1 Introduction

Human activities produce a variety of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions, including carbon dioxide (CO2), methane (CH4), and nitrous oxide (N2O). These gases, and their non-anthropogenic counterparts, accumulate in the atmosphere over time, altering the radiation balance and thus temperature of the Earth. The change in temperature for a given change in radiative forcing (RF) depends on climate sensitivity (CS). CS is a measure of the responsiveness of the Earth to changes in RF. CS is the equilibrium global mean temperature (GMT) rise associated with a doubling of CO2-equivalent concentrations from pre-industrial levels (Hegerl and Zwiers 2007). Thus, if CS is 3 °C, then doubling the CO2 concentration will result in an increase in GMT rise of 3 °C.Footnote 1 As a result, CS is a vital element in determining the emissions limit required to reach a prescribed temperature goal (Edmonds and Smith 2006; Meinshausen et al. 2009). Specifically, a higher CS will result in a higher GMT change for a given level of emissions.

In addition to a linkage between emissions and temperature, there is also an established linkage between temperature and the carbon cycle (Cox et al. 2000; Friedlingstein et al. 2001, 2006; Randerson et al. 2009; Zeng et al. 2004). These studies find that warmer temperatures accelerate the global carbon cycle (Bond-Lamberty and Thomson 2010), causing an increase in microbial soil respiration. Additionally, while increases in CO2 concentrations lead to CO2 fertilization, or increased CO2 uptake, warmer temperatures may result in saturation of this CO2 uptake by vegetation. The net effect is a decrease in terrestrial carbon uptake as temperature rises, which results in higher atmospheric CO2 concentrations for the same level of CO2 emissions. The combination of these effects creates a positive feedback. Increasing CS results in higher temperatures for the same CO2 concentration levels. Higher temperatures result in higher CO2 concentration levels for the same level of emissions, and higher concentration levels lead to higher temperatures.

While the science of these connections is well documented, the economic implications of these phenomena are less established. Previous research has quantified the amount of mitigation required to keep temperatures below 2 °C as CS increases (Caldeira et al. 2003; Edmonds and Smith 2006) and under different assumptions about ocean heat uptake (Johansson 2011). However, these articles did not explore the role of CS on the carbon cycle. Other research has focused on carbon cycle uncertainty and its implications for the cost of stabilizing CO2 concentrations (Smith and Edmonds 2006), but this work did not link carbon cycle uncertainty to temperature. In this article, we combine the two lines of research and examine the effect of climate sensitivity on the carbon cycle from a mitigation perspective.

Many aspects of the earth system are uncertain, including climate sensitivity, CO2 fertilization, climate-carbon cycle feedbacks, aerosol forcing, and ocean heat diffusion (see (Tanaka et al. 2007) for a more complete discussion). In this analysis, we focus on one uncertainty, climate sensitivity, and its effects on the carbon cycle and mitigation policy. The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) states that the likely range for CS is between 2 °C and 4.5 °C, with the most likely estimate about 3 °C, and values above 4.5 °C still possible (Meehl et al. 2007). Here, we conduct a sensitivity analysis on this parameter and find that achieving a given RF target becomes increasingly expensive as CS increases due to climate feedbacks on the carbon cycle. However, we also find that the uncertainty associated with CS causes the scenarios to vary greatly with respect to the probability of more extreme changes in GMT. While the more stringent policy scenario has only a small effect on the GMT, compared to the more moderate policy target, at a CS of 3 °C, it greatly increases the likelihood of remaining below 2 °C and not exceeding a GMT of 4 °C.

The next section describes the methodology used in this paper, including a brief description of the Global Change Assessment Model (GCAM). Section 3 describes the results of the REF run. The effects of imposing a climate policy are detailed in Section 4. Section 5 discusses aspects related to risk and Section 6 concludes.

