Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Referral hiring, endogenous social networks, and inequality: an agent-based analysis

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The importance of referral hiring, which is workers finding employment via social contacts, is nowadays an empirically well documented fact. It also has been shown that social networks for finding jobs can create stratification. These analyses are, by and large, based on exogenous network structures. We go beyond the existing work by building an agent-based model of the labor market in which the social network of potential referees is endogenous. Workers invest some of their endowments into building up and fostering their social networks as an insurance device against future job losses. We look into the manner in which social networks and inequality respond to increased uncertainty in the labor market. We find that larger variability in firms’ labor demand reduces workers’ efforts put into social networks, leading to lower inequality.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We may also, perhaps more abstractly, refer to number of links instead of using for illustrative reasons the term friends. In the model which we develop, friends have a particularly narrow meaning which, however, does not imply that we are not aware of much broader interpretations.

  2. More evidence on job search through friends and relatives can be found in the excellent survey by Ioannides and Loury (2004) or the comparative study by Pellizzari (2004). Recent contributions on the role of social networks and labor market performance using microdata are Cingano and Rosolia (2008) and Hellerstein et al. (2008).

  3. See Freeman (2002) for how information and computer technologies changed matching employers and employees in labor markets.

  4. See e.g. http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/.

  5. One of our referees brought to our attention the work by McCloskey and Ziliak (1996) arguing that, besides statistical significance, economic importance should also be reflected. While we fully agree, we would refer at this point to our earlier remark that we develop a quite stylized model for the study of economic mechanisms, which makes a quantitative interpretation of the results less straightforward.

  6. Note that the share of referral hirings in our experiment with an exogenously given friend is higher than in Table 2, even though the average number of friends is roughly the same. The reason is that an average number of friends equal to one in a framework in which friends are endogenous implies that some workers do not have friends at all, while others may have two or more. Those who do not have friends will not get referrals and those who have more than one friend might have more friends than they need to get a referral. Thus, on average, the share of referrals will be lower as compared to the experiment in which all workers have one friend.

  7. Results of these robustness checks are all available upon request from the authors.

References

  • Bertola G, Blau F, Kahn L (2002) Comparative analysis of labour market outcomes: lessons for the U.S. from international long-run evidence. In: Krueger A, Solow R (eds) The roaring nineties: can full employment be sustained? Russell Sage and Century Foundations, pp 159–218

  • Bewley T (1999) Why wage don’t fall during a recession. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Wolfers J (2000) Shocks and institutions and the rise of european unemployment: the aggregate evidence. Econ J 110:1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boorman S (1975) A combinatorial optimization model for transmission of job information through contact networks. Bell J Econ 6:216–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bramoullè Y, Saint-Paul G (2010) Social networks and labor market transitions. Labour Econ 17:188–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brenner T (2006) Agent learning representation: advice on modelling economic learning. In: Judd K, Tesfatsion L (eds) Handbook of Computational Economics, vol 2. North-Holland, pp 895–947

  • Calvo-Armengol A (2004) Job contact networks. J Econ Theory 115:191–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo-Armengol A, Ioannides Y (2007) Social networks in labor markets. In: Blume L, Durlauf S (eds) The New Palgrave, A Dictionary of Economics, 2nd edn. MacMillan Press, London, p. forthcoming

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo-Armengol A, Jackson M (2004) The effects of social networks on employment and inequality. Am Econ Rev 94:426–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo-Armengol A, Jackson M (2007) Networks in labor markets: wage and employment dynamics and inequality. J Econ Theory 132:27–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer C, Ho T (1999) Experienced-weighted attraction learning in normal form games. Econometrica 67:827–874

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cingano F, Rosolia A (2008) People i know: job search and social networks. Center for economic policy research discussion paper no. 6818.

  • Currarini S, Jackson MO, Pin P (2009) An economic model of friendship: homophily, minorities and segregation. Econometrica 77:1003–1045

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagiolo G, Dosi G, Gabriele R (2004) Matching, bargaining, and wage setting in an evolutionary model of labor market and output dynamics. Adv Complex Systems 7:157–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finneran L, Kelly M (2003) Social networks and inequality. J Urban Econ 53:282–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman R (2002) The labour market in the new information economy. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 18:288–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter M (1974) Getting a job: a study of contacts and careers. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J (2003) Flexibility, job creation and economic performance. CESifo Forum 4(2):29–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellerstein J, McInerney M, Neumark D (2008) Measuring the importance of labor market networks. NBER working papier series, working paper 14201

  • Ho T, Wang X, Camerer C (2008) Individual differences in ewa learning with partial payoff information. Econ J 118:37–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ioannides Y, Loury L (2004) Job information networks, neighborhood effects, and inequality. J Econ Lit 42:1056–1093

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirman A (1997) The economy as an evolving network. J Evol Econ 7:339–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krauth B (2004) A dynamic model of job networking and social influences on employment. J Econ Dyn Control 28:1185–1204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist L, Sargent T (2008) Two questions about european unemployment. Econometrica 76:1–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin C, Neugart M (2009) Shocks and endogenous institutions: an agent-based model of labor market performance in turbulent times. Comput Econ 33:31–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey DN, Ziliak T (1996) The standard error of regressions. J Econ Lit XXXIV:97–114

    Google Scholar 

  • McPherson M, Smith-Lovin L, Cook J (2001) Birds of a feather: homophily in social networks. Annu Rev Sociology 27:415–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery J (1991) Social networks and labor-market outcomes: toward an economic analysis. Am Econ Rev 81:1408–1418

    Google Scholar 

  • Neugart M (2004) Endogenous matching functions: an agent-based computational approach. Adv Complex Systems 7:187–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neugart M (2008) Labor market policy evaluation with ace. J Econ Behav Organ 67:418–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pellizzari M (2004) Do friends and relatives really help in getting a good job. Centre for economic performance, discussion paper no 623

  • Pingle M, Tesfatsion L (2003) Evolution of worker-employer networks and behaviors under alternative unemployment benefits: an agent-based computational study. In: Nagurney A (ed) Innovations in economic and financial networks. Edward Elgar Publishers, pp 256–285

  • Richiardi M (2006) Toward a non-equilibrium unemployment theory. Comput Econ 27:135–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tassier T, Menczer F (2001) Emering small world referral networks in evolutionary labor markets. IEEE Trans Evol Comput 5:482–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tassier T, Menczer F (2008) Social network structure, segregation and equality in a labor market with referral hiring. J Econ Behav Organ 66:514–528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilhite A (2006) Economic activity on fixed networks. In: Judd K, Tesfatsion L (eds) Handbook of computational economics, vol 2. North-Holland, pp 1013–1045

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Herbert Dawid and Philipp Harting and two anonymous referees for their suggestions, as well as all the participants commenting at the Conference of the Eastern Economic Association in Boston 2008, at the Artificial Economics Conference 2008 in Innsbruck, the conference of the European Social Simulation Association in Brescia 2008, the WEHIA conference 2009 in Beijing, the Tagung des Vereins für Socialpolitik 2009, and at the 2009 Cendef conference in Amsterdam, and at research seminars in Pisa and Münster.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Neugart.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gemkow, S., Neugart, M. Referral hiring, endogenous social networks, and inequality: an agent-based analysis. J Evol Econ 21, 703–719 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-011-0219-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-011-0219-3

Keywords

Navigation