Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Strategic Investment in Climate Friendly Technologies: The Impact of Global Emissions Trading

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Our point of departure is that a group of industrialized countries invest in research and development (R&D) of greenhouse gas (GHG) abatement technologies. R&D investments influence the future GHG abatement choices of both industrialized and developing countries. We distinguish between investments that reduce industrialized countries’ abatement costs and investments that reduce developing countries’ abatement costs. Unlike earlier contributions, we include global trading in emission permits. This changes the nature of the game. With global permit trading, industrialized countries should in many cases invest strategically in technologies that only reduce abatement costs at home. This comes in addition to investments abroad. Second, we show that R&D investments always decrease total emissions. Finally, we find that the developing region receiving investments always benefits.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Buchholz and Konrad (1994) also show that unilateral technology adoption might affect the outcome of international negotiations. If countries at a later stage bargain about emission reductions, the present unilateral actions change the cooperative outcome through their impact on the disagreement point, which is defined as the noncooperative Nash–Cournot equilibrium. Strategic investment in sunk capital to manipulate the outcome of the terms of an international environmental agreement is also studied in Stranlund (1999).

  2. One can of course envisage the developing country as a group of developing countries like the G77, as long as the group is able to agree on one emission reduction target.

  3. In a supplementary paper to this paper we consider the case of knowledge spillovers between the two types of technology investments. Including the spillover has no qualitative effect on the results for the global permit trading case. The supplementary paper can be obtained from the authors upon request.

  4. R&D of type \(k_{a}\) carried out by industrialized countries could also complement or be a substitute for R&D investments carried out by developing countries themselves. In the former case, \(k_{a}\) would induce more R&D by the developing countries, while in the latter case, \(k_{a}\) would crowd out R&D by developing countries. As long as the crowding out is less than 100 %, it should in principle be possible for the industrialized region to decide \(k_{a}\) through the use of technology export subsidies/restrictions.

  5. Exceptions can be found in Bauman et al. (2008) and Baker et al. (2008). The latter provides an overview of a number of models that comprise cases where technical change leads to an increase in marginal abatement costs at high levels of abatement.

  6. The first order conditions are found by differentiating (6) w.r.t \(k_{h}\) and \(k_{a}\)and inserting (5). It can be shown that the second order conditions for a welfare maximum are fulfilled.

  7. Tirole (1988) defines overinvestment (underinvestment) as a higher (lower) level of investment than the level of investment in the hypothetical case without the strategic effect.

  8. Without the strategic effect, the level of investment abroad would be zero. Moreover, underinvestment, i.e. \(k_{a}<0\), is not possible since \(k_{a}\) cannot be negative.

  9. Note that with technology spillovers, this may no longer hold. See the supplementary paper, which can be obtained from the authors upon request.

  10. Provided that \(\lim _{k_{a}\rightarrow 0}\left[ b_{h}^{\prime }\frac{\partial e_{a}^{N}}{\partial k_{a}}\right] >p_{a}\) as assumed by Stranlund (1996).

  11. We assume that the equilibrium is unique. In section “The uniqueness of the Nash-equilibrium in the permit trading case” of Appendix we show this is satisfied for \(\frac{\partial ^{3}c_{i}}{(\partial e_{i})^{3}}=0\).

  12. Note that the permit price will equal the marginal cost of emission reductions in the permit trading equilibrium.

  13. For instance, this holds in our numerical example.

  14. In the supplementary paper to this paper mentioned in Note 3, we also consider the case of \(\eta _{1}=a_{1}=0\) analytically.

  15. Note that this paper ignores technology spill-overs, which is another source of too little private investment (see further discussion in the next section).

