Skip to main content
Log in

Under the Cover of Antidumping: Does Administered Protection Facilitate Domestic Collusion?

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Anecdotal evidence suggests that domestic firms can use the antidumping petition process to engage in collusion and increase domestic prices. In this paper, I test whether the antidumping petition process itself can help domestic firms raise prices. I propose a method to identify whether firms in the industry experience a structural break in the level of market power possessed by the firms at the time that they file their antidumping petition. I use this methodology to analyze the impact of antidumping petitions on competition levels in two industries. I find little evidence that either of these industries increased their market power following the filing of petitions for trade relief, nor even from the protection that resulted from these petitions. These findings suggest that the widespread belief that antidumping leads to more market power may not always hold.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The US Justice Department investigation resulted in a 1995 plea agreement with one firm (Elkem Metals) and a 1997 conviction of another firm and one of its senior officials (SKW Metals and Alloys). In light of these criminal activities, the US International Trade Commission rescinded the antidumping order in 1999.

  2. In this case, an official from one firm pleaded guilty to price fixing charges that covered a period as early as September 1999 and as late as 2001, while an official from another firm was eventually acquitted of similar charges. The International Trade Commission did not find the evidence of price fixing to be compelling enough to review the antidumping case.

  3. Antidumping is certainly not the only legal procedure that could be used to encourage anticompetitive behavior. Klein (2011) conducts a general analysis of “sham litigation,” or lawsuits brought solely to gain a competitive advantage in violation of antitrust laws.

  4. For example, in 1999 Cheminor Drugs filed suit against Ethyl Corporation claiming that Ethyl’s antidumping petition against Cheminor (which Ethyl withdrew prior to a final determination) was baseless, and filed solely for anticompetitive reasons in violation of the antitrust laws. A court of appeals rejected Cheminor’s case, citing the fact that the International Trade Commission made a preliminary affirmative injury determination in the case. Similar allegations were made against Prestini Musical Instruments Corp. for their antidumping filings against Italian producers of musical instrument parts in 1983. The court also rejected this case.

  5. Stegemann (1990) studies a similar class of antidumping cases in which the government reaches an out-of-court settlement with the foreign industry, in which the foreign industry officially agrees to raise prices (a price undertaking) rather than face antidumping duties. Based on his sample of EU cases, Stegemann concludes that while these price undertakings are a legal substitute for illegal price fixing at some level, there is no public evidence that firms are using these undertakings to engage in collusion with their foreign counterparts in excess of that allowed for under antidumping law.

  6. Although the basic principles of US and European antidumping law are the same, there are some notable differences: For example, European antidumping petitions more often result in undertakings, in which the foreign firms agree to raise their prices. European antidumping law also specifies that the government must weigh the total welfare effects of the antidumping duties, explicitly taking into account the interests of consumers as well as producers.

  7. An antidumping petition is deemed to have been filed on behalf of the domestic industry if domestic producers and workers who support the petition account for (1) 25 % of the total production of the product and (2) 50 % of the production of those who both support and oppose the petition.

  8. Petitions often request that antidumping duties be imposed on more than one country, and the ITA and the ITC officially launch a separate investigation for each country that is targeted in the petition. Thus these 545 petitions resulted in 1,200 antidumping investigations, of which 44 % resulted in the imposition of antidumping duties, and 10 % were withdrawn prior to the government’s making a determination.

  9. This is admittedly a non-trivial assumption. Corts (1999) demonstrates that conduct parameter methods can result in severe mis-measurement if the underlying firm behavior is not the result of a conjectural variations equilibrium.

  10. US DRAM producers included Advanced Micro Devices (AMD), AT&T Technology, Fujitsu, Hitachi, IBM, Mitsubishi, Mostek, NEC Electronics, Texas Instruments, and Toshiba. Three additional firms had just recently ceased production of DRAMS, including Intel, Motorola, and National Semiconductor.

  11. Other US EPROM producers at this time included Fujitsu, Mostek (a division of United Technologies until 1985, at which time it was acquired by Thomson SA), Motorola, Rockwell International, SEEQ Technology, and Texas Instruments.

  12. The agreement also included provisions for Japan to provide sales assistance to US companies that were trying to export to Japan, with the goal of US producers achieving a 20 % market share within five years (Tyson 1992).

  13. Micron again asked for antidumping protection from foreign producers of semiconductors: antidumping duties were imposed against Korean producers of DRAMS on May 10, 1993, and against Taiwanese producers of static random access memory (SRAM) chips on April 16, 1998. These duties were revoked on October 5, 2000, and January 14, 2002, respectively.

  14. Because the semiconductor industry already had a long history of cooperation to prior to 1985, one may not expect to see a structural break in their level of competition due solely to their coordination on this trade relief petition.

  15. Tyson (1992) reports that there is some evidence, including pricing rules and a restraint on investment, that the Agreement may have led to cooperative behavior (or collusion) among Japanese firms in 1988 and 1989.

  16. In 2002, the US Department of Justice began investigating price fixing claims in the semiconductor industry, specifically against five producers of DRAMS, including Micron, which allegedly took place between the end of 2001 and mid-2002. Several of these firms eventually pled guilty to price fixing charges. This period of uncompetitive behavior could explain the increase in market power exhibited by Micron toward the end of the sample period.

