Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Democracy and corruption: a complex relationship

  • Published:
Crime, Law and Social Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We argue that an ‘electoral democracy’ is not sufficient to reduce corruption. Our contention is that the institutions associated with mature democracy are crucial to successfully deterring corrupt behaviour. At the core of our argument is the idea that with well-functioning institutions, the probability of detection and punishment is sufficiently high to deter most decision makers from choosing to act corruptly. The empirical evidence we present supports this idea. The nonlinearity of democracy variables is tested to confirm that an advanced stage of democracy is crucial for combating corruption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Corruption–the misuse of public offices for private gains–undermines economic development by weakening the institutional foundation on which economic growth depends [7, 37]. It also discourages investment, reduces tax revenues and lowers the quality of infrastructure and public services [26, 38, 41, 66]. Corruption is problematic particularly for developing and post-communist countries [33, 57].

  2. The concept of electoral democracy emerges from Schumpeter’s [56] emphasis on electoral competition as the core of democracy. The contemporary minimalist concept of democracy or equivalently an ‘electoral democracy’ refers to a multi-party system with (relatively) free and fair elections, but deficient in many important aspects that define a liberal democracy. See Diamond [16] and Tronquist [64, p. 98] for details.

  3. The narrow-democracy concept, which defines democracy as the selection of leaders through competitive elections by the people, comes from Huntington [30]. Electoral rights data have been compiled by Gastil [23] and Freedom House [21]. Bollen [10] constructed democracy index that included political liberties and popular sovereignty. Barro [8] notes that the Freedom House civil liberties index is a broader concept of democracy as it covers freedom of speech, press freedom and religious freedom and considers a variety of legal protections.

  4. There is no cross-country study that presents a differential comparative analysis based on an aggregate democracy measure, and its various separate components, and the nonlinearities of these variables.

  5. Studies by Montinola and Jackman [44] and Sung [60] find an increase in corruption level in the transitional stage.

  6. The term ‘illiberal democracy’ was popularised by the widely-read work of Fareed Zakaria [70]. We use this term interchangeably with the term ‘electoral democracy’.

  7. Rose, Munro and Mishler [49] contend that the current Putinist political equilibrium in the Russian Federation is characterised by ‘resigned acceptance’.

  8. We should note here that while there was considerable freedom for the institutions necessary for liberal democracy to form, there were substantial levels of corruption in 18th Century Britain [6].

  9. Any extra payment additional to the actual price made to the bureaucrat by a private agent for getting permits or licenses will be termed a “bribe.”

  10. As wage rate W cannot be negative.

  11. See Transparency International [62]. This index has been most commonly used in empirical studies in the economics literature [2, 3, 12, 18, 26, 33, 44, 54, 63, 69].

  12. Political rights include electoral process, political pluralism and functioning of government, and the civil liberties encompass freedom of expression and belief, associational and organizational rights, rule of law, personal autonomy and individual rights, and components of press freedom are laws and regulations, political controls and economic control [21].

  13. Arat [5] and Alvarez et al. [4] combine several democracy attributes using multiplicative aggregation rules.

  14. EF is equally weighted based on eight individual freedoms: business freedom, trade freedom, monetary freedom, freedom from government, fiscal freedom, property right, investment freedom and financial freedom. We excluded freedom from corruption component from the original economic freedom index as corruption is the dependent variable. The index is re-scaled from 0 to 10, where 10 represent the maximum level of freedom.

  15. The results are not reported here, will be available upon request from authors.

  16. Although corruption index ranges from 0 to 10, there is no value that contains zero. Hence, we can utilize panel estimation technique to measure the impact of democracy in combating corruption.

  17. Random effect results are not reported here but will be available from authors on request.

  18. TSLS results are not reported here but will be available on request from authors.

  19. OLS results are not reported here but will be available on request from authors.

  20. TSLS results are not reported here but will be available on request from authors.

  21. In federal structured states the competition among government officials increases. Weingast [67] and Rose-Ackerman [52] have argued that federal structures make more honest and efficient government by providing for competition between sub-jurisdictions. By contrast, Shleifer and Vishny [58] argue that when officials monopolise complementary products, they are likely to over graze, thus leading to sub-optimal over extraction.

  22. The higher value of CCI indicates a higher control of corruption.

  23. A higher value of CCI indicates greater control over corruption.

  24. The negative sign of PR suggests that greater political rights do not increase the control of corruption but the positive coefficient of RL indicates that the control of corruption increases with higher rule of law.