  16. See the Appendix for further comments on the parameter choices.

  17. We have \(-\frac{\partial t^{*}}{\partial k_{j}}+\frac{\partial t^{*} }{\partial \bar{e}_{i}}\frac{\partial e_{i}^{*}}{\partial k_{j}}=\, -c_{iek}^{\prime \prime }\left( \frac{c_{j}^{\prime \prime }}{c_{h}^{\prime \prime }+c_{a}^{\prime \prime }}\right) ^{2}>0.\)

References

  • Baker E, Clarke L, Shittu E (2008) Technical change and the marginal cost of abatement. Energy Econ 30(6):2799–2816

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett S (1999) A theory of full international cooperation. J Theor Polit 11(4):519–541

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauman Y, Lee M, Seeley K (2008) Does technological innovation really reduce marginal abatement costs? Some theory, algebraic evidence, and policy implications. Environ Resour Econ 40(4):507–527

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchholz W, Konrad KA (1994) Global environmental problems and the strategic choice of technology. J Econ (Springer Science & Business, Media B.V.) 60:299–321

    Google Scholar 

  • Carbone JC, Helm C, Rutherford TF (2009) The case for international emission trade in the absence of cooperative climate policy. J Environ Econ Manag 58(3):266–280

    Google Scholar 

  • Chander P, Tulkens H (1995) A core-theoretic solution for the design of cooperative agreements on transfrontier pollution. Int Tax Public Financ 2(2):279–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1989) Innovation and learning: the two faces of R &D. Econ J 99(397):569–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copenhagen Accord (2009) http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2009/cop15/eng/l07.pdf

  • Finus M (2003) Stability and design of international environmental agreements: the case of transboundary pollution. In: Folmer H, Tietenberg T (eds) International yearbook of environmental and resource economics 2003/4. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, Chap 3, pp 82–158

  • Gersbach H, Winkler R (2011) International emission permit markets with refunding”. Eur Econ Rev 55(6):759–773

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golombek R, Hoel M (2004) Unilateral emission reductions and cross-country technology spill-overs. Adv Econ Anal Policy 4(2): Article 3

  • Goulder LH, Mathai K (2000) Optimal CO\(_{2}\) abatement in the presence of induced technological change. J Environ Econ Manag 39(1):1–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Helm C (2003) International emissions trading with endogenous allowance choices. J Public Econ 87(12):2737–2747

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoel M (1991) Global environmental problems: the effects of unilateral actions taken by one country. J Environ Econ Manag 20(1):55

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffert MI, Caldeira K, Benford G, Criswell DR, Green C, Herzog H, Jain AK, Kheshgi HS, Lackner KS, Lewis JS, Lightfoot HD, Manheimer W, Mankins JC, Mauel ME, Perkins LJ, Schlesinger ME, Volk T, Wigley TML (2002) Advanced technology paths to global climate stability: energy for a greenhouse planet. Science 298(5595):981–987

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pizer WA (2002) Combining price and quantity controls to mitigate global climate change. J Public Econ 85:409–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosendahl KE, Strand J (2009) Simple model frameworks for explaining inefficiency of the clean development mechanism. Policy Research Working Paper 4931, The World Bank

  • Schneider L (2009) Assessing the additionality of CDM projects: practical experiences and lessons learned. Clim Policy 9:242–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stranlund JK (1996) On the strategic potential of technological aid in international environmental relations. J Econ (Springer Science & Business, Media B.V.) 64:1–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Stranlund JK (1999) Sunk capital and negotiated resolutions of environmental conflicts. Land Econ Univ Wisconsin Press 75:142–155

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole J (1988) The theory of industrial organisation. The MIT Press, Massachusetts, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • UNFCCC (2009) Expert group on technology transfer—five years of work. http://unfccc.int/2860.php

  • Wara M (2007) Is the global carbon market working? Nature 445(7128):595–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Valuable comments by Erling Holmøy, Jon Hovi, Nils-Henrik M. von der Fehr and two anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged. The financial support of the Norwegian Research Council is also highly appreciated.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mads Greaker.

