1 Introduction

There is a rich literature providing insights into the determinants of entrepreneurship and its economic returns. Footnote 1 According to the expected utility theory, individuals choose self-employment when they expect higher returns from doing so relative to wage-employment (Rees and Shaw 1986). In contrast, according to the non-pecuniary benefits theory, people select into entrepreneurship, even if the expected returns are lower, in search of non-pecuniary benefits, such as being their own boss (Hamilton 2000). However, entrepreneurs are not a homogenous group of individuals, and the type of entrepreneurship engaged in may have a significant effect on the returns. Footnote 2

To date, there has been little research into the nature of entrepreneurship and its economic returns in developing countries. The purpose of this paper is to examine the welfare effects of different types of entrepreneurship in the context of a developing country. Using a direct measure of welfare, per-capita consumption expenditure, and quantile regressions, this study examines the returns to individuals’ occupational choice across the welfare distribution. Footnote 3 The results suggest that, across the welfare distribution, entrepreneurs who employ others have the highest returns in terms of consumption, while those entrepreneurs who work for themselves, that is, self-employed individuals, have slightly lower returns than the salaried employees. However, self-employment entails higher returns than casual labor and a relative escape from poverty.

The structure of the paper is as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of the theoretical background on occupational choice and welfare and sets out the hypotheses. The third section discusses the methodology employed in this paper to examine the returns to occupations across the welfare distribution, the quantile regressions. Data and descriptive statistics are presented in the fourth section, and the fifth section contains a discussion of the empirical analysis linking occupation and welfare. The paper concludes with a summary of the main findings linking occupation and welfare.

2 Theoretical background

A key observation of many studies, including that of Banerjee and Neuman (1993) and, more recently, that of Dabla-Norris et al. (2008), is the inherent hierarchy of occupational choice according to which the most productive individuals become entrepreneurs, the next best choose self-employment, and the rest become workers or subsistence workers. Dabla-Norris et al. (2008) propose that at equilibrium, the lowest productivity individuals are workers, individuals with intermediate productivity are informal entrepreneurs, and those who are most productive are formal sector entrepreneurs. These theoretical insights have yet to be empirically validated. The possibility of self-employment being worse off in the hierarchy relative to wage workers, as is traditionally assumed to be the case in less developed countries (Ranis and Fei 1961; Harris and Todaro 1970), or at least equal in returns, would contest the applicability of these theories to less developed countries (LDCs). The literature on LDCs traditionally identifies self-employment as a distressed residual of people rationed out of jobs in the formal sector, although more recent literature on the nature of the labor market in developing countries is not monolithic on this point. Some scholars believe that the informal sector in LDCs consists of voluntarily self-selected competitive workers as well as disadvantaged individuals (Gindling 1991; Magnac 1991; Cunningham and Maloney 2001; Maloney 2004; Fields 2005; Günther and Launov 2006). Footnote 4

Occupational choice is generally modeled as a utility-maximizing decision of individuals (Lucas 1978; Kihlstrom and Laffont 1979). Footnote 5 While many models in the economics of entrepreneurship assume that individuals become self-employed as they expect higher returns relative to wage employment (Rees and Shaw 1986; Blau 1987; Parker 1996), the labor and development literature suggests that in the LDC context, people are forced into self-employment in the absence of viable economic opportunities.

However, empirical studies, such as that of Hamilton (2000), that focus on developed countries suggest that entrepreneurs may trade lower earnings for the non-pecuniary benefits of business ownership. Footnote 6 Evans and Leighton (1989) suggest that individuals who prefer greater autonomy are more likely to be entrepreneurs. Blanchflower and Oswald (1998) show that business owners have greater job satisfaction than paid-employees. According to Boháček (2006), as successful firms grow over time, individuals may enter self-employment even if the returns are lower.