References

  1. Ades, A., & Di Tella, R. (1999). Rents, competition, and corruption. American Economic Review, 89, 982–993.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Ades, A., & Di Tella, R. (1997). The new economics of corruption: a survey and some new results. Political Studies, 45, 496–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Ali, A., & Isse, H. (2003). Determinants of economic corruption: a cross-country comparison. Cato Journal, 22, 449–466.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Alvarez, M., Cheibub, J., Limongi, F., & Przeworski, A. (1996). Classifying political regimes. Studies in Comparative International Development, 31, 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Arat, Z. (1991). Democracy and human rights in developing countries. Boulder: Lynne Rienner.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Bannerman, G. (2007). Merchants and the military in Eighteenth-Century Britain: British Army Contracts and Domestic Supply, 1739–1763. London: Pickering & Chatto.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Bardhan, P. (1997). Corruption and development: a review of issues. Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 1320–1346.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Barro, R. (1999). Determinants of democracy. Journal of Political Economy, 107, S158–S183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Bohara, A., Mitchell, N., & Mittendorff, C. (2004). Compound democracy and the control of corruption: a cross-country investigation. The Policy Studies Journal, 32, 481–499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Bollen, K. (1990). Political democracy: conceptual measurement traps. Studies in Comparative International Development, 25, 7–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Brown, J.-M. (2000). Corruption is alive and well in ‘honest’ NZ. New Zealand Herald 16 September 2000. http://www.nzherald.co.nz/nz/news/article.cfm?c_id=1&objectid=151551. Accessed 27 March 2013.

  12. Chowdhury, S. (2004). The effect of democracy and press freedom on corruption: an empirical test. Economic Letters, 85, 93–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Cohen, A. (1995). Crime and corruption in Eurasia: A threat to democracy and international security. Washington: The Heritage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Coppedge, M. (2002). Democracy and dimensions: comments on Munck and Verkuilen. Comparative Political Studies, 35, 35–39.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Dahl, R. (1971). Polyarchy: Participation and opposition. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Diamond, L. (1996). Is the third wave over? Journal of Democracy, 7, 20–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Doig, A. (2000). In the state we trust? Democratization, corruption and development. In A. Doig & R. Theobald (Eds.), Corruption and democratization. London: Frank Cass.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Emerson, P. (2006). Corruption, competition and democracy. Journal of Development Economics, 81, 193–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Fjelde, H., & Hegre, H. (2007). Democracy depraved. Corruption and Institutional Change 1985–2004. Paper presented at the 48th Annual Meeting of the International Studies Association, Chicago, USA.

  20. Freedom House. (2003). Freedom in the world 2003: The Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties. New York: Freedom House.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Freedom House. (2010). Freedom in the world 2010: Methodology. http://www.freedomhouse.org/report/freedom-world-2010/methodology?page=351&ana_page=363&year=2010. Accessed 27 March 2013.

  22. Fukuyama, F. (1992). The end of history and the last man. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Gastil, R. (Ed.). (1978). Freedom in the world: Political rights and civil liberties. Boston: G.K. Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Glaeser, E., Scheinkman, J., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The injustice of inequality. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 199–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Gounder, R. (2002). Political and economic freedom, fiscal policy, and growth nexus: some empirical results for Fiji. Contemporary Economic Policy, 20, 234–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Gupta, S., Davoodi, H., & Alonso-Terme, R. (2002). Does corruption affect income inequality and poverty? Economics of Governance, 3, 23–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Habtemichael, F., & Cloete, F. (2010). Complexity thinking in the fight against corruption: some perspectives from South Africa. Politikon, 37, 85–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Harris-White, B., & White, G. (1996). Liberalization and new forms of corruption. Brighton: Institute of Development Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Herge, H., Ellingsen, T., Gates, S., & Gleditsch, N. (2001). Toward a democratic civil peace? Democracy, political change and civil war, 1816–1992. The American Political Science Review, 95, 33–48.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Huntington, S. (1991). The third wave: Democratization in the late twentieth century. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Jackman, R. (1985). Cross-national statistical research and the study of comparative politics. American Journal of Political Science, 29, 161–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Jamieson, A. (2000). The Antimafia: Italy’s fight against organized crime. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., & Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1998). Regulatory discretion and the unofficial economy. American Economic Review, 88, 387–392.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Kang, D. C. (2002). Bad loans to good friends: money politics and the developmental state in South Korea. International Organization, 56, 177–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., Mastruzzi, M. (2005). Governance matters IV: Governance indicators for 1996–2004. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4280.

  36. Klerman, D., & Mahoney, P. (2005). The value of judicial independence: evidence from eighteenth century England. American Law and Economics Review, 7, 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Klitgaard, R. (1988). Controlling corruption. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics, 7, 207–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Kristiansen, S., & Ramli, M. (2006). Buying an income: the market for civil service positions in Indonesia. Contemporary Southeast Asia, 28, 207–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15, 222–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Mobarak, A. (2005). Democracy, volatility and development. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 87, 348–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Mohtadi, H., & Roe, T. (2003). Democracy, rent seeking, public spending and growth. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 445–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Montinola, G., & Jackman, R. (2002). Sources of corruption: a cross-country study. British Journal of Political Science, 32, 147–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Moran, J. (2001). Democratic transitions and forms of corruption. Crime, Law and Social Change, 36, 379–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Munck, G., & Verkuilen, L. (2002). Conceptualizing and measuring democracy: evaluating alternative indices. Comparative Political Studies, 35, 5–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Nelson, M., & Singh, R. (1998). Democracy, economic freedom, fiscal policy, and growth in LDCs: a fresh look. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 46, 677–696.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Rock, M. (2009). Corruption and democracy. Journal of Development Studies, 45, 55–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Rose, R., Munro, N., & Mishler, W. (2004). Resigned acceptance of an incomplete democracy: Russia’s Political Equilibrium. Post-Soviet Affairs, 20, 195–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Rose, R., & Shin, D. (2001). Democratization backwards: the problem of third-wave democracies. British Journal of Political Science, 31, 331–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999). Corruption and government: Causes, consequences and reform. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  52. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1978). Corruption: A study in political economy. New York: Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Saha, S., & Gounder, R. (2013). Corruption and economic development nexus: variations across income levels in a non-linear framework. Economic Modelling, 31, 70–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  54. Sandholtz, W., & Koetzle, W. (2000). Accounting for corruption: economic structure, democracy, and trade. International Studies Quarterly, 44, 31–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  55. Schwartz, H. (1999). Surprising success: The new eastern European Constitutional Courts. In L. Scheller & M. Plattner (Eds.), The self-restraining state: Power and accountability in new democracies (pp. 195–214). Boulder: Lynne Rienner.

    Google Scholar 

  56. Schumpeter, J. (1947). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy (2nd ed.). New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  57. Shleifer, A. (1997). Government in transition. European Economic Review, 41, 385–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  58. Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1993). Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 599–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  59. Solomon, P. (2007). Informal practices in Russian justice: probing the limits of post-soviet reform. Law in Eastern Europe, 56, 79–91.

    Google Scholar 

  60. Sung, H.-E. (2004). Democracy and political corruption: a cross-national comparison. Crime, Law and Social Change, 41, 179–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  61. Transparency International. (2005). Corruption perception index. http://archive.transparency.org/policy_research/surveys_indices/cpi/2005. Accessed 27 March 2013.

  62. Transparency International. (2013). Corruption perceptions index: Overview. http://www.transparency.org/research/cpi/overview. Accessed 27 March 2013.

  63. Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: a cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 399–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  64. Tronquist, O. (1999). Politics and development. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  65. Vanhanen, T. (2000). A new dataset for measuring democracy, 1810–1998. Journal of Peace Research, 37, 251–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  66. Wei, S.-J. (1997). Why is corruption so much more taxing than tax? Arbitrariness kills. Working Paper No. 6255, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  67. Weingast, B. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11, 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  68. Willems, L., & Puddington, A. (2013). Russian model gains as press freedom declines. Freedom House Website. http://www.freedomhouse.org/blog/russian-model-gains-press-freedom-declines. Accessed 17 September 2013.

  69. You, J.-S., & Khagram, S. (2005). A comparative study of inequality and corruption. American Sociological Review, 70, 136–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  70. Zakaria, F. (2004). The future of freedom: Illiberal democracy at home and abroad. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We wish to thank Jeff Kline, Gulasekaran Rajaguru, and Ahmed Khalid for helpful comments and discussions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Neil Campbell.

Appendixes

Appendixes

Appendix 1

Table 6 Data sources

Appendix 2

Table 7 Descriptive statistics

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Saha, S., Gounder, R., Campbell, N. et al. Democracy and corruption: a complex relationship. Crime Law Soc Change 61, 287–308 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10611-013-9506-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10611-013-9506-2

Keywords

Navigation