2 Methodology

2.1 The GCAM model

The analysis undertaken in this paper uses the GCAM, Version 3.0 (Calvin et al. 2011; Clarke et al. 2007; Kim et al. 2006). GCAM is a global integrated assessment model that couples modules of the economy, energy system, agriculture system, land use, and the climate system in an internally consistent fashion. The world is subdivided into 14 geopolitical regions in the energy and economic systems and 151 regions in the agriculture and land-use systems. The model operates from 2005 to 2095 in 5-year increments. GCAM is a market-equilibrium model; that is, prices of all energy, agriculture, and forest products are adjusted until supply and demand are equilibrated. GCAM is a dynamic-recursive model, that is, decision-makers are myopic and future prices are not considered when choices are made.

The version of GCAM used for this analysis includes a representation of a water system with both supply and demand modules. The water supply module is a gridded (0.5 × 0.5°) monthly water balance model. Using gridded monthly precipitation, temperature, and maximum soil water storage capacity (a function of land cover), it computes the amounts of evapotranspiration to the atmosphere, runoff, and soil moisture (Hejazi et al., under review). The water demand module includes six water demand components: agriculture (irrigation and livestock), primary and secondary energy production, manufacturing and mining, and the municipal sector. Agricultural water demand calculations are detailed, with derivations for 12 crop commodity classes at sub-regional scales (Chaturvedi et al., 2013). Industrial water demands are calculated for a wide range of energy technologies (Davies et al. 2013; Kyle et al. 2013), with the remainder of industrial water use assigned to manufacturing. Municipal water use is a function of GDP per capita, water price, and a technological change parameter (Hejazi et al., 2013).

GCAM computes emissions for 16 gases and short-lived species (CO2, CH4, N2O, F-gases, SO2, BC, OC, NOx, CO, NMVOCs) from a variety of human activities. GCAM computes GHG concentrations, RF, and climate-related variables with the Model for the Assessment of Greenhouse-gas Induced Climate Change (MAGICC) (Wigley and Raper 1992). MAGICC is a simple energy-balance model that includes coupled representations of gas-cycle and climate models. MAGICC has been calibrated to reproduce the results of more complex models. It allows the user to quickly analyze the effect of different projections of future anthropogenic emissions profiles on the carbon cycle, RF, GMT rise, and global mean sea level rise (SLR).

These analysis in this paper is part of the Climate Change Impacts and Risk Analysis (CIRA) project (Waldhoff et al. 2013, this issue), a project aiming to quantify climate change impacts within the United States. To ensure consistency across scenarios within the CIRA project, we have calibrated GCAM’s regional GDP and population to MIT’s EPPA model (Paltsev et al. 2013, this issue), described further in the Supplementary Material (SM).

2.2 Scenarios

The CIRA project combines three policy assumptions (No action (REF), Not-to-Exceed 4.5 W/m2 (POL4.5), Not-to-Exceed 3.7 W/m2 (POL3.7)) with four CS assumptions (2 °C, 3 °C, 4.5 °C, 6 °C), resulting in 12 core scenarios (see (Waldhoff et al. 2013, this issue), for more details). For the REF scenarios, we only modify the CS parameter in the MAGICC component of GCAM. Thus, the four versions of the REF scenario have identical energy systems, agricultural systems, water demand, and emissions. They differ only in their GHG concentrations, RF, climate-related variables, and water supply.

For the policy scenarios, we limit RF to its prescribed level by imposing a carbon price on all emissions, regardless of the source. Specifically, this carbon price applies not only to fossil fuel and industrial emissions, but also to land-use change emissions (see (Wise et al. 2009) for more information). We assume that all regions implement this carbon price beginning in 2015. The time-profile of the price path is chosen to reach the RF target in the most cost-effective manner. As a result, the price rises at the rate of interest until the target is reached. After that time, the carbon price is adjusted in each period to ensure that the target is not exceeded (Calvin et al. 2009). We compute carbon price paths for each of the four climate sensitivities and two RF targets. When varying the climate sensitivity, it is important to note that we adjust emissions to ensure the climate target is met, unlike the approach taken in the REF scenarios where emissions were held constant and climate responded.