Thus, two main theories of returns to self-employment choice have emerged. First, the expected utility view claims that individuals choose self-employment when they expect higher returns in self-employment relative to wage-employment. This theory also explains the traditional low-productivity view of self-employment, which suggests that individuals are compelled into self-employment in the absence of viable economic alternatives. Second, the non-pecuniary benefits view argues that individuals select into entrepreneurship even when the returns are lower, for non-pecuniary benefits, such as being one’s boss.

I hypothesize that, given the occupational structure of individuals in an economy, the returns to occupations depend on the relative positioning of individuals in the welfare distribution. Self-employed individuals at the lower end of the distribution fundamentally differ from the self-employed individuals in the upper end of the distribution. This is also true for salaried employees. Occupations and their economic returns are characterized by a heterogeneity that is not discernable in studies that examine this relationship solely at the mean. By examining the returns to occupations across the welfare distribution, this paper sets out a novel approach to studying the relative returns to occupations.

A number of other factors that have been found to influence the per-capita consumption of the households are examined in this study. Dreze and Srinivasan (1997), using an earlier survey of India’s National Sample Survey Organization (NSSO), find that households that are female headed are more likely to be poor. Jenkins (2000) finds that changes in labor earnings from persons other than the household head, changes in non-labor income, changes in the earnings of the household head, and household composition are important determinants of the poverty dynamics. Miles (1997) finds that uncertainty, education, and location matter. Using both durable and non-durable goods in the welfare measure, Glewwe (1991) finds high returns to education in urban areas compared to rural areas in Côte d’Ivory. Nelson (1988) shows the existence of economies of scale in all adult households. Such economies of scale are found to be more important in the consumption of shelter and less so in the consumption of clothing and transportation. Footnote 7 Furthermore, a vast literature is concerned with equivalence scales in the measurements of welfare for comparisons across households. Households with the same income but different structures, in terms of the number of children and old people, are likely to have different consumption patterns. For example, Lanjouw and Ravallion (1995, pp. 1431–1432) suggest that the relationship between poverty and household size depends on the weight attached to child and adult welfare. Footnote 8 Hence, household demographic structure is controlled in the analysis reported here. In the Indian context, Dreze and Srinivasan (1997) find that the poverty head-count ratio is very robust to alternate equivalent scales. I also test the robustness of the results using adult equivalent scales. Footnote 9

3 Methodology

For testing the hypothesis of heterogenous returns of occupation across the welfare distribution, I employ quantile regressions (see Koenker and Hallock 2001, and references therein). The superstar model of Rosen (1981) suggests that a comparison of the mean earnings of workers in self-employed sector and in wage sector would be highly influenced by a few entrepreneurial superstars. Thus, mean earnings do not really characterize the returns of the majority of self-employed individuals. The greatest advantage of using quantile regressions is their ability to show snapshots of relationships across different quantiles of the distribution and not only at the mean.

4 Data

The data used for the analysis originate from the 60th round employment–unemployment survey of the National Sample Survey Organization (NSSO) of India. I only consider those households where the household heads are reported to be self-employed (includes own account workers and employers), salaried employees, casual laborers, and unemployed. The sample is restricted to those who are older than 15 years but younger than 70 years. I then consider only those households who work in the nonagriculture sectors. The final sample consists of 26,485 households, of which only the household head is economically active in 13,782 households.

Table 1 reports summary statistics of the database. The first two data columns report the mean and standard deviation of the variables when the entire database is considered. The third and fourth column report the descriptive statistics when the database is restricted to households that have the household head as the sole economically active member. As the descriptive data on monthly per-capita consumption expenditure (MPCE) in columns 1 and 3 show, employers have the highest average consumption rate. The self-employed individuals have an consumption rate that is lower than that of salaried employees but higher than the consumption rate of the casual laborers.