Appendices

Appendix 1: The Uniqueness of the Nash-Equilibrium in the Permit Trading Case

We have assumed that the Nash equilibrium following from (18) is unique. In this Appendix, we show that this is satisfied for \(\frac{\partial ^{3}c_{i}}{(\partial e_{i})^{3}}=0\). For simplicity, we write the second order derivatives of the welfare function in the permit trading case as follows: \(\frac{\partial ^{2}\bar{\omega }^{i}}{\partial \bar{e}_{i}\partial \bar{e}_{i}}=\bar{\omega }_{ii}^{i},\, \frac{\partial ^{2}\bar{\omega }^{i}}{ \partial \bar{e}_{i}\partial \bar{e}_{j}}=\bar{\omega }_{ij}^{i},\, i,\, j=h,a,\, i\ne j.\) The derivatives are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\omega }_{ii}^{i}=b_{i}^{\prime \prime }-2\frac{\partial t}{\partial \bar{e}_{i}}+\frac{\partial t}{\partial \bar{e}_{i}}\frac{\partial e_{i}}{ \partial \bar{e}_{i}}-\frac{\partial ^{2}t}{(\partial \bar{e}_{i})^{2}}\left[ \bar{e}_{i}-e_{i}^{*}\right] ,\end{aligned}$$
(24)
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\omega }_{ij}^{i}=b_{i}^{\prime \prime }-\frac{\partial t}{\partial \bar{e}_{j}}+\frac{\partial t}{\partial \bar{e}_{i}}\frac{\partial e_{i}}{\partial \bar{e}_{j}}-\frac{\partial ^{2}t}{\partial \bar{e}_{i}\partial \bar{e}_{j}}\left[ \bar{e}_{i}-e_{i}^{*}\right] . \end{aligned}$$
(25)

The second-order conditions of the regions’ optimization problems demand that \(\bar{\omega }_{ii}^{i}<0.\) A sufficient condition for uniqueness is that the reaction functions are downward sloping with an absolute value of the slope less than one (Tirole 1988, chapter 5.4). The slope of the reaction function is given by \(-\frac{\bar{\omega }_{ij}^{i}}{\bar{\omega } _{ii}^{i}}\).The sufficient condition for uniqueness is thus satisfied for \( \bar{\omega }_{ij}^{i}<0\) and \(\left| \bar{\omega }_{ii}^{i}\right| >\left| \bar{\omega }_{ij}^{i}\right| .\)

Note that the derivative \(\frac{\partial t}{\partial \bar{e}_{i}}\)equals \( \frac{\partial t}{\partial \bar{e}_{j}}\), \(\frac{\partial ^{2}t}{(\partial \bar{e}_{i})^{2}}\) equals \(\frac{\partial ^{2}t}{\partial \bar{e} _{i}\partial \bar{e}_{j}},\) and \(\frac{\partial e_{i}}{\partial \bar{e}_{i}}\) equals \(\frac{\partial e_{i}}{\partial \bar{e}_{j}}.\) Hence, for \(\bar{\omega }_{ii}^{i}\,, \bar{\omega }_{ij}^{i}<0,\) we must have \(\left| \bar{\omega }_{ii}^{i}\right| >\left| \bar{\omega }_{ij}^{i}\right| .\frac{ \partial ^{2}t}{(\partial \bar{e}_{i})^{2}}\) is equal to zero when \(\frac{ \partial ^{3}c_{i}}{(\partial e_{i})^{3}}=0\). Then, since \(b_{i}^{\prime \prime }<0\,, \frac{\partial t}{\partial \bar{e}_{i}}=\frac{\partial t}{ \partial \bar{e}_{j}}>0\) and \(\frac{\partial e_{i}}{\partial \bar{e}_{i}}= \frac{\partial e_{i}}{\partial \bar{e}_{j}}\in \left\langle 0,1\right\rangle \), we have \(\bar{\omega }_{ii}^{i}\), \(\bar{\omega } _{ij}^{i}<0\) for \(\frac{\partial ^{3}c_{i}}{(\partial e_{i})^{3}}=0\), and equilibrium is unique.

