301)

Monthly at cinema 1 if respondent reports to go at least once a month to the cinema, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: xp0302)

Monthly doing sport activities 1 if respondent reports to participate at least once a month to sport activities, 0 otherwise (SOEP sourcevariable: xp0303)

Monthly at social gatherings 1 if respondent reports to visit at least once a month friends, relatives or neighbours, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: xp0305)

Monthly helping friends 1 if respondent reports to help at least once a month friends, relatives or neighbours, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: xp0306)

Monthly volunteering 1 if respondent perform volunteer work at least once a month in clubs, associations or social services, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: xp0307)

Monthly local political participation 1 if respondent reports to participate at least once a month in citizens’ action groups, politic-al parties, local government, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: xp0308)

Unemployed 1 if respondent declares to be unemployed, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable:lfs07)

Student 1 if respondent declares to be student, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable:lfs07)

Non working 1 if respondent declares to be non-working, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable:lfs07)

Retired 1 if respondent declares to be retired, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable:lfs07)

Military/civil service 1 if respondent declares to be in military of civil service, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable:lfs07)

West 1 if respondent declares to live in West Germany, 0 otherwise (SOEP source variable: l1110207)

Appendix 2: Descriptives

See Table 5.

Appendix 3: Construction of reference groups

We defined reference group of individual i in year t as the sub-sample of individuals in Germany living in i’s region (west or east) in year t same year with education and age similar to i’s. More precisely, reference groups are defined using the following four different variables:

  • Year

    a scalar containing all years between 1984 and 2007;

  • West

    a dummy variable indicating living in West Germany;

  • \(\texttt{Age\_cls}\)

    a scalar indicating whether individuals are younger than 30, between 31 and 60 and 61 or older;

  • \(\texttt{Yreduc\_cls}\)

a three-value variable indicating whether individuals went through less than 11 years of education, between 11 and 12 years, or 13 or more years of education.

We used the following Stata 9.0 syntax to construct groups:

\(\texttt{egen Ref.Group = group(year west age\_cls2 yreduc\_cls2)}\)

\(\texttt{if !missing(year,west,age\_cls2,yreduc\_cls2)}\)

In this way, we generated a new variable assuming a different value for each possible group. This procedure generated 378 reference groups. Subsequently, we computed the income of the reference group as the mean value of the incomes of all the individuals in each reference group:

bys Ref.Group: egen ref.income = mean(income) if !missing(income)

Finally, we took the log of reference income:

gen lnref.income = ln(ref.income)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bartolini, S., Bilancini, E. & Sarracino, F. Predicting the Trend of Well-Being in Germany: How Much Do Comparisons, Adaptation and Sociability Matter?. Soc Indic Res 114, 169–191 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-012-0142-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-012-0142-5

Keywords

Navigation