3 Business as usual scenario

3.1 3 °C CS results

The REF assesses the evolution of the economy, energy, agriculture, and climate system absent any climate policy. In such a world, future changes in energy, agricultural, land, and water demand are due to assumptions about socioeconomic conditions (Figure SM1), resource exhaustion, and technological progress. Global primary energy consumption rises in the REF Scenario, and the world remains dependent on fossil fuels to meet its energy needs (Fig. 1a). In the USA, primary energy consumption rises in the first half of the century and then stabilizes in the second half of the century (Fig. 1b), as increases in technological efficiency offset the increases in energy services demanded by a growing population. Like the world as a whole, the USA continues to rely heavily on fossil fuels throughout the century.Footnote 2

Fig. 1
figure 1

Primary energy consumption and land use in the REF

Rising populations and increases in wealth result in greater demand for food over the course of the coming century, as GCAM assumes that people will shift to a more meat-intensive diet as incomes grow. These two effects, absent any other changes, would lead to an increase in land devoted to crop and pasture. However, the increases in agricultural productivity that are assumed in GCAM as a result of more mechanized agricultural production and future crop breeding efforts offset the increase in crop and pasture lands. The net effect is that cropland grows slightly between now and 2050 before declining (Fig. 1c). Pastureland remains virtually constant at a global level throughout the century. In the USA (Fig. 1d), land used for the production of food and fiber grows slightly in the near-term before stabilizing. Pastureland declines steadily, despite increases in animal production, to accommodate increasing bioenergy production.

On the water supply side, the amount of total runoff is projected to increase by about 12–13 % both globally and in the USA by 2095 (Figure SM2). This change is attributed to the wet future climate associated with the IGSM-CAM model (Paltsev et al. 2013, this issue). Rising populations, higher demands, and technological shifts attribute to mixed results in total water demands. Total irrigation water demand for crops approximately doubles in the USA and triples in globally by 2095. These increases are due to the expansion of bioenergy and crop production to meet increasing demands. The non-irrigation sectors exhibit a similar trend of doubling globally by 2095 due to increases in population, income, electricity and energy demand, especially in the developing world. In the USA, however, non-irrigation water demand decreases by about 40 % by 2095, primarily due to diminishing thermoelectric cooling water demand. This decrease is driven by shifts away from once-through cooling to more efficient cooling technologies. Therefore, under the REF, water demands are projected to increase by about 150 % globally, and to stay roughly the same in the USA by 2095.

Because of the continued reliance on fossil fuels, both global and U.S. total anthropogenic CO2 emissions are dominated by energy-system emissions (Fig. 2a, b). Global CO2 emissions rise steadily throughout the century from ~30 GtCO2/yr in 2005 (cf. (Le Quere et al. 2009)) to ~90 GtCO2/yr in 2095. In the USA, CO2 emissions grow between 2005 and 2050 before roughly stabilizing. Land-use change (LUC) CO2 emissions grow modestly in the USA and decline slightly at the global level. However, in both cases, LUC emissions are a very minor component of total anthropogenic CO2 emissions.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Emissions, radiative forcing, and global mean temperature rise in the reference

The increase in CO2 emissions in the REF_CS3.0 Scenario results in a rise in CO2 concentrations from 380 ppmv in 2005 to 883 ppmv in 2095. RF rises from 1.6 W/m2 in 2005 to 7.2 W/m2 in 2095 (Fig. 2c). This leads to an increase in GMT of 3.9 °C above preindustrial in 2095 (Fig. 2d). Global SLR increases by 47 cm by 2095.

3.2 The effect of CS on the carbon cycle

Given the design of the REF scenario, varying the CS does not affect energy, agricultural, land use, or emissions (Fig. 3a). However, GMT increases with CS at a given level of RF. This increase in GMT in turn affects the carbon cycle. In particular, we observe a slight increase in ocean carbon uptake as the CS rises (Fig. 3b). However, this increased uptake is more than offset by a decline in terrestrial carbon uptake.Footnote 3 Between climate sensitivities of 4.5 °C to 6 °C the terrestrial system switches from a sink to a source of carbon. This decline in carbon uptake leads to a pronounced increase in the amount of carbon in the atmosphere. In 2095, CO2 concentration levels range from 825 ppmv to 890 ppmv depending on CS.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Cumulative emissions (2005-2095), cumulative carbon uptake (2005-2095), and 2095 CO2 concentrations in the REF and POL4.5 scenarios

Thus, changing CS creates a positive feedback loop, in which higher temperatures lead to more CO2 residing in the atmosphere, which results in different RF levels for the same emissions level (Fig. 2c) and even higher temperatures. GMT rise increases by a factor of two across the four REF runs. Much of this difference is attributable to changes in CS; however, some fraction of this is due to the temperature-carbon-cycle feedback.Footnote 4 Even within a given emissions scenario, the uncertainty over CS creates a wide range of plausible changes to GMT in 2095. SLR is very sensitive to temperature increases, particularly because one cause of SLR is thermal expansion, so as RF increases, temperatures rise, and sea level also rises. The MAGICC results show a range in 2095 SLR for the REF scenario from 37 cm to 69 cm between CS of 2 °C and 6 °C.

4 Policy results

4.1 CS of 3 °C

The imposition of a carbon price raises the costs of freely-emitting technologies in the energy system, rendering lower carbon technologies more attractive. As a result, primary energy consumption, both globally and in the USA, shifts towards nuclear, renewables, and CO2 capture and storage (CCS) technologies (Fig. 4a, b). In POL4.5, energy production from freely-emitting fossil fuel technologies are reduced from a peak of more than 700 EJ/yr in 2050 to below their 2005 values in 2095, whereas they grow continuously through the century in the REF scenario. In the USA, all coal is used in combination with CCS in 2095. Global nuclear power production grows by a factor of 16 over the coming century, biomass consumption increases by a factor of ten, and non-biomass renewables increase by a factor of eight between 2005 and 2095.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Primary energy consumption and land use in the POL4.5_CS3.0 scenario

In the terrestrial sphere, the imposition of a carbon price provides incentives for land-owners to increase their terrestrial carbon stock. The increased demand for bioenergy in the energy system results in increased prices of bioenergy, which in turn influence land cover decisions. As a result of incentives to sequester carbon in the terrestrial system, global forest cover increases by 25 % between now and 2095 (Fig. 4c) for the POL4.5 scenario. This compares with a slight decrease (4 %) forest cover in the REF scenario. POL3.7 has a slightly smaller increase in forests at 23 % due to the increased demand for biomass production needed to meet the tighter RF target. Land devoted to the production of bioenergy accounts for 3 % of global land and 9 % of land in the USA in 2095 (Fig. 4c, d) in the POL4.5 scenario, compared with 2 % and 6 %, respectively, in the REF.

In terms of water, climate policy leads to a decrease in total runoff and an increase in water demand both globally and in the USA (Fig. 5a–d). Although reduced temperatures lead to a reduction in evaporation, and thus, an increase in runoff, this feedback is offset by the decrease in precipitation leading to an overall decrease in total runoff as compared to the REF Scenario. On the demand side, higher biomass production and electricity use result in higher water demands than in the REF Scenario. Water stress (defined as the ratio of demand over supply) in the USA and globally (Fig. 5e, f) is affected by these changes in supply and demand. Water stress globally increases from about 10 to 22–28 % in 2095. This may pose formidable water stress challenges in the coming decades. In the USA, however, this ratio stays roughly around 17 % throughout the century.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Total water supply (runoff), water demand, and water stress in the REF_CS2.0, REF,_CS3.0, REF_CS6.0, POL4.3_CS3.0, and POL3.7_CS3.0 scenarios

The carbon price required to limit RF to 4.5 W/m2 rises exponentially between 2015 and 2095 (Fig. 6a). In the POL4.5 scenario, the price starts at $6/tCO2 in 2015 and reaches $195/tCO2 in 2095.Footnote 5 Total anthropogenic CO2 emissions decrease rapidly in the initial period, before rising again (Fig. 6b). Emissions then peak in 2050 at nearly 50 GtCO2/yr before declining to less than one-third of their 2005 levels. The initial decline is due to the rapid expansion of forest cover globally (Fig. 4c) as a result of incentives to increase terrestrial carbon stocks. The potential for afforestation saturates soon after the policy is implemented. Emissions reductions that occur after that point are mostly due to mitigation efforts in the energy system.

Fig. 6
figure 6

CO2 prices, emissions, radiative forcing, and temperature rise in the POL3.7 and POL4.5 scenarios

With a CS of 3 °C, climate policy reduces GMT rise in 2095 from 3.9 °C in the REF Scenario to 2.6 °C in the POL4.5 scenario and 2.2 °C in the POL3.7 scenario. SLR in 2095 is reduced from 47 cm in the REF to 36 cm in the POL4.5 scenario and 32 cm in the POL3.7 scenario.

4.2 The effect of CS on mitigation

In the policy cases, we prescribe a target RF value and allow emissions, carbon prices, energy use, water demand, and land cover to respond in order to meet the target. As described in Section 3.2, due to the climate feedback on the carbon cycle, varying the CS results in changes in these systems. However, unlike in the REF where we held emissions constant and observed changes in the carbon cycle, in the mitigation scenarios we allow the model to adjust emissions so that the climate target is met. As a result, we find that, to reach the same RF target with higher climate sensitivities, lower anthropogenic CO2 emissions (Figs. 6b and 3c) and higher carbon prices (Fig. 6a) are required.Footnote 6

As in the REF, we see a decline in terrestrial carbon uptake as the CS increases (Fig. 3d). The model responds to this reduction in uptake by increasing mitigation of anthropogenic emissions (Fig. 3c) to maintain roughly constant atmospheric CO2 concentrations (Fig. 3d). This requires additional effort as demonstrated by the change in carbon price.Footnote 7 For both the POL3.7 and POL4.5 RF targets, the carbon price is 20 + % higher under a 6 °C CS than under a 2 °C CS in 2050 and ~50 % higher in 2095 (Fig. 6a).

The CIRA scenarios are designed to limit RF to prescribed levels with four different climate sensitivities. As discussed above, GMT change depends not only on the RF target, but also on the CS. The uncertainty around CS results in a wide range of GMT change at a given RF level. Thus, GMT rise could range from 1.9 °C to 4.0 °C in 2095 for a POL4.5 scenario (Fig. 6d) or 1.6 °C to 3.4 °C for the POL3.7 scenario.Footnote 8

If instead we opted to constrain temperature rise to a specific level, the difference in mitigation effort across climate sensitivities would be larger than in the RF constraint scenarios. For example, limiting temperature rise to 2.6 °C (the 2095 warming level in a POL4.5_CS3.0) under a 6 °C CS requires RF to kept below 2.6 W/m2. In order to meet such a goal, global anthropogenic CO2 emissions would need to peak at 20GtCO2/yr in 2030, as compared to a peak of 47GtCO2/yr in 2050 under a 3 °C CS. Such effort would require a carbon price through 2080 that is more than four times higher than that of the POL4.5_CS3.0 scenario. This change in peak emissions is consistent with (Caldeira et al. 2003; Edmonds and Smith 2006).Footnote 9

In summary, the carbon price required to achieving a RF target increases with CS because tighter emissions limits are required to meet the same RF goal. In addition, for a given RF target, even when the emissions mitigation is adjusted for the level of CS, GMT will still increase with CS, a result consistent with previous literature. Restricting emissions to specific levels will not guarantee that a RF target will be met, nor does meeting a RF target guarantee a specific GMT change.

5 Mitigating risk through mitigation

For a risk-averse society, a thorough understanding of the risks associated with different future scenarios is essential to informed decision-making. This requires the evaluation of both the potential to achieve the desired GMT change and the likelihood of more extreme changes in the climate. Decisions that are made based on only the GMT change at the current “most likely” CS will fail to capture society’s risk aversion to potentially catastrophic climate change.Footnote 10

The scenarios described in this paper show a significant level of uncertainty surrounding the level of climate change that will be realized with any specific RF or emissions reduction policy. When these three scenarios are analyzed at the current IPCC estimate of the “most likely” CS of 3 °C (IPCC 2007), the global average temperature changes in 2095 are 3.9 °C, 2.6 °C, and 2.2 °C, for the REF, POL4.5, and POL3.7 scenarios, respectively.

However, Fig. 7 shows the cumulative density functions for GMT in 2095 for each of the three scenarios and emphasizes the differences in the distribution of GMT across emission scenarios. By applying a an approximation of the probability distribution for climate sensitivity provided in (Roe and Baker 2007),Footnote 11 we can examine the likelihood of staying below various temperature thresholds for each emissions scenario (see (Waldhoff and Fawcett 2011) for more information). While the POL3.7 scenario has a most likely GMT change in 2095 only 0.4 °C less than the POL4.5 scenario, the probability of the GMT change remaining below 2 °C is more than two times greater under the more stringent policy (39 % as compared to 17 %), while under the REF scenario, there is essentially no chance of remaining below this target. In addition, the probability of exceeding more extreme temperature thresholds, such as 4 °C or 5 °C is greatly reduced in the policy scenarios. For instance, there is a 45 % chance of GMT change exceeding 4 °C in 2095 for the REF scenario. The likelihood of this more extreme temperature change is 9 % and 3 % for the POL4.5 and POL3.7 scenarios, respectively. Further, the most extreme GMT change outcomes are virtually eliminated with more stringent policy targets.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Probability of remaining below various temperature thresholds under different policy scenarios

6 Discussion

In this paper, we examine future changes in the energy, agriculture, land, water, and climate in three policy scenarios under four different climate sensitivities. We find that without any climate action, anthropogenic emissions continue to rise throughout the coming century. These increases cause GMT to rise between 3 °C and 6 °C from preindustrial by 2095, depending on CS. The imposition of a carbon price reduces emissions substantially, resulting in a decrease the projected temperature rise from REF. Specifically, 2095 GMT rise ranges from 2 °C to 4 °C, depending on the RF target (3.7 W/m2 or 4.5 W/m2) and the CS. Importantly, climate policy increases the probability of staying below a particular temperature threshold. The chance of keeping GMT below 2 °C increases from 0 % in the REF to 17 % in POL4.5 and 39 % in POL3.7.

Additionally, our results indicate that temperature rise affects the ability of the terrestrial system to store carbon, leading to higher CO2 concentrations for the same emissions levels under higher climate sensitivities. When a climate policy is imposed, we find that higher climate sensitivities require higher carbon prices to limit RF to the same level due to this carbon cycle feedback. This effect places additional uncertainty on outcomes when specifying a RF target (commonly defined in the literature). Such a target renders both the cost of mitigation and the expected temperature outcome uncertain, as both are dependent on the actual CS.

The analysis conducted in this paper focuses on one uncertainty within the earth system. However, many other aspects of this system are uncertain, including CO2 fertilization, climate-carbon cycle feedbacks, aerosol forcing, and ocean heat diffusion. By focusing only on uncertainty in the CS, we do not fully explore the interactions among the carbon cycle, climate, and economy. Instead, we leave a more thorough investigation of these interactions to future research.