Appendix 2: The Numerical Example

1.1 Benefits and Costs

The benefits of emission reduction targets are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} b_{h}(\cdot )=\eta _{0}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})-\frac{\eta _{1}}{2}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})^{2},\\ b_{a}(\cdot )=\alpha _{0}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})-\frac{\alpha _{1}}{2}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})^{2}. \end{aligned}$$

While the costs of emission reductions are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} c_{h}(\cdot )=\frac{c_{h}}{2}(e_{h})^{2}-\sqrt{k_{h}}e_{h},\\ c_{a}(\cdot )=\frac{c_{a}}{2}(e_{a})^{2}-\sqrt{k_{a}}e_{a}. \end{aligned}$$

The level of investment \(k_{i}\) is bounded such that \(c_{i}e_{i}>2\sqrt{k_{i} }\). The derivative of the cost function with respect to \(k_{i}\) can then be written:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial c_{i}(\cdot )}{\partial k_{i}}=\frac{-e_{i}}{2\sqrt{k_{i}}} \end{aligned}$$

For investments at home we have overinvestment if \(\frac{e_{h}}{2\sqrt{k_{h}} }<p_{h}\), while for investments abroad we have overinvestment if \(k_{a}>0\).

1.2 Parameter Values

The parameters in the benefit functions originate partly from Carbone et al. (2009). The initial emissions reduction for the home region is valued as \( 219 \) $/ton \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\), which is a GDP weighted average of the numbers given in Carbone et al. (2009) for the three countries: the US, EU and Japan. Moreover, we assume that the marginal benefit of emission reductions is halved if world emissions are halved. Hence, we have \(\eta _{0}=219\) and \( \eta _{1}=0.0049\). Following the same procedure for China, we obtain \(\alpha _{0}=50\) and \(\alpha _{1}=0.0011\).

The parameters \(c_{i}\) are set by assuming that it costs 5 % of GDP to reduce region specific business as usual emissions by 50 %. This yields \( c_{_{h}}=0.1\) and \(c_{a}=0.014\). For the GDP figures we have used IMF World Economic Outlook year 2016 predictions (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2011/02/weodata/index.aspx). For the \(CO_{2}\) emissions we have used CDIAC 2008 figures (http://cdiac.ornl.gov/). These are projected to 2016 by assuming the same emissions/GDP ratio in 2016 as in 2008.

Finally, for the prices of R&D we have \(p_{h}\in \left[ 50,102\right] \) and \(p_{h}=p_{a}/7\). This yields a cost reduction in the range 30–15 % for both regions in the sub-game perfect equilibrium with investments never amounting to more than 1.3 % of GDP in total (\(k_{h}+k_{a}\)), which to us seems reasonable. Note that with \(p_{a}=p_{h}\), we would see cost reductions in the developing country far in excess of 30 % in the sub-game perfect equilibrium. This would not change the results qualitatively, but in the example we prefer to have similar cost reduction opportunities.

1.3 Solution Without Permit Trading

Welfare in Stage 2 can be expressed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} W_{h}=\eta _{0}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})-\frac{\eta _{1}}{2}(\bar{e}_{h}+ \bar{e}_{a})^{2}-\frac{c_{h}}{2}(e_{h})^{2}+\sqrt{k_{h}}e_{h},\\ W_{a}=\alpha _{0}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})-\frac{\alpha _{1}}{2}(\bar{e}_{h}+ \bar{e}_{a})^{2}-\frac{c_{a}}{2}(e_{a})^{2}+\sqrt{k_{a}}e_{a}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\bar{e}_{h}=e_{h}\) and \(\bar{e}_{a}=e_{a}\).

From the first-order conditions for a welfare maximum we obtain the following best response curves:

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{0}-\eta _{1}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})-c_{h}\bar{e}_{h}+\sqrt{k_{h}}&= 0 \\ \alpha _{0}-\alpha _{1}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})-c_{a}\bar{e}_{a}+\sqrt{k_{a}}&= 0 \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{e}_{h}=\frac{\eta _{0}+\sqrt{k_{h}}-\eta _{1}\bar{e}_{a}}{\eta _{1}+c_{h}},\quad \bar{e}_{a}=\frac{\alpha _{0}+\sqrt{k_{a}}-\alpha _{1} \bar{e}_{h}}{\alpha _{1}+c_{a}}. \end{aligned}$$

These are then plotted for values of \(k_{i}\) such that \(c_{i}=\) and \(c_{i}=\, ,i=h,a\). We can also find the equilibrium values of \(\bar{e}_{h}\) and \( \bar{e}_{a}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{e}_{h}^{N}=\frac{\alpha _{1}\eta _{0}-\alpha _{0}\eta _{1}+\eta _{0}c_{a}+(\alpha _{1}+c_{a})\sqrt{k_{h}}-\eta _{1}\sqrt{k_{a}}}{\eta _{1}c_{a}+\alpha _{1}c_{h}+c_{a}c_{h}} \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{e}_{a}^{N}=\frac{\alpha _{0}\eta _{1}-\alpha _{1}\eta _{0}+\alpha _{0}c_{h}+(\eta _{1}+c_{h})\sqrt{k_{a}}-\alpha _{1}\sqrt{k_{h}}}{\eta _{1}c_{a}+\alpha _{1}c_{h}+c_{a}c_{h}} \end{aligned}$$

In order to find the equilibrium values of \(k_{h}\) and \(k_{a}\) we solve the following optimizing problem numerically:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{k_{h},k_{a}}\left\{ \eta _{0}(\bar{e}_{h}^{N}+\bar{e}_{a}^{N})-\frac{\eta _{1}}{2}(\bar{e}_{h}^{N}+\bar{e}_{a}^{N})^{2}-\frac{c_{h}}{2}(\bar{e}_{h}^{N})^{2}+\sqrt{k_{h}}\bar{e}_{h}^{N}-p_{h}k_{h}-p_{a}k_{a}\right\} \end{aligned}$$

The results are reported in the text. For the derivative \(\frac{\partial W_{a}}{\partial k_{a}}\) we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial W_{a}}{\partial k_{a}}=-\frac{\alpha _{0}-\alpha _{1}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})}{2\sqrt{k_{a}}}\frac{\eta _{1}}{\eta _{1}c_{a}+\alpha _{1}c_{h}+c_{a}c_{h}}+\frac{\bar{e}_{a}}{2\sqrt{k_{a}}} \end{aligned}$$

which can be plotted.

1.4 Solution with Global Permit Trading

Equilibrium in the permit market allows us to write \(e_{h}\,, e_{a}\) and \(t\) as functions of \(\bar{e}_{h},\bar{e}_{a},k_{h}\) and \(k_{a}\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} e_{h}=\frac{(\bar{e}_{a}+\bar{e}_{h})c_{a}-\sqrt{k_{a}}+\sqrt{k_{h}}}{ c_{a}+c_{h}}, \quad e_{a}=\frac{(\bar{e}_{a}+\bar{e}_{h})c_{h}+\sqrt{k_{a}}- \sqrt{k_{h}}}{c_{a}+c_{h}}, \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} t=\frac{(\bar{e}_{a}+\bar{e}_{h})c_{h}c_{a}-c_{a}\sqrt{k_{h}}-c_{h}\sqrt{ k_{a}}}{c_{a}+c_{h}}. \end{aligned}$$

Welfare in Stage 2 can be expressed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} W_{h}=\eta _{0}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})-\frac{\eta _{1}}{2}(\bar{e}_{h}+ \bar{e}_{a})^{2}-t\left[ \bar{e}_{h}-e_{h}\right] -\frac{c_{h}}{2} (e_{h})^{2}+\sqrt{k_{h}}e_{h}, \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} W_{a}=\alpha _{0}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})-\frac{\alpha _{1}}{2}(\bar{e}_{h}+ \bar{e}_{a})^{2}-t\left[ \bar{e}_{a}-e_{a}\right] -\frac{c_{a}}{2} (e_{a})^{2}+\sqrt{k_{a}}e_{a}. \end{aligned}$$

Differentiating with respect to \(\bar{e}_{h}\) and \(\bar{e}_{a}\) yields the following first order conditions:

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{0}-\eta _{1}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})-\frac{\partial t}{\partial \bar{e}_{h}}\left[ \bar{e}_{h}-e_{h}\right] -t=0,\\ \alpha _{0}-\alpha _{1}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})-\frac{\partial t}{\partial \bar{e}_{a}}\left[ \bar{e}_{a}-e_{a}\right] -t=0, \end{aligned}$$

which by inserting for \(e_{i}\), \(t\) and \(\frac{\partial t}{\partial \bar{e} _{i}}\) yields the reaction functions. We can then find the Nash-equilibrium values of \(\bar{e}_{h}\) and \(\bar{e}_{a}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{e}_{h}^{N}=\frac{\theta _{h}+c_{a}\left( 2c_{a}c_{h}+2\alpha _{1}c_{h}+\alpha _{1}c_{a}-\eta _{1}c_{a}\right) \sqrt{k_{h}}+c_{h}\left( \alpha _{1}c_{h}-\eta _{1}c_{h}-2\eta _{1}c_{a}\right) \sqrt{k_{a}}}{\varphi }\\ \bar{e}_{a}^{N}=\frac{\theta _{a}+c_{a}\left( \eta _{1}c_{a}-\alpha _{1}c_{a}-2\alpha _{1}c_{h}\right) \sqrt{k_{h}}+c_{h}\left( 2c_{a}c_{h}+2\eta _{1}c_{a}+\eta _{1}c_{h}-\alpha _{1}c_{h}\right) \sqrt{ k_{a}}}{\varphi } \end{aligned}$$

where \(\theta _{h}=\left( 2\eta _{0}c_{a}+\eta _{0}c_{h}-\alpha _{0}c_{h}\right) c_{a}c_{h}-(\alpha _{0}\eta _{1}-\alpha _{1}\eta _{0})\left[ (c_{a})^{2}+(c_{h})^{2}+2c_{a}c_{h}\right] \) and \(\theta _{a}=\left( 2\alpha _{0}c_{h}+\alpha _{0}c_{a}-\eta _{0}c_{a}\right) c_{a}c_{h}+\left( \alpha _{0}\eta _{1}-\alpha _{1}\eta _{0}\right) \left[ (c_{a})^{2}+(c_{h})^{2}+2c_{a}c_{h}\right] \) and \(\varphi =\left[ 2c_{a}c_{h}+(\alpha _{1}+\eta _{1})(c_{h}+c_{a})\right] c_{a}c_{h}\).

In order to show that the effects of investments \(k_{h}\) and \(k_{a}\) are ambiguous, we use \(c_{h}=c_{a}=c\). We then have:

$$\begin{aligned} sign\left[ \frac{d\bar{e}_{h}^{N}}{dk_{a}}\right]&= sign\left[ \alpha _{1}-3\eta _{1}\right] \\ sign\left[ \frac{d\bar{e}_{h}^{N}}{dk_{h}}\right]&= sign\left[ 2c+3\alpha _{1}-\eta _{1}\right] \\ sign\left[ \frac{d\bar{e}_{a}^{N}}{dk_{a}}\right]&= sign\left[ 2c+3\eta _{1}-\alpha _{1}\right] \\ sign\left[ \frac{d\bar{e}_{a}^{N}}{dk_{h}}\right]&= sign\left[ \eta _{1}-3\alpha _{1}\right] \end{aligned}$$

Note that all signs depend on the parameters of the benefit functions \( \alpha _{1}\) and \(\eta _{1}\).

In order to find the equilibrium values of \(k_{h}\) and \(k_{a}\) and the degree of overinvestment we solve the following optimization problem numerically:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{k_{h},k_{a}}\left\{ \eta _{0}(\bar{e}_{h}^{N}+\bar{e}_{a}^{N})-\frac{ \eta _{1}}{2}(\bar{e}_{h}^{N}+\bar{e}_{a}^{N})^{2}+t(e_{h}-\bar{e}_{h}^{N})- \frac{c_{h}}{2}(e_{h})^{2}+\sqrt{k_{h}}e_{h}-p_{h}k_{h}-p_{a}k_{a}\right\} . \end{aligned}$$

The results are reported in the text. For the derivative \(\frac{\partial W_{a}}{\partial k_{a}}\) in the with global permit trading case we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial W_{a}}{\partial k_{a}}=\frac{1}{2\sqrt{k_{a}}}\left[ \frac{ c_{h}\left( \alpha _{1}c_{h}-\eta _{1}c_{h}-2\eta _{1}c_{a}\right) \left[ \alpha _{0}-\alpha _{1}(\bar{e}_{h}+\bar{e}_{a})\right] }{\left[ 2c_{a}c_{h}+(\alpha _{1}+\eta _{1})(c_{h}+c_{a})\right] c_{a}c_{h}}+\frac{( \bar{e}_{a}-e_{a})c_{h}}{c_{a}+c_{h}}+e_{a}\right] \end{aligned}$$

which can be plotted.

Appendix 3: Proof of Proposition 3

In this Appendix we prove that \(\frac{d\bar{e}_{h}^{N}}{dk_{i}}+\frac{d\bar{e }_{a}^{N}}{dk_{i}}>0.\) By totally differentiating the two equations (18), we obtain the effects of \(k_{h}\) and \(k_{a}\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \bar{e}_{h}^{N}}{\partial k_{h}}=\frac{\left[ \bar{\omega } _{ha}^{h}\bar{\omega }_{ak_{h}}^{a}-\bar{\omega }_{aa}^{a}\bar{\omega } _{hk_{h}}^{h}\right] }{D},\end{aligned}$$
(26)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \bar{e}_{a}^{N}}{\partial k_{h}}=\frac{\left[ \bar{\omega } _{ah}^{a}\bar{\omega }_{hk_{h}}^{h}-\bar{\omega }_{hh}^{h}\bar{\omega } _{ak_{h}}^{a}\right] }{D},\end{aligned}$$
(27)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \bar{e}_{h}^{N}}{\partial k_{a}}=\frac{\left[ \bar{\omega } _{ha}^{h}\bar{\omega }_{ak_{a}}^{a}-\bar{\omega }_{aa}^{a}\bar{\omega } _{hk_{a}}^{h}\right] }{D},\end{aligned}$$
(28)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \bar{e}_{a}^{N}}{\partial k_{a}}=\frac{\left[ \bar{\omega } _{ah}^{a}\bar{\omega }_{hk_{a}}^{h}-\bar{\omega }_{hh}^{h}\bar{\omega } _{ak_{a}}^{a}\right] }{D}, \end{aligned}$$
(29)

where \(\omega _{ii}^{i}\) and \(\omega _{ij}^{i}\) are given by (24) and (25), respectively, and

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\omega }_{ik_{i}}^{i}=-\frac{\partial t}{\partial k_{i}}+\frac{\partial t }{\partial \bar{e}_{i}}\frac{\partial e_{i}}{\partial k_{i}}-\frac{\partial ^{2}t}{\partial k_{i}\partial \bar{e}_{i}}\left[ \bar{e}_{i}-e_{i}\right] ,\end{aligned}$$
(30)
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\omega }_{ik_{j}}^{i}=-\frac{\partial t}{\partial k_{j}}+\frac{\partial t }{\partial \bar{e}_{i}}\frac{\partial e_{i}}{\partial k_{j}}-\frac{\partial ^{2}t}{\partial k_{j}\partial \bar{e}_{i}}\left[ \bar{e}_{i}-e_{i}^{*} \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(31)
$$\begin{aligned} D=\bar{\omega }_{ii}^{i}\bar{\omega }_{jj}^{j}-\bar{\omega }_{ij}^{i}\bar{\omega }_{ji}^{j}>0 \end{aligned}$$