Table 1 Summary statistics

Figure 1 shows that kernel density plots of log per-capita consumption of households with heads working as self-employed, salaried employees, employers, and laborers. While the distribution plots of salaried employees and employers are to the right of the self-employed, the density of the laborers is centered to their left. The plots also show that the inequality observed in the employer group is substantially higher than that in the other groups.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Consumption and occupation (un-normalized)

5 Empirical results

5.1 Entrepreneurship and welfare

5.1.1 Household level analysis

The empirical strategy is to estimate simultaneous quantile regressions, using the log of per-capita consumption of the household as dependent variable. Footnote 10 As Browning and Lusardi (1996, p. 1801) note ‘although consumption changes are uncorrelated with anticipated income changes, the actual path of consumption may follow quite closely the actual path of income if the latter displays some persistence.’ Hence, the consumption and income paths are assumed to be correlated.

The occupations of the members of the household enter the regression as independent variables. A series of controls that are found to influence the consumption of the household by earlier studies are introduced in the estimation. In particular, personal characteristics of the household head, demographics of the household, including the proportion of children, adults, and old persons, educational background of the members, urban location, and land possessed are introduced as control variables. Footnote 11 State level dummies are also included to control for regional effects.

The results presented in Table 2 suggest that the entrepreneurship has a distinct relationship with welfare. As mentioned earlier, people in the database belong to one of the five primary occupations—they are either employers, self-employed, salaried employees, casual laborers, or unemployed. In this estimation, the category that is left out of the occupation variables is the proportion of economically active individuals in a household who are self-employed. As the positive coefficients suggest, households that have a higher proportion of employers and those that a higher proportion of salaried employees have higher per-capita consumption levels than self-employed households. However, households that have a higher proportion of casual laborers and unemployed people have lower welfare levels than self-employed households. This result suggests the existence of a welfare hierarchy that is determined by the occupational choices of the members of the household.

Table 2 Households, occupation, and consumption

As the estimates in Table 2 suggest, employers are increasingly better off at higher quantiles than self-employed workers. Salaried employees who are in the middle of the distribution show the greatest difference from the self-employed individuals compared to those at the extreme quantiles. At higher quantiles, casual laborers are increasingly worse off than the self-employed individuals, and a similar phenomenon is observed for the unemployed. Footnote 12

The coefficients of control variables are in accordance with what might be expected. Households with older household heads are more likely to have higher consumption rates, and female-headed households are poorer across quantiles. Female-headed households are the most worse off at the lowest quantile of the distribution. Households with a higher proportion of educated individuals have higher consumption rates, and the returns are increasing along the quantiles as well as along higher levels of education. The proportion of children <15 years old in the household has a significant negative effect at the lowest two quantiles, but this vanishes at higher quantiles. However, the proportion of old people in a household significantly increases the per-capita consumption expenditure. A 1% increase in the proportion of elderly people increases the per-capita consumption by 18% at the lowest quantile and 38% at the highest quantile. The proportion of females has an insignificant effect in the lower two quantiles but a significant positive effect at higher quantiles. Thus, at median, a 1% increase in the proportion of females increases the per-capita consumption by 4.4%, and at q(.9), by 9%. The coefficients of the household size variables show that the relationship between household size and welfare of the household is consistent with earlier studies that households of larger size have a lower per-capita consumption expenditure. However, the household size squared term is positive and increases across quantiles, indicating that households of larger size become worse off along the quantiles, but at decreasing rates. Thus, a convex relationship exists between household size and welfare, with households in the middle of the distribution showing the greatest negative effect of size on per-capita consumption. This could be the result of higher economies of scale at the tails of the income distribution.

The quantile plots in Fig. 2 allow visualization of the estimated effects of the occupation variables on the per-capita consumption expenditure at different quantiles of the distribution. The X-axis shows the quantiles and the Y-axis shows the magnitude of the effect of the independent variables on the dependent variable. The dotted line shows the effect of the independent variable on the dependent variable if a simple ordinary least squares (OLS) regression is estimated. The curve shows the estimated effect of the independent variables on the per-capita consumption expenditure across different quantiles. The grey region around the curve shows the 95% confidence interval for the estimated effects. As the quantile plots in Fig. 2 show, the effect of occupation on the per-capita expenditure is non-linear and varies across quantiles. As the first sub-plot shows, the effect of being employers on per-capita consumption expenditure increases across the quantiles, varying from 0.34 at the lowest quantile to 0.45 at the highest quantile. Although the effect is significantly positive throughout, the magnitude of the effect is much smaller at the lower quantiles than at the higher quantiles. The second sub-plot shows that being salaried employees has a positive effect on per-capita consumption expenditure. However, the effect has an inverted U shape across quantiles. Similar non-linear effects are seen in the case of laborers and unemployed—the effects, however, are negative in both cases. Thus, estimating the mean effect of occupations on per-capita consumption expenditure in a simple OLS framework would not have captured these nonlinear effects.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Quantile plots. The graph shows the non-linear effects of the occupation variables, across different quantiles, on the per-capita consumption expenditure. The quantiles are on the X-axis, and the estimated effects of occupations on the per-capita consumption expenditure are on the Y-axis

Individuals choose occupations by maximizing expected utility over lifetime. As one example, a higher degree of risk aversion and a preference for stability at the workplace may make individuals choose salaried employment, even if their income in the immediate future is relatively lower than that of the entrepreneurs. However, due to the cross-sectional nature of the database, this study is limited to examining the relative positioning of individuals in different occupational groups, across the welfare distribution. The results should be interpreted carefully given this caveat.

5.1.2 Analysis restricted to household heads

One of the main limitations of the analysis of the household level occupation data is the simultaneous determination of the occupation of the household members leading to potential endogeneity of the occupation variables. Thus, the occupation of members of the household may not be independent of the occupation of the head of the household, in the presence of intra-household dependence of occupation choice. Footnote 13 In order to reduce the potential endogenous determination of the occupational choice of the household based on the occupational choice of the household head, we re-estimate the simultaneous quantile regressions for a restricted sample of households that have only the household head as the economically active individual in Table 3. This is more likely to give the pure effect of occupation, and entrepreneurship in particular, on household welfare. Footnote 14

Table 3 Household heads, occupation, and consumption

The dataset on the unemployed is also dropped from the analysis as there are only 90 heads of household who are unemployed. Furthermore, as a check for robustness of the results in Table 2, the industry sector of the individuals in Table 3 is controlled as there may be sectoral differences in returns to self-employment. Footnote 15 The base category for the occupation variables is ‘salaried employee’. The estimation results are consistent with the estimations of the quantile regressions presented in Table 2. The results presented in Table 3 confirm the welfare hierarchy that the earlier regression suggested. Households headed by employers and salaried individuals have a higher per-capita consumption than households headed by self-employed individuals and casual laborers—after other factors that influence household welfare have been controlled. The magnitude of the coefficient of ‘employer’ suggests that households headed by entrepreneurs who employ others have the highest consumption levels. Relative to households headed by salaried employees, households headed by employers have consumption rates that 22.4% higher at the smallest quantile (q0), 25.8% higher at the median (q50), and 30.6% higher at the largest quantile (q90). Although the coefficient of salaried employees is positive, it is small, and salaried employees are only slightly better off than those who are self-employed. Footnote 16 Households headed by self-employed individuals have consumption rates that are 4.9% lower at the smallest quantile q(10), and 6.3% lower at the median (q50). As suggested by the insignificant coefficient on the self-employed variable in the q90 column, households headed by self-employed individuals and salaried employees have no significant difference in the consumption rates at the upper end of the distribution. The casual laborers are last in the hierarchy. Laborers have consumption rates that are 20%–24.5% lower across the distribution. Thus, the results support the conjecture that relative returns to occupations differ across the welfare distribution and a comparison of returns at only the mean would not uncover these nonlinear effects.

Table 3 suggests that at lower quantiles, informal education has a significantly positive effect on the per-capita consumption. The returns to primary school education increase along the quantiles. It is seen that at the lowest quantile [q(.1)], primary schooling increases the per-capita consumption of the household by 14%. The coefficient, however, is higher at the highest quantile, q(.9), where it raises the per-capita consumption of household by 19%. A similar effect is observed for other education variables. If the household head has a high school education, per-capita consumption expenditure increases by 23% at the lowest quantile and 36% at the highest quantile. Similarly, if the household head has a university education, the per-capita consumption of the household increases by 41% at the lowest quantile and by 73% at the highest quantile. Thus, education has a positive effect on the per-capita consumption and increases as individuals move from the lower to higher quantiles. The returns to technical degree/diploma are also positive and increase as individuals shift from the lower to the higher quantiles. Footnote 17 The estimates of the control variables are in accordance with the hypotheses and are consistent with the estimation in Table 2.

5.1.3 Entrepreneurship and poverty

Per-capita consumption of individuals is predicted after estimating the quantile regression at different quantiles. Footnote 18 The cumulative distribution plots of occupation-wise predicted values are shown in Fig. 3. The per-capita expenditure is on the X-axis and the cumulative probability is on the Y-axis. At any point x on the X-axis, the cumulative distribution function of a particular occupational category would give the proportion of individuals in that occupational category whose consumption is below x. It can be seen that in all the sub-plots of Fig. 3, at any given point x on the X-axis, the proportion of employers whose per-capita consumption expenditure is below x is lower than the proportion of salaried employees whose per-capita expenditure is below x. An analogous argument implies that the proportion of salaried employees whose per-capita consumption expenditure is below x is lower than the proportion of self-employed individuals or casual laborers whose per-capita consumption expenditure is below x. The plots show that the cumulative distribution function of employers stochastically dominates the distributions of other occupational categories. Since x is any point on the X-axis, the figure does away with the necessity of having a fixed poverty line to examine the relative poverty in different occupational groups.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Occupation and poverty plots

A simple mathematical formulation of the above arguments is as follows. Let the cumulative distribution functions of the four occupational categories be given by functions F emp for employers, F sal for salaried employees, F self for self-employed individuals, and F lab for laborers. At any given point x on the X-axis, the plots show that that F emp(x) < F sal(x) < F self(x) < F lab(x). Thus, the employers group would have the least proportion of people under the poverty line, if the poverty line is at x.

The plot clarifies the status of the self-employed; they appear to be sandwiched between the salaried employees and the casual laborers. A direct implication of this observation is that, conditional on other characteristics, individuals in the informal sector, primarily comprising the self-employed and the casual laborers, have lower returns to their occupations. Furthermore, if the dataset is split into formal and informal sectors, with laborers and self-employed in the informal sector and salaried employees and employers in the formal sector, the plots suggest that in both sectors, entrepreneurship in the form of employers in the formal sector and self-employed in the informal sector entails higher relative consumption.

I also analyzed occupational choice as a determinant of poverty of households using a probit model. A widely used relative measure of poverty, given by half of the median per-capita consumption of all the households, was considered as the poverty line. Footnote 19 The results suggest that while households headed by employers, self-employed, and salaried employees are less likely to be under the poverty line, households headed by casual laborers are most likely to be under the poverty line, after controlling many characteristics that are likely to influence their poverty status. Footnote 20

6 Conclusion

This paper makes important contributions to the literature on the economics of entrepreneurship. I have extensively examined the welfare consequences of entrepreneurship in a developing country, an area of study that has received little attention to date.

Using simultaneous quantile regressions, I have found that employers, those entrepreneurs who also hire others, have the highest returns in terms of consumption, while the self-employed, those entrepreneurs who work for themselves, have slightly lower returns than the salaried employees. The results demonstrate that the relative returns to occupations differ at different points of the welfare distribution. Thus, empirical studies that consider only mean returns for broad occupational categories miss important variations in the data. For instance, although the consumption rates of self-employed household heads is significantly lower at many points of the distribution relative to the salaried household heads, there is no significant difference at the highest quantile. A comparison of returns at the mean alone would not have uncovered these nonlinear effects. Self-employed are more likely to escape poverty, as are salaried employees and entrepreneurs who are employers, when compared to casual laborers. The results are robust to alternate empirical specifications.