  17. This result contradicts the results in Nieberding (1999), who found that Timkin experienced an increase in the market power statistic in the period after antidumping protection (between January 1988 and December 1992). I was unable to replicate Nieberding’s (1999) results even after restricting my sample to the same time period and including a single break in January 1988. This may be due to the vastly different market share values that are used in the analysis. As is noted in the “Appendix”, I calculated market share using two different denominators: the sum of sales that are reported in Compustat by the five public firms at the time of the antidumping petition that produced the product under investigation and the average quarterly sales in the ball bearing industry as calculated using the data from the US Census Bureau’s Annual Survey of Manufacturers. Although the results presented here use the former definition, results from the latter were qualitatively similar. Neither market share definition replicates those reported in Nieberding’s (1999) summary statistics, and the author did not report how he calculated the denominator of his market share statistic.

References

  • Bai, J., & Perron, P. (1998). Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural changes. Econometrica, 66(1), 47–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corts, K. S. (1999). Conduct parameters and the measurement of market power. Journal of Econometrics, 88(2), 227–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartigan, J. C. (1995). Collusive aspects of cost revelation through antidumping complaints. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 151(3), 478–489.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartigan, J. C., Kamma, S., & Perry, P. P. (1989). The injury determination category and the value of relief from dumping. Review of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 183–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, C. (2011). Deregulation and the demise of sham litigation: A structural time series test. Paper presented at the 9th annual meeting of the international industrial organization conference, Boston.

  • Konings, J., & Vandenbussche, H. (2005). Antidumping protection and markups of domestic firms. Journal of International Economics, 65(1), 151–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, K. M. (2004). Free riders among the rent seekers: A model of firm participation in antidumping petitions. Retrieved April 22, 2013, from American University Web site: http://aladinrc.wrlc.org/bitstream/handle/1961/4941/200404-01.pdf

  • Martin, S. (1988). The measurement of profitability and the diagnosis of market power. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 6(3), 301–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nieberding, J. F. (1999). The effect of US antidumping law on firms’ market power: An empirical test. Review of Industrial Organization, 14(1), 65–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pierce, R. J. (1999). Antidumping law as a means of facilitating cartelization. Antitrust Law Journal, 67, 725–743.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prusa, T. J. (1992). Why are so many antidumping petitions withdrawn? Journal of International Economics, 33(1), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutkowski, A. (2007). Withdrawals of antidumping complaints in the EU: A sign of collusion. World Economy, 30(3), 470–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staiger, R. W., & Wolak, F. A. (1994). Measuring industry specific protection: Antidumping in the United States. In M. N. Bailey & P. C. Winston (Eds.), Brookings papers on economic activity: Microeconomics (pp. 51–118). Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stegemann, K. (1990). EC antidumping policy: Are price undertakings a legal substitute for illegal price fixing? Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 126(2), 268–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, C. (2004). The economic effects of withdrawn antidumping investigations: Is there evidence of collusive settlements? Journal of International Economics, 62(2), 295–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tyson, L. D. (1992). Managing trade and competition in the semiconductor industry. In Who’s bashing whom? Trade conflict in high-technology industries (pp. 85–154). Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

  • Veugelers, R., & Vandenbussche, H. (1999). European anti-dumping policy and the profitability of national and international collusion. European Economic Review, 43(1), 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zanardi, M. (2004). Antidumping law as a collusive device. Canadian Journal of Economics, 37(1), 95–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kara M. Reynolds.

Appendix

Appendix

As noted in the text, all variables were obtained from Compustat’s quarterly data. Specific definitions of each variable are included below, and summary statistics are included in Table 8.

Table 8 Summary statistics

Price-Cost Margin (PCM): Pre-Tax Income (piq)/Total Revenue (revtq)

Market Share (MS): Firm Sales (saleq)/Total Sales. Although the Compustat variable includes the firm’s global sales, I calculate the market share in the semiconductor industry by dividing by US domestic semiconductor sales (i.e. those sales made by all firms (foreign and domestic) in the US market, as reported by the Semiconductor Industry Association, in order to make sure that I capture the sales of all competitors, not just the public company competitors. The results that are presented for the ball bearing industry calculate total sales by adding the sales that are reported in Compustat of the five public firms at the time of the antidumping petition which produced the product under investigation. Results that use average quarterly sales in the ball bearing industry as calculated using the data from the US Census Bureau’s Annual Survey of Manufacturers were qualitatively similar to those presented here.

Capital Stock to Sales Ratio (KSR): Total Property, Plant and Equipment (ppentq)/Firm Sales (saleq).

Interest Expense to Sales Ratio (ISR): Interest and Related Expenses (xintq)/Firm Sales (saleq)

Receipts from new Stock Issue to Sales Ratio (NSR): After 1983, I calculate this variable as the difference between the Sales of New Common Stock (sstky) and Purchase of New Common Stock (prstkcy) divided by firm sales (saleq). Prior to 1983, I had to calculate this variable using the change in outstanding shares (shares) multiplied by share price at the end of the quarter. For each firm, I took into account stock splits in calculating this variable.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Reynolds, K.M. Under the Cover of Antidumping: Does Administered Protection Facilitate Domestic Collusion?. Rev Ind Organ 42, 415–434 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-013-9385-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-013-9385-9

Keywords

Navigation