(see section “The uniqueness of the Nash-equilibrium in thepermit trading case” of Appendix)

By using (26)–(29) above we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \bar{e}_{h}^{N}}{\partial k_{i}}+\frac{\partial \bar{e} _{a}^{N}}{\partial k_{i}}=\frac{\left[ \bar{\omega }_{ah}^{a}-\bar{\omega } _{aa}^{a}\right] \bar{\omega }_{hk_{i}}^{h}+\left[ \bar{\omega }_{ha}^{h}-\bar{ \omega }_{hh}^{h}\right] \bar{\omega }_{ak_{i}}^{a}}{D} \end{aligned}$$

The terms in the brackets are positive as \(\bar{\omega }_{ii}^{i}\,, \bar{ \omega }_{ij}^{i}<0\) and \(\left| \bar{\omega }_{ii}^{i}\right| >\left| \bar{\omega }_{ij}^{i}\right| \). Moreover, we also see from (24) and (25) that \(\left[ \bar{\omega }_{ah}^{a}-\bar{\omega } _{aa}^{a}\right] =\left[ \bar{\omega }_{ha}^{h}-\bar{\omega }_{hh}^{h}\right] . \) Furthermore, the two first terms on the right-hand side of (30 ) are positive, and it can be shown that the sum of the two first terms on the right-hand side of (31) is positive.Footnote 17 Since \(\left[ \bar{e} _{h}-e_{h}^{*}\right] =-\left[ \bar{e}_{a}-e_{a}^{*}\right] \), then \( \bar{\omega }_{hk_{i}}^{h}+\bar{\omega }_{ak_{i}}^{a}>0\), which implies that \( \frac{\partial \bar{e}_{h}^{N}}{\partial k_{a}}+\frac{\partial \bar{e} _{a}^{N}}{\partial k_{a}}>0\), and \(\frac{\partial \bar{e}_{h}^{N}}{\partial k_{h}}+\frac{\partial \bar{e}_{a}^{N}}{\partial k_{h}}>0\).

Appendix 4: Proof of Proposition 6

The derivative \(\frac{\partial \bar{\omega }^{a}}{\partial k_{a}}\), given by ( 23), can be rearranged by using (21) and that \(- \left[ \bar{e}_{a}^{N}-e_{a}\right] =\left[ \bar{e}_{h}^{N}-e_{h}\right] \):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \bar{\omega }^{a}}{\partial k_{a}}=t\left[ \frac{\partial \bar{ e}_{h}^{N}}{\partial k_{a}}+\frac{\partial \bar{e}_{a}^{N}}{\partial k_{a}} \right] +\left| c_{ak}^{\prime }\right| -p_{a} \end{aligned}$$

We know from section “Proof of proposition 3” of Appendix that the sum of the terms in the bracket is positive. Hence, the condition \(\left| c_{ak}^{\prime }\right| \ge p_{a}\) is sufficient for \(\frac{\partial \bar{\omega }^{a}}{\partial k_{a}}\ge 0\), but not necessary. Since some R&D investment is profitable from a cost minimizing point of view, the equation \(\left| c_{ak}^{\prime }\right| =p_{a}\) yields a positive \(k_{a}\). Thus, \( k_{a}^{*}\) must be positive.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Greaker, M., Hagem, C. Strategic Investment in Climate Friendly Technologies: The Impact of Global Emissions Trading. Environ Resource Econ 59, 65–85 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9718-z

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9718-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation