Skip to main content
Log in

The profitability, costs and systematic risk of the post-earnings-announcement-drift trading strategy

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper re-examines the profitability of the post-earnings-announcement-drift (PEAD) trading strategy using a practical simulation approach that aligns with a fund manager’s investment perspective. It allows us to calculate the break-even transaction costs of following a PEAD strategy, and permits the explicit incorporation of transaction costs. Using US data from 1974 to 2007, we show that the traditional event-study method understates the risk and overstates the abnormal return of the PEAD strategy. Accounting for transaction costs in a practical simulation framework, we show there is no abnormal return (alpha) from the PEAD strategy in multi-factor asset pricing regression analyses. These results are robust to sub-period analyses and alternative transaction cost measures. The effects of intraday timing and information risk on the PEAD strategy are also explored. Overall, our study shows that the practical aspects of implementing the PEAD strategy are vitally important to evaluating the risk and return of the strategy. We provide a practical, analytical tool that can be directly adopted by fund managers to study the PEAD strategy with their institutional parameters of transaction costs and market timing.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Ball (1978), Latane and Jones (1979), Bidwell and Riddle (1981), Rendleman et al. (1982), Foster et al. (1984), Bernard and Thomas (1989, 1990) and other following studies, such as Bernard and Seyhun (1997).

  2. The average price is defined as the average of the opening, high, low and closing prices.

  3. In our sample we find that a long-bad-news portfolio would produce an average positive quarterly return of 1.84 % which is annualized to be 7.67 %.

  4. The choice of the fund size does not matter in terms of calculating returns; it only matters when there is a need to consider the price impact of a large-size trade.

  5. This is part of the trading strategy to close the position. Alternative holding periods can be considered but this holding period is closest to the event-study approach where 60-day CARs are used to measure the drift. While alternative exit days are examined (2 or 5 days before the next earnings announcement) the main conclusions of this paper remain.

  6. As a robustness check, we run the model with the liquidity factor from Pastor and Stambaugh (2003) and those from Sadka (2006) which we obtain from the websites of Professor Pastor and Professor Sadka, respectively. The main results remain the same with the liquidity factor being insignificant in all regressions.

  7. http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html.

  8. We also conduct a robustness check by examining the overnight announcements to see if trading at the next morning opening price would affect the profitability of the strategy. We find that trading closer to the announcement improves the size of the profit slightly but the higher profit comes with a cost of higher volatility since trading around the announcement is more volatile. We thank the referee for his/her suggestion on this test.

  9. The daily low, high and average prices are assumed to be the buy prices and the daily high, low and average prices are assumed to be the sell prices for the best, worse and average timing portfolios respectively.

  10. Given the similarity of the results for different cost measure in the previous section, we examine only the sub-period between 1993 and 2007 with the BAS being used as the transaction costs measure. .

  11. Does this finding of the significant positive alpha on portfolio 1/AGE4 suggest that the market is inefficient? From an asset pricing point of view, it suggests that the market is not efficient in pricing this group of stocks. However, it does not suggest that the market as a whole is not efficient since the majority of the portfolio returns can be explained by risk factors.

References

  • Ball R (1978) Anomalies in relationships between securities yields and yield-surrogates. J Financ Econ 6:103–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball R, Brown P (1968) Empirical evaluation of accounting income numbers. J Acc Res 6:159–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battalio RH, Mendenhall RR (2007) Post earnings announcement drift: timing and liquidity costs. Working paper. University of Notre Dame

  • Bernard V, Seyhun HN (1997) Does post-earnings-announcement drift in stock prices reflect a market inefficiency? A stochastic dominance approach. Rev Quant Financ Acc 9:17–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard VL, Thomas JK (1989) Post earnings announcement drift: delayed price response or risk premium. J Acc Res 27:1–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard VL, Thomas JK (1990) Evidence that stock-prices do not fully reflect the implications of current earnings for future earnings. J Acc Econ 13:305–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessembinder H, Chan K (1998) Market efficiency and the returns to technical analysis. Financ Manag 27:5–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhushan R (1994) An informational efficiency perspective on the post-earnings announcement drift. J Acc Econ 18:45–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bidwell CM, Riddle JR (1981) Market inefficiencies: opportunities for profits. J Acc Audit Financ 4:198–214

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird R, Choi DF, Yeung D (2013) Market uncertainty, market sentiment, and the post-earnings announcement drift. Rev Quant Financ Acc. Forthcoming

  • Brock W, Lakonish J, LeBaron B (1992) Simple technical rules and the stochastic properties of stock returns. J Financ 47:1731–1764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carhart MM (1997) On persistence in mutual fund performance. J Financ 52:57–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan LKC, Jegadeesh N, Lakonishok J (1996) Momentum strategies. J Financ 51:1681–1713

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chordia T, Goyal A, Sadka R, Sadka G, Shivakumar L (2009) Liquidity and the post-earnings-announcement drift. Financ Analyst J 65:18–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Avolio G (2002) The market for borrowing stock. J Financ Econ 66:271–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daniel K, Titman S (1997) Evidence on the characteristics of cross sectional variation in stock returns. J Financ 52:1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (1993) Common risk-factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. J Financ Econ 33:3–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster G, Olsen C, Shevlin T (1984) Earnings releases, anomalies, and the behavior of security returns. Acc Rev 59:574–603

    Google Scholar 

  • Garfinkel JA, Sokobin J (2006) Volume, opinion divergence, and returns: a study of post-earnings announcement drift. J Acc Res 44:85–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gregoriou A, Ioannidis C, Ghosh S (2009) Heterogeneous time varying transaction costs and asset pricing in international equity markets. Financ Mark Portf Manag 23:271–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grinblatt M, Moskowitz TJ (2004) Predicting stock price movements from past returns: the role of consistency and tax-loss selling. J Financ Econ 71:541–579

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasbrouck J (2009) Trading costs and returns for U.S. equities: estimating effective costs from daily data. J Financ 64:1445–1477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ke B, Ramalingegowda S (2005) Do institutional investors exploit the post-earnings announcement drift? J Acc Econ 39:25–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim D, Kim M (2003) A multifactor explanation of post-earnings announcement drift. J Financ Quant Anal 38:383–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Latane HA, Jones CP (1979) Standardized unexpected earnings: 1971–77. J Financ 34:717–724

    Google Scholar 

  • Lesmond DA, Ogden JP, Trzcinka CA (1999) A new estimate of transaction costs. Rev of Financ Stud 12:1113–1141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendenhall RR (2004) Arbitrage risk and post-earnings-announcement drift. J Bus 77:875–894

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng J, Rusticus TO, Verdi RS (2008) Implications of transaction costs for the post-earnings announcement drift. J Acc Res 46:661–696

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastor L, Stambaugh RF (2003) Liquidity risk and expected stock returns. J Polit Econ 111:642–685

    Google Scholar 

  • Rendleman RJ, Jones CP, Latane HA (1982) Empirical anomalies based on unexpected earnings and the importance of risk adjustments. J Financ Econ 10:269–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roll R (1984) A simple implicit measure of the effective bid-ask spread in an efficient market. J Financ 39:1127–1139

    Google Scholar 

  • Sadka R (2006) Momentum and post-earnings-announcement drift anomalies: the role of liquidity risk. J Financ Econ 80:309–349

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang XF (2006) Information uncertainty and analyst forecast behavior. J Financ 61:105–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the two anonymous referees and the editor of the Journal, Professor Cheng-few Lee, for their helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Charlie X. Cai.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Classification of earnings surprise

While Foster et al. (1984) construct two time-series models to calculate earnings surprise (standardized unexpected earnings—SUE) and measure the significance of PEAD, they also find that a simple seasoned random-walk model performs just as well. Because of the simplicity of the calculation, this model has been widely used by subsequent studies (for example Bernard and Thomas 1989; Chan et al. 1996) and is also adopted here as our main earnings classification method.

For each calendar quarter, stocks have been divided into 10 deciles based on the SUE, which is calculated as follows:

$$SUE_{i,t} = \frac{{e_{i,q} - e_{i,q - 4} }}{{\sigma_{i,t} }} $$
(7)

where e i,q is the quarterly earnings observation before extraordinary items and discontinued operations for stock i at quarter q, and e i,q−4 is the observation four quarters prior. σ i,t is the standard deviation of (e i,q e i,q−4 ) over the preceding eight quarters.

Once the SUE has been calculated for each calendar quarter, the cut-off points used to classify SUE into 10 deciles are based on the ranking of the previous quarter’s SUE. Foster et al. (1984) first used this method to resolve the cut-off point problem. At each calendar quarter, earnings announcements with the most negative surprise SUE values are assigned to Decile 1 and those with the most positive surprise SUE values are assigned to Decile 10.

Appendix 2: The limited dependent variable model for transaction costs

The limited dependent variable model for estimating transaction costs is introduced by Lesmond et al. (1999). The basic intuition of the model is that marginal investors will not choose to trade if the benefit of trading does not exceed transaction costs, and this will result in a zero return for a given day. Marginal investors can be informed traders or uninformed traders. For informed traders, they compare transaction costs with their information, and for uninformed traders, they compare transaction costs with their needs for liquidity. Therefore, when transaction costs stop marginal investors trading, we will observe a realized zero return which deviates from the true return generating process. Lesmond et al. (1999) use a market model to measure the true returns process as follows,

$$R_{jt}^{*} = \beta_{j} R_{mt} + \varepsilon_{jt} , $$
(8)

where \(R_{jt}^{*}\) is the true return for security j at day t, and R mt is the market return at day t. The relation between the observed return R jt and the true return \(R_{jt}^{*}\) is given by following equations,

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {R_{jt} = R_{jt}^{*} - \alpha_{1j} } & {if} & {R_{jt}^{*} < \alpha_{1j} } \\ {R_{jt} = 0} & {if} & {\alpha_{1j} < R_{jt}^{*} < \alpha_{2j} } \\ {R_{jt} = R_{jt}^{*} - \alpha_{2j} } & {if} & {R_{jt}^{*} > \alpha_{2j} } \\ \end{array} $$
(9)

where α 1j is the transaction cost threshold for trades on negative information (selling), and α 2j is the threshold for trades on positive information (buying). α 2j – α 1j is the measure for round trip transaction costs.

By assuming the error term follows a normal distribution N(0, σ j ), the maximum likelihood method can be used to estimate the model with following log likelihood function,

$$\begin{aligned} Ln(L) & = \sum\limits_{1} {\ln \frac{1}{{(2\pi \sigma_{j}^{2} )^{1/2} }} - } \sum\limits_{1} {\frac{1}{{2\sigma_{j}^{2} }}} (R_{jt} + \alpha_{1j} - \beta_{j} R_{mt} )^{2} \\ & \quad + \sum\limits_{2} {\ln \frac{1}{{(2\pi \sigma_{j}^{2} )^{1/2} }} - } \sum\limits_{2} {\frac{1}{{2\sigma_{j}^{2} }}} (R_{jt} + \alpha_{2j} - \beta_{j} R_{mt} )^{2} \\ & \quad + \sum\limits_{0} {\ln (\Upphi_{2} \left( {\frac{{\alpha_{2j} - \beta_{j} R_{mt} }}{{\sigma_{j} }}} \right) - \Upphi_{1} \left( {\frac{{\alpha_{1j} - \beta_{j} R_{mt} }}{{\sigma_{j} }}} \right)} \\ \end{aligned} $$
(10)

where 0, 1, 2 represent the subsample of zero, negative and positive observed returns, respectively. Φ1 and Φ2 are standard normal distribution functions.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Zhang, Q., Cai, C.X. & Keasey, K. The profitability, costs and systematic risk of the post-earnings-announcement-drift trading strategy. Rev Quant Finan Acc 43, 605–625 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-013-0386-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-013-0386-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation